Work choices: the low productivity road to an underclass.
Cowling, Sally ; LaJeunesse, Robert ; Mitchell, William 等
1. Introduction
The Workplace Relations Amendment (Work Choices) Act 2005 was
proclaimed on March 27, 2006. The Australian Government (2005) posits
that the reforms will generate a fairer balance of forces within the
labour market and lead to higher employment, productivity and real
wages. These changes are deemed essential given Australia's
increasing exposure in a globalised economy.
The origins of Work Choices can be traced to the neo-liberal
economic reform agenda that emerged in response to the inflation
breakout following the first oil price shock in the mid-1970s. This
agenda gained additional impetus with the publication of the Jobs Study
by the Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) in
1994. This blueprint for reform was grounded in the primacy of markets,
and the imperative to remove the institutional fetters which allegedly
inhibited their operation. Active macroeconomic policy was eschewed and
the pursuit of tight monetary policy and budget surpluses, to constrain
inflation, was advocated.
In embracing these prescriptions, the Australian Government has
ignored the macroeconomic consequences of having nearly 1.8 million
workers without sufficient work (Keating, 2005) and has established
pernicious compliance regimes to ensure that unemployed and marginalised
workers are blamed and punished for their circumstances.
With the introduction of Work Choices, one of the last symbols of
fairness in our society--the judicially-determined conciliation and
arbitration system and wage-setting machinery--has been eliminated. The
economic and social consequences already being experienced are likely to
be more profound than those flowing from previous changes in the conduct
of industrial relations. While low-paid workers will bear the brunt of
the impact, few workers will be garrisoned from the radical and damaging
transformation in the way we work, earn income, take leisure, and engage
in social relationships.
2. A conceptual framework
2.1 Methodological Individualism
The theoretical perspective underpinning the Work Choices Act
argues that reducing the rights and protections for workers will promote
individual bargaining with employers, providing both parties with a
broader range of choices about workplace arrangements and producing
superior labour market outcomes. Two caveats are important here. First,
despite the mantra of flexibility, the legislation is highly
prescriptive, particularly with respect to allowable matters in
agreements. Second, the current macroeconomic policy framework, which
remains entrenched as the backdrop to the legislation, has resulted in
the stagnation of median real minimum wages over two decades.
The neo-liberal policy approach draws on the textbook model of
perfect competition for its theoretical imprimatur. This orthodox model
argues that the establishment of market-clearing equilibrium is
guaranteed by the presence of wage and price flexibility. Ipso facto the
failure of markets to clear is a result of prices and/or wages being
inflexible, which would reflect market imperfections, including labour
market regulations, impinging on the exercise of free choice by economic
agents.
This model is devoid of the institutional, social and political
context in which asymmetries of power and information, bounded
rationality, tradition, myopia and a myriad of other influences bring
about so-called imperfections in the functioning of markets. In
particular, no power is assumed to be exercised by the large number of
autonomous agents who interact in impersonal product and labour markets,
with the labour exchange indistinguishable from the exchange for lemons
or any other commodity (Polanyi, 1957). Accordingly, the object is
exchanged for money and use values are transferred between worker and
employer to be consumed outside the exchange. This construction fails to
recognise that labour is a special commodity because the employer
consumes the use values of the exchange during the work process rather
than after the exchange, and because the worker relies on employment for
both sustenance and social identity (Cowling and Mitchell, 2005: 201).
This power imbalance in the employment relationship was codified in
the Australian industrial relations system in the 1907 Harvester
decision which recognised that the anarchy of the market would rarely
generate a fair distribution of wages, due to the imbalance of
bargaining power. The Basic Wage was defined as a social minimum living
wage. Market constructs such as the capacity to pay were subjugated by
this social wage concept. A fair society, which, by definition, would
exclude the creation and perpetuation of an under-class, required that
the distributional system be legally regulated. For this reason
industrial relations were given a specialised judicial process. The
development of labour-specific, union-oriented arbitration and
conciliation processes in Australia reflected a need for labour law to
redress the power imbalance, which placed workers in a subordinate
position to employers (Mitchell, 2005: 2).
