Creditors uninterested in getting their money back: dissolving the Eurozone paradox.
Varoufakis, Yanis
I welcome this opportunity to reflect on the lessons arising from
the short period of time during which I led the negotiations between the
Greek Government and our international creditors. Before I explain why
those creditors don't want their money back--and the kind of
disaster that emanates from being indebted to creditors who don't
want their money back--I should give some context.
When you bind together different national economies monetarily, you
join their monetary systems. Their exchange rates become fixed, as
happened when Mexico and Argentina did that some time ago, disastrously,
and during the Gold Standard in the inter-War period, under the Bretton
Woods System after the Second World War, and in the exchange rate
mechanism of Europe in the period prior to 1991-1992. Or you go the
whole way and you replace currencies with a single currency that is then
shared by a number of countries.
What happens when you fix exchange rates is really quite basic.
There is an acceleration of imbalances in trade and imbalances in
capital movements, and the reason for this is simple. Every country,
every monetary union--whether this is New South Wales, Australia,
Europe, Britain, the United States or any other macroeconomic
entity--comprises areas that have trade surpluses with the other areas
that have trade deficits. So in Britain, for instance, the London area
is always in surplus in relation to Wales and the North of England,
while Wales and the North of England are always in deficit in relation
to London. Similarly in Germany--East Germany, West Germany. In
Greece--North Greece, South Greece. In Italy--North Italy and South
Italy. Similarly, California is always going to be in surplus in
relation to Arizona next door. For decades, even centuries, these
patterns of surplus and deficit for regions have remained.
Financing Trade Deficits
How do the perpetual trade deficits get financed? It's very
simple--by recycling of capital as goods flow asymmetrically from the
surplus to the deficit country or regions. Then what happens is that the
profits that are being made through the sale of these goods and services
and which accumulate in the surplus parts migrate to the deficit parts.
They are recycled. There are many ways in which this can occur.
One way is through bank loans: banks that are in London accumulate
all the idle cash and then lend it to people in Wales or North England.
Another way is through the welfare state. If unemployment is higher in
Northern England and Wales than it is in London, then almost
automatically through the tax system, funds go from London to Northern
England and Wales as welfare payments to the unemployed people.
Third, there are political elements. The most impressive surplus
redistributing mechanism on Planet Earth is the military industrial
complex of the United States of America. So when Lockheed or Boeing
canvass with the Pentagon that they should be given the contract to
build a new fighter jet that will cost zillions, there is a tacit
agreement with the Pentagon that, yes, we will give you the contract on
condition that you build a factory to manufacture the wings of the
aircraft in Arizona, and the engines in a new greenfields development in
Missouri--in other words, in deficit regions--so that those deficit
regions receive investment coming from California or from New York. This
is not philanthropy. It's just pragmatic management at the
macroeconomic level, because these investments create jobs and incomes
in Arizona and Missouri, and then the residents of those regions can
carry on purchasing the products of California and New York so that
those surpluses can be recycled and be reproduced.
So surplus recycling is an essential part of any monetary union.
The trouble with the European monetary union, also known as the
Eurozone, is that what I just said never emerged as an important fault
in the mind of its designers. If you read the documents that led to the
creation of the Euro, you will find that there's no mention of the
surplus recycling problem.
How will the surpluses of Germany, the Netherlands, or
Austria--surplus countries within the European Monetary Union--get
recycled to the rest of Europe? The implicit assumption was that it
would happen through the financial system. Indeed, this is what happened
between 1998, when effectively the Euro came into being, and 2008, when
the great financial collapse--the GFC as we call it here in
Australia--struck.
The problem is that creating a monetary union is a little bit like
invading Russia. At first, there is rapid progress, as the French
troops, Napoleon or the Wehrmacht found when they stormed the country,
taking large tracts of land without much resistance. Then slowly, as the
heavy winter sets in, the Cossacks and the Russian partisans start
blowing up your convoys. Eventually you end up with blood on the snow
and a hasty retreat. Recall the 1920s--after the Great War the Gold
standard had created 'the Roaring 20s'. Similarly, when Mexico
and Argentina pegged their currency one to one on the US dollar, there
was a flood of capital coming from the major surplus country--the United
States--into Mexico and Argentina, creating the feeling of triumph,
growth and investment. It was exactly the same in the Eurozone.