The clear intent of the Work Choices Act is for wages and
conditions to be determined by market forces. Equity and social justice
issues are ignored through reducing the perceived importance of minimum
wage adjustment. This begs the question of whether the negotiation of
individual contracts--via the imposition of Australian Workplace
Agreements (AWAs) on possibly unwilling employees--is appropriate within
an equitable industrial relations system. Until recently Australian
legal practice has not regarded labour market relations as being best
regulated by commercial law. Labour or employment law was seen as being
distinct with certain rights and responsibilities that transcended
commodity exchange. Common law, in particular, leaves unorganised labour
vulnerable. Certainly successive rounds of reform since the acceptance
of enterprise bargaining by the Australian Industrial Relations
Commission (AIRC) in 1991 and the enactment of the Workplace Relations
Act 1996, encompassing the promotion of AWAs, have not created a de
facto competitive labour market.
2.2 Macroeconomics
The Work Choices legislation lies within the broad policy framework
of the 'new macroeconomic consensus' and the OECD Jobs Study
agenda (OECD 1994). Orthodox economists extend microeconomic market
clearing principles to the operation of the macroeconomy. Keynes (1936)
and later the Post Keynesians demonstrated that the presence of perfect
competition was neither necessary nor sufficient for the achievement of
full employment (Davidson 1994). The conceptual leap from microeconomic
market clearing propositions to full employment involves a fallacy of
composition that is omnipresent in the public policy debate and the
economics literature.
The experience of World War II showed governments that full
employment could be maintained with the appropriate use of budget
deficits. At the War's end, governments had to translate the full
employed war economy with extensive civil controls and loss of liberty
into a fully employed peacetime model. The emphasis of macroeconomic
policy was on achieving full employment by generating enough jobs. The
control of inflation was a secondary concern.
The rise in inflation in the mid-1970s deteriorated into
stagflation when governments failed to develop appropriate macroeconomic
responses to the oil price impulse. The emergence of stagflation
revealed ideological fissures among Keynesians. These were previously
masked by the prosperous post-war consensus between government, labour
and business. The rift led to the development of
'New-Keynesianism'--a paradigm obsessed with economic
rigidities, such as trade unions and minimum wages- which served as a
precursor to the neo-liberal agenda centred on labour market flexibility (Palley, 2004). This professional discord assisted the articulation of a
consensus based on methodological individualism in leading Western
nations. The reform paradigm became prominent in the policy
recommendations of international economic organisations, including the
OECD's Jobs Study.
Monetary policy in the wake of the oil crises was geared to control
inflation while fiscal policy was designed to passively support this aim
through the pursuit of balanced budgets over the business cycle. The
Australian Government has redefined fiscal policy in terms of the
imperative to achieve persistent surpluses and to sustain the economy at
the rate of unemployment at which the inflation rate is alleged to be
stable. This macroeconomic paradigm was buttressed by specific
microeconomic reform proposals. These focused on the labour market to
rid the OECD economies of what was deemed to be a sclerosis, reflecting
years of regulation and income transfer policies that had eroded
individual incentive and institutionalised high unemployment rates.
Before outlining and investigating some of the weaknesses of the
Work Choices Act, we note some stylised facts that challenge the alleged
macroeconomic success of the present neo-liberal agenda. In February
2006, the official unemployment rate was 5.2 per cent, which is well
above the rate experienced in the immediate post-war period. Moreover, a
broader hours-based measures of labour underutilisation (incorporating
hidden unemployment and underemployment) calculated by the Centre of
Full Employment and Equity (CofFEE) indicated that 9.9 per cent of
willing labour resources were unused. The quality of the work undertaken
has also deteriorated with the growth of jobs characterised by
precarious tenure, low pay and non-standard working hours (Borland et
al., 2001).
The persistent labour wastage indicates that net government
spending is too low (Mitchell and Mosler, 2002) and the preoccupation
with budget surpluses has introduced significant fiscal drag into the
growth cycle. The willingness of households to become increasingly
indebted has driven economic growth for some time. This growth strategy
is unsustainable and will eventually lead to an entrenched recession as
households resume saving and reduce their debt exposure.
Freeman (2005: 1) notes that the debate about the determinants of
economic performance has shifted from the conduct of macroeconomic
policy to the degree of labour market deregulation. Empirical studies will be flawed, unless they recognise that outcomes (particularly
employment and productivity) will be influenced by macroeconomic policy
settings. Firms hire workers to produce goods and services that they can
sell. Thus, at prevailing wage levels, aggregate employment is a
function of the demand for the output that workers produce. The Work
Choices legislation can only bring about putative employment gains if
the envisaged reductions in wage growth and erosion of working
conditions serve to increase household consumption; stimulating
aggregate demand and, with a lag, labour demand. Clearly, this is most
unlikely. Wage erosion is likely to reduce aggregate demand, and further
diminish demand for labour.
Persistent unemployment has no basis in a lack of labour market
flexibility. Instead, the macroeconomic policy (on-going budget
surpluses) pursued by the Australian Government remains the major cause
of labour market slack. There is also a failure to understand that
government expenditure is not subject to the financing constraints that
apply to households. Deficits, which are calibrated to provide enough
flat currency to 'finance' the private sector's desire to
net save in the currency of unit, are necessary to achieve full
employment unless alternative employment policies are introduced. CofFEE
advocates a Job Guarantee, which provides a minimum wage job in the
public sector to all workers who want one. It is one way to regulate the
minimum extra spending that is required by the Federal Government to
ensure that everyone who wants to work can get a job (Mitchell and Wray,
2005). We now examine the provisions and likely impact of the Work
Choices legislation based on this conceptual framework.
3. The Impact of the Work Choices Legislation
3.1 Wage Setting
The new legislation guarantees that nominal minimum and award
classification wages will be protected at the current weekly Federal
Minimum Wage (FMW) of $484.40. The Australian Fair Pay Commission (AFPC)
will be required to place greater emphasis on promoting economic
prosperity, through employment generation, in determining the subsequent
adjustment of the FMW. Given that the establishment of the AFPC has been
explicitly linked to the view that the generosity of AIRC Safety. Net
decisions has been to the detriment of employment growth, it is
reasonable to expect that the real minimum wage will fall over time or
grow at a considerably slower rate. Briggs and Buchanan (2005) note that
the reforms will also impact on a cohort of skilled workers who lack
bargaining power and on low paid workers who earn above the FMW but for
whom safety net increases represent a floor underpinning their wages.
The AFPC will determine the timing, scope and frequency of its wage
reviews, the manner in which wage reviews are to be conducted and the
date on which wage-setting decisions are to come into effect (House of
Representatives, 2005: 20). Cowling and Mitchell (2005) argue that the
independence of the AFPC is compromised by the relatively short tenure
of its members prior to re-appointment and the capacity of the
Commonwealth to recruit sympathetic members within the selection
criteria. While the Department of Employment and Workplace Relations
(DEWR) states that the AFPC wage reviews are designed to be inclusive
and that the Commission can undertake or commission research, engage in
consultation, and monitor and evaluate the impact of its wage-setting
decisions, this will be for the AFPC to determine alone. The AFPC can
choose to publish its wage-setting decisions, without supporting
evidence.
By contrast, at Safety Net reviews, previously conducted by the
Full Bench of the AIRC, a range of parties and expert witnesses
presented evidence, were questioned by the Commissioners, and were
subject to cross-examination. The AIRC not only published its decisions,
but also a detailed evaluation and assessment of the evidence presented
to explain the basis on which its determination was made (Cowling and
Mitchell, 2005).