I remember I was on an aeroplane in 2011 from Frankfurt to New York
City, sitting next to a German traveller--his name was Franz--and we
started talking, as you do when travelling for 12 hours on a plane. He
said to me that he used to be a banker and now had retired. He worked
for Deutsche Bank, one of the major banks in the European Union. 'I
had a feeling', he said, 'that my life was totally charmed
until the Euro was created. But when the Euro was created, it became a
complete nightmare.' I asked him why that was. Why did the life of
a banker deteriorate in quality so rapidly under the Euro? He said that
up until 1998/1999 he was a master of the universe. 'I would fly to
Paris, to Lisbon, to Athens in your country, and I would be received by
CEOs of large corporations, local bankers, and government officials who
feted me, took me to the opera and their best restaurants. They were
effectively trying to convince me that they should be given a billion
Euros here, another billion there and so on. They were seeking loans.
There was a dearth of credit in the periphery of Europe before 1998, and
I would take their business plans, their track records with me back to
Frankfurt. I would pore over them for about a week and then I would
decide whether I should recommend to the board of directors that these
large loans go ahead. It felt like I was doing a decent job, I was an
important person, I was respected both my superiors and the potential
creditors. Then the Euro came and, suddenly, the frenzy began. Suddenly
we had quotas. I had to lend one billion, two billion, three billion a
week and if I didn't my bonus wasn't safe; and if I
didn't reach those quotas in two or three consecutive weeks, my job
was on the line. So the situation reversed. The balance of power was
completely altered. I would fly into Athens and I would have to act as a
predatory lender. I would have to beg government officials to take loans
off my bank. It was a bit like the sub-prime industry in the United
States during that period. Now why was this happening? It was the Euro.
'
You see, before the Euro, the French and German banks were in two
minds before lending to the Greek State, to the Portuguese State to a
Portuguese bank or a Spanish bank. Why? Because they feared devaluation
of the local currency. If you take 10 million Deutsche Marks from
Frankfurt and you give it to a Spanish, Greek or Italian firm or bank
--and that is prior to monetary union--and then suddenly there is a
substantial devaluation of the currency of Spain, of Italy or Greece
something that was happening at regular intervals prior to monetary
union--then you know that the capacity of the creditors to repay the
loan shrinks. Because their income comes in the local currency, they
will not be able to repay when the local currency is devalued. So banks
were very careful before unloading Deutsche Marks to the periphery of
Europe prior to the creation of a common currency. But the moment
everybody had the Deutsche Mark--because that's what the Euro is,
the Deutsche Mark with different clothes--everything changed.
The purpose of the Euro was for France in particular to get its
hands on the Deutsche Mark--to get rid of the Franc and to replace it
with the Deutsche Mark. Also for other countries, but France was the
main player. That was the Faustian bargain between Germany and France
and the rest: we'll give you the Deutsche Mark but we will write
the rules. So the moment that happened, the managers of the Deutsche
Bank felt that it doesn't matter whether we lend to a German
company or a Greek company because now we're all one currency area.
All incomes are denominated in Deutsche Marks. The only concern is: do
the creditors have any collateral?
Increasing Regional Stresses
In Greece--and this is something that surely will astound you--when
we entered the European Union we had the lowest level of debt in Europe.
Yes, the lowest, both private and public. Private debt in Greece is the
lowest even to this day. Most people own outright their own homes. I
grew up in a country where the idea that you would borrow 90 per cent of
the price of the house and think of yourself as a 'houseowner'
was laughable. Indeed, it is laughable.
The Greeks--and Spaniards, Portuguese and Irish too--had very low
levels of debt and collateral for houses and land. Deutsche Bank looked
at that and thought: 'my goodness, this is amazing. These people
have Deutsche Marks and they have collateral and they have low debts.
This is the dream of a banker. Pile that on there: this is how you make
money.'
Now, every time a Volkswagen is sold in Greece--let's say for
a Volkswagen costing 20,000 Euros-20,000 Euros goes from a Greek bank
account to a Frankfurt bank account--perhaps to Deutsche Bank. Greece
doesn't make cars, so the balance of trade is rather asymmetrical,
as you can imagine. How many oranges or olives can you sell in Germany
in order to ameliorate for the Mercedes Benz's and the Porsches
that are exported? So there's always going to be a deficit--a trade
deficit that Greece has. What then happens is the Deutsche Bank has to
lend to a Greek Bank, so that the Greek can carry on purchasing the
exports from Germany.
This is precisely what the German banks wanted to do. Why? When you
have a major trade surplus, it means that you have net exports and a net
flow of capital from the deficit countries to your banks. So there is a
flood of cash coming into your banking system. The Germans, both
households and the State, simply didn't have enough demand for all
this cash that was piling up there. There's one thing that the
banker hates more than anything and that is idle cash--cash that's
just sitting there and not being lent--because it's a wasted
opportunity for a banker to profit.
So the oversupply of capital in Germany was pushing down the value
of money in Germany. That affected interest rates in Germany, pushing
them very low. So there was no incentive for the banks to lend that
money in Germany and there was not sufficient demand. But in the
periphery of Europe where there was an exodus of capital going to places
like Germany and the Netherlands to facilitate the purchase of the net
exports of those surplus countries, this exodus of capital created a
scarcity of capital--of money--in Greece and Portugal and Ireland, which
pushed up the effective price of money.
So if you were a business person and you wanted to borrow money in
Greece to invest, you would have to pay a much higher interest rate than
the equivalent German businessperson, even though the official interest
rates were the same. The commercial interest rates were not the same
because of this imbalance. So, if you were a banker sitting on a pile of
cash in Frankfurt, where the effective interest rate is one or two per
cent, but you can lend the same money to a Greek businessman or woman
for five per cent, what would we do? Lend it in the latter place, of
course. You're going to take the pile of cash, go there and say:
'please take it'.
So the Greek debt prior to the debt crisis in 2008 was the flip
side of the coin of German net exports, which had been accelerating as a
result of the currency union. That is something that happens inevitably
in the history of capitalism: it has happened every time a monetary
union has been created.
The problem with this is the reason why Germany is a surplus
economy relative to Greece or Portugal. It is because of well-developed
industry and high capital utilisation intensity in Germany, coexisting
with very low utilisation--low production of tradable goods--in places
like Greece. You have a lot of souvlaki and a lot of nightclubs
producing services in Greece. But these are not internationally trade
goods. You cannot sell them directly in Germany. You have to go to
Greece--which is also very nice. So the imbalances are underpinned by
asymmetries in capital utilisation.
This means that in places like Germany, because of the capital
intensity of production, profit margins are very high, and companies
like Volkswagen make a mint. In other words, the difference between the
prices they charge and their costs of production is high and there is
also excess capacity. They can produce a lot more Volkswagens than
they're currently producing, which acts as a deterrent to
competition, because if you know that the main player in a market sector
has excess capacity, you hesitate to compete against them. Thus,
competition is lowered in the surplus parts of the monetary union as a
result of the same economic factors that create trade imbalances.
Monetary Unions
In a proper monetary union, what happens is that this recycling
would be rationalised in two important ways. Firstly, a federal
government, like you have in Australia, should ensure that these loans
go from the surplus parts, like New South Wales, to deficit parts like
Tasmania. Because there is a common industrial policy, development
policy, environmental policy, and social policy, transfers by the state
to the deficit areas should bolster the capacity of those deficit areas
to do useful things. However, when you don't have that, this flood
of capital simply pushes up house prices, for instance, creating bubbles
in the real estate. This happened in Spain, in Greece and in Ireland,
which gave the house owners this illusion of being richer. So they took
on more debts, using credit cards and personal loans. The first few
years look like a startling success story. Greece consistently
outperformed Germany in terms of growth rates. We had about four and
five per cent annual growth rates in Real GDP between 2000 and 2008,
while Germany was only growing at one per cent. There was convergence.
Because our income was growing faster than either of the Germans, that
was being presented by Brussels as testimony to the success of the
monetary union. However, it was all a bubble. It was Ponzi
growth--unsustainable debt-fuelled growth.
The problem with these kinds of monetary unions, as we know from
1929, is that at some point something pricks the bubble. It could be a
meteor; or it could be fear of a bankruptcy of some large firm like
Enron in the United States. Then suddenly the bankers will realise that
they have lent so much money, especially to one another, that they
themselves have become insolvent. So many of the debts that they created
have gone bad because the debt cannot be paid and then they panic. As
Keynes said, they resemble fair weather sailors who abandon the ship
that they are supposed to be commanding, the moment that dark clouds
emerge. But in their haste to get ashore, they also sink the lifeboats
when they stop lending.