Also in contrast to the AIRC, the AFPC will not be required to
consider 'fairness' and living standards as part of the four
legislated wage-setting parameters. These parameters (House of
Representatives, 2005: 49) are:
a. The capacity of the unemployed and the low paid to remain in
employment.
b. Employment and competitiveness across the economy.
c. Providing a safety net for the low paid.
d. Providing minimum wages for junior employees, employees to whom
training arrangements apply and employees with disabilities that ensure
those employees are competitive in the labour market.
The exclusive focus on labour costs is likely to promote overly
cautious wage decisions, particularly when economic activity slows.
Importantly, the Work Choices Act fails to recognise that "fairness
among workers and fairness among the population are not the same
thing" (Richardson and Harding, 1999: 152). While increasing the
minimum wage will not, in isolation, have a potent and equalising impact
on the distribution of household income, the Commission should be
charged with ensuring 'fair pay' so that a minimum wage rate
is determined that prevents worker exploitation and provides a level of
remuneration which represents the worker's contribution to the
value of output.
In addition, parameter (c) will require the AFPC to respond to
Government decisions, which influence the household distribution of
income--such as changes to rates and thresholds within the personal
income tax system and the level, and targeting, of income support
payments--as opposed to making determinations about appropriate wage
settings per se. This decision-making process leaves no room for
consideration of what constitutes a fair division of production between
labour and capital. This represents an important shift from the
determination of a fair social minimum, and the recognition that labour
is a special commodity, which underpinned the 1907 Harvester Judgment.
3.2 Employment effects
Without providing specific estimates, DEWR argued at the 2005-06
Budget Senate Estimates Hearings that the operation of the AFPC would
benefit employment creation:
DEWR has provided considerable evidence of the negative effects on
employment arising from the operation of the current Workplace
Relations Act 1996 where the Australian Industrial Relations
Commission (AIRC) continues to grant large wage rises in the
annual Safety Net Review ... The AFPC will ensure a better balance
between fair pay and employment.
DEWR (2005: W319-06)
Economists and employer groups have long claimed in their
submissions to wage setting tribunals that wage increases, or the
imposition of minimum wages and conditions, will have adverse
consequences for employment (see, for example, AIRC: 2003, 2004, 2005).
This proposition is grounded in the orthodox microeconomic theory
outlined in Section 2, however empirical support is tenuous. Significant
interdependencies between labour demand and supply are typically ignored
by those who use 'text-book' theory as an
'authority' for their claims (Thurow, 1983).
Despite abundant international evidence (Card and Krueger, 1994;
Machin and Manning, 1994; Borland and Woodbridge, 1999; and Watson,
2004), the debate about the impact of a minimum wage increase remains
unresolved and largely divides along ideological lines. Neoclassical
economists have used a litany of poorly constructed empirical research
to draw a negative association between real wage rises and employment.
The OECD (1998) is now more equivocal about the role of minimum wages on
employment and acknowledges that a rise in the minimum wage has not
unambiguously led to job losses for youth. It still argues that
(unspecified) high levels of minimum wages will be detrimental to
employment.
In its May 2004 Safety Net decision the AIRC (2004: Paragraph 229)
states:
After yet another survey of the literature and other material
on the economic effects of increases in minimum wages it has
clearly emerged, once again, that most of the information is
of very limited assistance. The research is either largely
irrelevant, is limited in scope, or has serious methodological
flaws.
With the scrapping of the no disadvantage test, the 'race to
the bottom', within the limits defined by the Australian Fair Pay
and Conditions Standards, has begun. Recent reports of marginal
retailers and meatpackers firing workers and offering to re-hire them on
AWAs, serve as a harbinger of downward wage movements that even
progressive employers will be pressured to pass along to their workers.
Disadvantaged workers who lack bargaining power will be forced to accept
AWAs and other individual agreements with terms and conditions below the
relevant award standard or face dismissal. The unemployed will still be
required to take any work that is offered to them, irrespective of the
contractual arrangements, or have their unemployment benefits suspended.