But in a place like Greece, Portugal or Spain--where bubble
economies have been created which need constant refinancing--developers
who had been developing by borrowing began going bankrupt when suddenly
faced with a situation where the debts that they already had were not
refinanced by the bank. When the new loans didn't come the
developers went bankrupt. In 2008 the whole of the private sector
started deleveraging--in other words saving or not spending. The moment
that happened, the States' regulators collapsed, economic activity
shrunk, everybody started owing to everyone else and no one could pay.
That's what had happened in Mexico and in Argentina, as it had
throughout the world in the late 1920s leading to the great depression,
the rise of fascism and the onset of the second world war.
So there was nothing new in what happened in Europe. However, it
was unlike the case of Mexico, Argentina or the Gold Standard, where the
national currency in people's pockets remained the same--except
that it was pegged to another hard currency. In the case of Argentina,
the peso was pegged to the United States Dollar: so you still had pesos
in your pocket but every peso was worth one US Dollar. But you still had
the pesos in your pocket. Now why is this important? Because ending this
regime when the going gets tough takes a simple decision by the Minister
of Finance. Overnight he could say that the exchange rate of one-to-one
doesn't exist anymore. Severing the peg and floating the currency
effects an instant devaluation. Through this devaluation, suddenly a
large chunk of your debt in dollars has disappeared. In Europe, by
contrast, all the currencies had been replaced with a single one.
So how can you devalue when you don't have a distinct currency
to devalue? How was the Greek crisis to be dealt with? Well, in 2010,
the Greek State became well and truly bankrupt. Think of these two
mountains. One is the mountain of national income and the other is the
mountain of national or public debt. Public debt was 120 per cent--1.2
times--national income. But, up until 2008 to 2009, national income in
nominal terms--in Euros--was rising by 7 or 8 per cent every year, due
to the Ponzi growth. The debt mountain was rising by 4 per cent. If your
income is rising at 7 or 8 per cent and your debt is rising by 3 or 4
per cent, it's sustainable.
But then the GFC caused our nominal income to fall by 10 per cent.
The country went from 8 per cent annual growth to minus 10 per cent. So
we lost 18 per cent at this point. Investors and bankers thought:
'oh my God, we have a new Lehmann Brothers disaster in the form of
Greece'. They demanded huge interest rates in order to carry on
refinancing the existing debt mountain. The Greek State became
bankrupt--well and truly, irreversibly. What was the response of the
European Union and the Greek Government to this? Denial--pure, undiluted
denial.
I wrote an article in 2010 saying: let's embrace our
bankruptcy because if we don't, it will kill us. I was considered a
national traitor. How dare you say that the Greek State is bankrupt,
even when it is? So when you're bankrupt, what do you do? If you
pretend that you're not bankrupt there's only one way--to
borrow more. When you can't repay your mortgage, you get a credit
card from which you draw money to make the payments every month,
pretending you're not bankrupt. How old do you need to be to
understand that this cannot end well--eight, six, seven? But making this
point in Europe in 2010 was regarded as subversive and dangerous talk by
a radical left looney person. Okay, so what did Greece do? We took the
largest loan in human history, about 110 billion Euros approximately 190
billion Australian dollars--in one go, on condition of implementing
austerity measures that would cause the Greek national income to shrink
further.
Now we have a choice here. We can say that our creditors were
stupid. Imagine if you went to your bank and you said: 'dear
manager, I can't repay my mortgage because I've lost my
income--I lost my job or I lost overtime or I had to take a pay cut or
I'm sick and I need to pay all this money for medical treatment--I
can't repay my mortgage. Please can you give me a second mortgage
from which I'll repay the first mortgage?' Imagine your banker
saying: 'yes but under the condition that you will agree to shrink
you income further'. Of course, no banker would say that. No
creditor would sensibly impose on debtors conditions that guarantee that
the creditor will not get their money back. Because I never believe an
explanation based on the assumption or presumption of stupidity,
something else must be going on. What was it? The fact of the matter was
that a year before the bankruptcy of the Greek State, Deutsche Bank was
deeply bankrupt. When Lehmann Brothers went bankrupt, it had a leverage
ratio of 1 to 38--that is, for every one dollar it had, it owed 38.
Deutsche Bank in 2009 had a leverage ratio of 73: it was clearly kaput.