Thus employers have significantly more power under WorkChoices and
take-it-or-leave-it contracts are likely to become widespread.
It is important to recall that the periodic increase of minimum
wage levels can force low wage firms to raise labour productivity
through new investment, rather than compete on the basis of wage cuts.
If properly implemented, statutory minimum wages can reduce earnings
inequality, ensure a fairer distribution of economy-wide productivity,
gains and build prosperity from the bottom up by increasing incentives
to work at a living wage, particularly for welfare dependent youth. This
is an important alternative to current policy settings that has gone
largely ignored in countries such as Britain, the USA, Australia and New
Zealand where a policy of trickle-down economics has been pursued
(Palley, 1998).
3.3 Workplace reform and economic performance
Under Work Choices, corporate employers with fewer than 100
employees are exempt from unfair dismissal laws and will be able to
summarily dismiss their workers with relative impunity. For larger
firms, widely defined operational reasons will be sufficient to justify
workforce reductions. The incentive for capricious behaviour will be
compelling. Few workers will seek legal redress for unlawful dismissal,
because of the expense, legal complexity and time lags of common law
claims, coupled with the fact that successful actions do not offer
reinstatement. While a tight labour market may discipline rogue employer
behaviour, the real hardships for many workers will arise during the
next business cycle contraction.
Calling on the authority of the textbook competitive model, the
Government justifies the elimination of unfair dismissal protection on
the grounds that regulatory constraints impact negatively on economic
performance, particularly employment growth. Following the Jobs Study,
researchers have attempted to assess the impact of institutional
arrangements on economic performance. Authoritative labour economists,
including Baker et al., (2004) and Freeman (2005) have not found that
free market reforms have led to a statistically significant fall in
unemployment. The OECD (1998, 1999) and the World Bank (2003) are now
more equivocal about the professed impact of proposed reforms. Nor does
Australian empirical work support the Commonwealth's implicit
proposition that, by providing access to career opportunities, any job
is better than no job (for example, Burgess and Campbell, 1998; Dunlop,
2000).
Institutional arrangements which enable wage cutting in a
macroeconomic environment of underutilised labour will not promote
on-the-job training and increased productivity, despite exaggerated
claims about skill shortages in Australia. Mitchell and Quirk (2005)
argue that the persistently high levels of labour underutilisation and
emerging skills shortages in some specialised areas both reflect a lack
of governance, exemplified by the reduction in public sector employment
and training structures. Work Choices entrenches the view that the
private market can deliver dynamic training responses to occupational
demands, despite significant evidence to the contrary. The international
research literature finds that the industrial relations regime of a
country can impact adversely on the human resource strategy of an
innovating firm (see LaJeunesse, Mitchell and Watts 2006).
Finally there are many parallels between the objectives of Work
Choices and the disastrous industrial relations experiment conducted in
New Zealand during the 1990s. The outcomes of the Employment Contracts
Act offer relevant evidence of the relationship between unions and
labour productivity. Although the 1991 legislation was successful in
accelerating the decline of unions--with union density falling by 50 per
cent in less than a decade- labour productivity growth collapsed between
1993 to 1998, reflecting the deterioration of morale, trust, loyalty,
and good faith in the workplace (May et al., 2002).
4. Conclusion--a better way forward
In February. 2006, despite fourteen years of sustained economic
growth, 9.9 per cent of willing labour hours were being wasted in
Australia (CofFEE, 2006). The Work Choices legislation represents the
continuation of a neo-liberal reform agenda based on the discredited
premise that shifting the balance of power within the labour market will
lead to full employment. As such, the legislation represents a
significant 're-regulation' rather than a deregulation of the
labour market.
Under Work Choices, the imperative to minimise labour costs will
spur a race to the bottom and the profusion of insecure, low-paid,
poor-quality work. Not only will this strategy, fail to achieve full
employment, but the economy will be characterised by allocative
inefficiency. A low-wage regime represents a subsidy to inefficient
firms by enabling them to remain viable. In addition, the failure of the
Act to promote physical and human capital formation to raise
productivity, signals dynamic inefficiency and a future characterised by
stagnant real wages and living standards, and declining international
competitiveness (Buchanan and Callus 1993).