So Mrs Merkel, the German Chancellor, and Doctor Schauble, her
Finance Minister--the paragons of parsimony and fiscal rectitude who
claimed that you should never live beyond your means--suddenly had their
aides come into their office and say: 'you know what, all or banks
are bankrupt--and we have to pay them money'. 'What? How much
do they need?' 'Oh, 500 billion, and we have only a few hours
before they blow up'. So Merkel had to bite the bullet and go to
the Bundestag--the Federal Parliament in Berlin--and face her own
parliamentarians who had spent their political lives nit-picking over
100,000 Euros here and 100,000 Euros there--for example, should we give
a million to this state or to the health service--to tell them that in a
very short space of time that they will have to give 500 billion Euros
to the bankers who had been rolling in money for decades. It was very
difficult for them to hear this, but within a few hours they had voted
for a bail-out of the banks of Germany by 500 billion Euros. Now what
they hadn't been told was that the black hole of German Banks was
actually much greater. 500 billion Euros was not enough, because of the
derivatives and the loans that France was giving to the banks that were
not counted in the 500 billion. When, a year later, Greece went
bankrupt, we owed something like 200 billion Euros to the German and
French banks: only this.
Then there was Portugal, there was Spain, there was Italy, and a
domino effect was in the making. So you can imagine the Chancellor
thinking: 'oh my God! I may have to go back to the Bundestag and
say, remember that 500 billion--it wasn't enough'. So a
different solution had to be found.
Remember Aesop's fable of the Ant and the Grasshopper? The ant
is working hard throughout the summer--he's a protestant--while the
Greek grasshopper is sitting under a tree, singing and playing the
bouzouki. Winter comes, so the grasshopper goes to the ant and begs for
assistance. Everyone had to help the grasshoppers. Now the problem was
that the array of grasshoppers seeking help included--as my friend Franz
on that international flight was relating to us--the Northern banks.
It takes two to tango. For every irresponsible borrower, there is
an irresponsible lender; and for every irresponsible lender there is
going to be an irresponsible borrower. This is not a moralistic tale:
this is a problem of the architecture of the Eurozone. So, to cut a long
story short, the first bail-out was not because the creditors wanted to
get their money back, but because the creditors were trying to find some
way of saving the German and the French banks--that this bailing them
out a second time, without the parliamentarians and electorates of
Germany and France realising that this was what was going on.
So how was it presented? It was presented as a bail-out of Greece,
rather than a second bail-out of the Deutsche Bank. Of that huge amount
of money that Greece got in May 2010-110 billion Euros--how much do you
think was retained by the Greek State? It was just eight per cent.
Moreover, it didn't go to the pensioners or anything like that: 91
or 92 per cent went to the banks. The reason why I'm not the Greek
Finance Minister any more is because I refused to sign another such a
loan agreement on the 12th of July last year. That loan agreement
entailed another 85 billion Euros. Do you know how much of that was
going to go to the Greek State? Zero. It was new money to pay off the
older debts but in a manner that would sinks Greece deeper into
bankruptcy. That was the real situation.
Since 2010, Europe is in denial of the causes of Ponzi growth and
then what I call the Period of Consolidation after 2010, I refer to as
Ponzi Austerity. Yes, there's nothing wrong with belt tightening
during the tough times if you or I have a problem balancing our
household accounts because we spend more than we earn. We have a moral
duty to ourselves and to rationality to tighten our belts--not go on
that holiday, not to buy a new car, but to save. This is just common
sense. But this is not helping in Greece. We have borrowed 400 billion
Euros since we became bankrupt in 2010. This is not parsimony: this is
profligacy. Remember, Ponzi growth is growth based on unsustainable
debt. Ponzi austerity is belt tightening based on unsustainable debt.
This is what is happening in Europe now.
Ponzi austerity is a result of the capacity of the European
periphery to purchase Germany exports. That has created deflationary
forces that afflict Germany and Holland. You can see that the rate of
inflation has collapsed to zero. Interest rates in Germany are negative.
Pension funds in Germany are in dire straits because they have negative
interest. What does it mean to have negative interest? You have to pay
people to take your money. Why do you do that? Because you fear that
prices are going to fall. So if somebody takes your money and charges
you one per cent interest you perpetuate the cycle of recession.