Demographic trends may well lead to a long-term tightening of the
labour market, and increased bargaining power for more highly skilled
workers. However, low-skilled workers, with limited bargaining power,
will always be vulnerable to reductions in wages and conditions
irrespective of the state of the business cycle. In the modern labour
market the low-wage worker serves as a macroeconomic buffer for both
inflation and wider unemployment among the lower--and middle-classes.
The Work Choices Act is of value only because it recognises the
serious social problem of labour underutilisation. The travesty of the
legislation is that it ignores the role of macroeconomic policy in
directly addressing the efficiency, fairness and distributional issues
that have been said to motivate its provisions. The Bill also ignores
the different bargaining power of workers and capital and pays no
attention to the serious social repercussions that will flow when labour
is treated like a commodity.
To directly address the cause of unemployment and ameliorate income
inequality requires the State to use its fiscal powers to achieve and
maintain full employment. Mitchell, (1998) outlined the Job Guarantee
approach in which the public sector would maintain a 'buffer
stock' of minimum wage jobs available to anyone willing and able to
work as the most expedient means of addressing unemployment. This
approach does not rely on engineering labour supply adjustments by
paring back real wages at the bottom of the earnings distribution.
References
Australian Government (2005) Work Choices: A New Workplace
Relations System, Commonwealth of Australia, October.
Australian Industrial Relations Commission (MRC) (various years)
'Safety Net Review Wages', Decision and Statement. Available
at: http://www.e-airc.gov.au/
Baker, D., Glyn, A., Howell, D.R. and Schmitt, J. (2004)
'Labor Market Institutions and Unemployment: A Critical Assessment
of the Cross-Country Evidence', in Howell, D.R. (ed.) Fighting
Unemployment: The Limits of Free Market Orthodox,, Oxford University.
Press, Oxford.
Borland, J., Gregory, R.G. and Sheehan, P. (2001) Work Rich, Work
Poor: Inequality and Economic Change in Australia, Centre for Strategic
Economic Studies, Melbourne.
Borland, J. and Woodbridge, G. (1999) 'Wage Regulation, Low
Wage Workers and Employment', in Richardson, S. (ed.) Reshaping the
Labour Market: Regulation, Efficiency and Equality in Australia,
Cambridge University Press: Melbourne.
Briggs, C. and Buchanan, J. (2005) 'Work, Commerce and Law: A
New Australian Model?', Australian Economic Review, 38(2), 182-191,
June.
Buchanan, J. and Callus R. (1993) 'Efficiency and Equity at
Work: The Need for Labour Market Regulation', Journal of Industrial
Relations, 35(4), 515-527.
Burgess, J. and Campbell, I. (1998) 'The Nature and Dimensions
of Precarious Employment in Australia', Labour and Industry, 8(3),
5-22.
Card, D. and Krueger, A.B. (1994) 'Minimum Wages and
Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and
Pennsylvania', The American Economic Review, 84(4), 772-793.
CofFEE (2006) CofFEE Labour Market Indicators, Centre of Full
Employment and Equity, February. Available at
http://e1-newcastle.edu.au/coffee/
Cowling, S. and Mitchell, W.F. (2005) 'Taking the Low Road:
Minimum Wage Determination Under WorkChoices', in Wrightson, G.
(ed), Creating a Culture of Full Employment, Proceedings of the 7th Path
to Full Employment Conference and the 12th National Conference on
Unemployment, December, 196-206.
Davidson, P. (1994) Post Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory, Edward
Elgar, Aldershot.
Department of Employment and Workplace Relations (DEWR) (2005)
Answer to Question on Notice W319-06, 2005-06 Budget Senate Estimates
Hearing, May.
Dunlop, Y. (2000) 'Labour Market Outcomes of Low Paid Adult
Workers', ABS Cat. No. 6293.0.00.005, Australian Bureau of
Statistics, Canberra.
Freeman, R.B. (2005) 'Labour Market Institutions without
Blinders: The Debate over Flexibility and Labour Market
Performance', Working Paper 11286, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, MA.
House of Representatives (2005) 'Workplace Relations Amendment
(WorkChoices) Bill 2005', Explanatory Memorandum, The Parliament of
the Commonwealth of Australia, November.
Keating, M. (2005) 'Increasing Employment Participation in
Australia and How to Finance It', Paper presented to Transitions
and Risk: New Directions in Social Policy Conference, University of
Melbourne, February.
Keynes, J.M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money, Macmillan, London.
LaJeunesse, R., Mitchell, W.F. and Watts, M.J. (2006)
'Economics and Industrial Relations: Debunking the Myths', in
Teicher, J., Lambert, R. and O'Rourke, A. (eds.) WorkChoices: The
New Industrial Relations Agenda, Pearson Education, Australia, 123-141.
Machin, S. and Manning, A. (1994) 'The Effects of Minimum
Wages on Wages Dispersion and Employment: Evidence from the UK Wages
Councils', Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 47, 319-329.
May, R., Walsh, P., Harbridge, R. and Thickett, G. (2002) Unions
and Union Membership in New Zealand: Annual Review, Industrial Relations
Centre, Victoria University, Wellington.
Mitchell, W.F. (1998) 'The Buffer Stock Employment Model--Full
Employment without a NAIRU', Journal of Economic Issues, 32(2),
547-55.
Mitchell, W.F. (2005) 'Industrial Relations Changes: The Final
Demise of a 'Fair Go' Society!', New Matilda, May.
Mitchell, W.F. and Mosler, W.B. (2002) 'Fiscal policy and the
Job Guarantee', Australian Journal of Labour Economics, 5(2),
243-60.
Mitchell W.F. and Wray, L.R. (2005) 'In Defence of the
Employer of Last Resort' Journal of Economic Issues, March, 39(1),
235-45.
Mitchell W.F. and Quirk, V. (2005) 'Skill Shortages in
Australia: Concepts and Reality', in Wrightson, G. (ed.) Creating a
Culture of Full Employment, Proceedings of the 7th Path to Full
Employment Conference and the 12th National Conference on Unemployment,
December, 307-323.
OECD (1994) OECD Jobs Study, Evidence and Explanations,
Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.
OECD (1998) 'Making the Most of the Minimum: Statutory Minimum
Wages, Employment and Poverty', OECD Employment Outlook,
Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.
OECD (1999), 'Employment Protection and Labor Market Performance', OECD Employment Outlook, Organisation of Economic
Cooperation and Development, Paris.
Palley, T.I. (1998) 'Restoring Prosperity: Why the U.S. Model
is not the Answer for the United States or Europe', Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics, 20(3), 337-53, Spring.
Palley, T.I. (2004) 'From Keynesianism to Neoliberalism:
Shifting Paradigms in Economics', in Johnston, D. and Saad-Filho,
A. (eds.) Neoliberalism--A Critical Reader, Pluto Press, London.
Polanyi, K. (1957) The Great Transformation: The Political and
Economic Origins of our Time, Beacon Press, Boston.
Richardson, S. and Harding, A. (1999) 'Poor Workers? The Link
between Low Wages, Low Family Income and the Tax and Transfer
Systems' in Richardson, S. (ed.) Reshaping the Labour Market:
Regulation, Efficiency and Equality in Australia, Cambridge University
Press, Melbourne, 122-158.
Thurow, L. (1983) Dangerous Currents: The State of Economics, OUP,
Oxford.
Watson, I. (2004) 'A Needle in a Haystack: Do Increases in the
Minimum Wage Cause Employment Losses?', ACIRRT Working Paper, 90,
March
World Bank (2003) Unions and Collective Bargaining: Economic
Effects in a Global Environment, Washington, February.