The only thing that kept Germany and the North of Europe alive
after 2008 was the positive impact of China's economic growth--also
impacting here in Australia. We can discuss how positive it is in the
long run, but at least in the short time it was clearly positive. China
decided, quite wisely I think, to buy time for itself and for Europe and
the United States, hoping that the Europeans and the Americans would get
their act together within three or four years. It pushed the rate of
investment from an already high 32 per cent to 51 per cent of GDP. In
other words, out of every 100 dollars of output in China, 51 per cent
was invested. This is the largest percentage in history. It was based on
Ponzi growth--on developing real estate at the regional government
level, creating bubbles in the real estate that would support collateral
credit creation. The fastest credit growth episode in the history of
capitalism has been in China. But that was all done in full knowledge of
the dangers of what they were doing, hoping that, by 2011 or 2012,
Europe would have picked up the slack and consolidated.
Concluding Observations
Look, Greece is not important except to us Greeks. We're two
per cent of the Euro economy. If New England in northern New South Wales
was constantly in the news for six years because its economic
instability threatened financial failure for the Commonwealth of
Australia, that would signify not a problem with New England but a
problem with the Commonwealth of Australia as a whole. So the only
reason why it makes sense to focus on Greece is because what it
reflects. It is 'the canary in the mine', an indicator of the
fact that European capitalism is ungovernable. There remains a kind of
denial that condemns Europe to constant fragmentation and to a process
which leads to the deconstruction of the European community.
When, on top of that, you have some crisis which cannot be
anticipated, like the current refugee crisis, the European union has no
solid foundation upon which to build a common security and refugee
policy. Every national government has succumbed to asking
'what's in it for me?' and seeking how to avoid taking
responsibility for the common problem. This does not auger well for
establishing or dealing with humanitarian issues or the threat from
geopolitical ruptures like the conflict over Ukraine, like ISIS, like
Libya.
Europe has given us no evidence that it is in the hands of a
political class capable of achieving that which its name proclaims--a
European Union. Ghandi was once asked what he thought of European
civilisation: his answer was 'it would be an excellent idea'.
The same applies to the European Union: it would be a splendid idea, but
we don't have it and, increasingly, we're moving into the
realm of European disunion. Many Europeans could quite understandably
respond to this fact, and to the sights and sounds of an inane political
class stumbling from one debacle to another fiasco, by saying:
'let's just abandon it and go back to our nation status'.
I warn against this.
We should not have created the monetary union. I was an opponent of
this when I was a lecturer here at the University of Sydney. I penned
feisty and fiery articles in Greek which were published in Greek
newspapers in Athens, opposing Greece's entry to the monetary
union. However, it's one thing to say we should not have
entered--that we should not have created a European Union the way we
did--but it's quite another to say that we should disband it. Once
you follow the path towards a European Union, that path no longer
exists. Retracing it backwards--reversing--will cause you to fall in an
abyss, because that path is no longer there. Similarly, with
institutions of political union. Fear is created over the way Brussels
and Frankfurt operate. But if we allow the terrible European union we
have now to fragment, we're going to go back to a worse situation.
With a highly deflationary Germany and surrounding area--Poland,
Slovakia, the Czech Republic and with Greece attached there
somehow--high unemployment will occur. This will be terrible for
Australia, terrible in the United States, and it will be appalling for
China. Europe has managed to drag the world into the mire of world wars
twice in the last 100 years. Could it do so again?
I leave you with just one simple thought: why is this poltical
economic debacle happening in Europe? My answer is because the EU is not
operating as a democracy. Democracy is not a luxury to be afforded to
the rich or credit rich nations. The reason why democracy is important
is because it is essential to good economic policy. So the economic
crisis now evident in Europe is the result of all the important
decisions being taken in a democratic vacuum. Either we are going to
democratise the European Union or the European Union is going to perish.
Yanis Varoufakis was the Finance Minister in the Greek Government
during 2015. He had formerly been a lecturer and senior lecturer in the
Faculty of Economics at the University of Sydney, and professor at the
University of Athens. He has recently been appointed as an Honorary
Professor in Political Economy at the University of Sydney. This article
is based on a transcript of a lecture he presented at the University of
Sydney in November 2015.
JAPE YOUNG SCHOLARS AWARD
Each year the editors of JAPE offer $2000 and some supervision for
one or more young scholars to work on a potentially publishable journal
article.
Applicants are usually recent undergraduates who have written an
extended essay, dissertation or thesis as part of their study .
Applications should be submitted to
[email protected]_
before the end of November.
Further info at www.jape.org