Herd behavior and the 1997 Asian crisis: further evidence.
Khan, Saleheen ; Islam, Faridul ; Park, Kwang Woo "Ken" 等
Abstract
This paper presents empirical evidence in support of the claim that
herd behavior can explain the severity of the 1997 Asian crisis above
and beyond macroeconomic fundamentals. We compare cross-country
correlations between crisis and tranquil periods among the nations of
Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, Korea, and the Philippines, with regard
to such macro variables as, stocks returns, interest rates, exchange
rates, and foreign reserves. Macro models are constructed and
implemented to capture the pure contagion effects on markets. After
controlling for the economic fundamentals for these economies, we find
strong evidence of herding contagion.
JEL classification: F30, G15
Keywords: Financial Markets, Currency crisis, Herd behavior,
Contagion, Correlation
I. INTRODUCTION
The 1997 Asian crisis has rekindled the debate over currency
contagion. When the Thai Government abandoned the dollar exchange rate
peg on July 2, 1997, the looming crisis quickly spread through much of
East Asia. How this crisis spread so rapidly from the first victim to
the rest has baffled the policy makers and has attracted the attention
of a growing number of economists and professionals, all searching for
answers.
According to Calvo and Reinhart (1996), herding contagion is rooted
in factors that are independent of economic fundamentals. Such contagion
is more likely to occur when common shocks or all channels of
interdependence are not present or controlled for. In other words, a
herding framework assumes that individual investor simply follow other
investors where market sentiment provides the main dynamic force. As
Radelet and Sachs (1998) argue, to a foreign creditor the basic economic
characteristics of the Southeast Asian countries prior to the crisis
were indistinguishable from one another. To them, if Thailand was in
trouble, any other country in the region could be the next. Therefore,
creditors' mood was to get out of the region as soon as possible,
something that potentially can lead to herding behavior in the financial
market.
The objective of the paper is to examine the 1997 Asian crisis in
an effort to provide further empirical evidence in favor of the
existence of herding contagion; and also to offer a set of general
policy insights based on the observed facts. We define contagion as
shocks that are in excess of what can be normally explained by economic
fundamentals alone. (1) The paper tests for contagion by comparing the
cross-country correlations between crisis and tranquil period, among the
macro variables for Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, Korea, and the
Philippines. The variables selected relate to stocks index, interest
rates, exchange rates, and foreign reserves. The approach used here is
relatively common in the prevailing literature on contagion (2), but
differs in one major aspect. Most of the prevailing research uses high
frequency data and thus, cannot control for macroeconomic fundamentals
and global shocks. By contrast, this paper uses monthly data which
allows us to address the macro issues. Given that our research focus is
about herding contagion, we consider it is of significant importance to
control for macroeconomic fundamentals and global shocks to better
understand the forces at play.
The paper closely relates to Baig and Goldfajn (1999), but differs
from them in approach and methodology. While these authors examine
whether cross-country correlations among currencies, stock returns,
interest rates, and sovereign spreads in emerging markets increased
during the Asian crisis, we examine the cross-country residual
correlations among variables of currencies, stock returns, interest
rates, and foreign reserves after controlling for macroeconomic
fundamentals and global shocks. The prevailing models try to capture the
contagion using the correlations of a set of macro variables across
nations. The correlations obtained by using this procedure can however,
be biased due to its link with macro variables and thus may fail to
capture pure contagion. Masson (1998), and Pindyck and Rotemberg (1990)
also use the concept of pure contagion and argue that co-movements of
macro variables between nations cannot be explained by economic
fundamentals alone, because of the role of market sentiments. Residuals
filter out the effects of other included relevant macro variables. So,
correlations obtained from the residuals are expected to better
represent market sentiments or herding contagion. The paper thus is a
significant contribution to the literature.
The paper is organized as follows. Section II briefly reviews the
literature. Section III describes methodology, and data. Empirical
results are reported in Section IV. Section V offers some policy
perspective. Section VI concludes the paper.
II. REVIEW OF LITERATURE
Following the US stock market crash of 1987 changes in the
cross-country correlation have been the standard to measure contagion.
King and Wadhwani (1990) applied this approach to the US, British, and
the Japanese data and found evidence of significant rise in correlations
after the crash. Lee and Kim (1993) also find similar results. Calvo and
Reinhart (1996) find evidence of a rise in correlation between weekly
returns on equities and Brady bonds for Asian and Latin American
emerging markets, after the Mexican crisis. Baig et al. (1999) and Khan
et al. (2005) also find evidence of increased cross-market correlations.
Forbes and Rigobon (2002) counsel caution in interpreting the increased
correlations as evidence of contagion because the returns correlations
can be the product of statistical artifact, and more so in a volatile
stock market. Using a corrected conditional heteroskedasticity method
they showed that once the bias is adjusted, the evidence of contagion
disappears in all three major crises (Asia 1997, Mexico 1994 and the US
1987). Bartram and Wang (2005) and Corsetti, Pericoli, and Sbracia
(2005) question Forbes and Rigobon (2002) results because of its
reliance on particular assumptions about the underlying stochastic
process of the stock returns. The authors show that the adjustment
produces serious biases in test in favor of the null hypothesis of
"no contagion." Masson (1998), and Pindyck and Rotemberg
(1990) also use the concept of pure contagion and argue that
co-movements of macro variables between countries cannot be explained by
economic fundamentals alone, because of the role of market sentiments.
III. EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK
(a) Data
The paper uses monthly data on nominal and real exchange rate,
interest rate, consumer price index, money supply (M2), trade volume,
domestic credit, and stock return. The sample period covers 1994.1
through 1999.12. For interest rate, we use the money market rates for
Thailand, Indonesia, and Korea; and Treasury bill rates for Malaysia and
the Philippine. All data are taken from the IFS CD ROM, except for stock
return and real exchange rate. Stock return series are from the
Bloomberg, and real exchange from JP Morgan. The 3-month US Treasury
bill rate represents foreign interest rate.
(b) Methodology
In line with Baig et al. (1999) and Forbes and Rigobon (2002), we
define contagion as a significant increase in cross-market linkages,
after an initial shock to one country or a group of countries. Within
this framework, test for contagion boils down to verifying if the
cross-market co-movements increase significantly after a shock. The
argument is: If correlations increase significantly in the crisis
compared to tranquil period, one may conclude in favor of herding
contagion because international financial markets tend to move more
closely together during a period turbulence. Due its simplicity, the
approach is standard in the literature on contagion.
Whether or not the Asian currency crisis was contagious is an
empirical question. As defined, contagion refers to a substantial
increase in the cross-market linkages following a shock to an single or
a group of countries (3). Our task is to tests if such a rise in some of
the channels of economic linkages did take place after the shock.
Possible channels for shock transmission include; stock market, interest
rate, currency, and foreign reserves for the economies of Indonesia,
Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand (4).
We obtain two different measures of correlation for the above noted
series for the five Asian nations, most hit by the crisis. First, we
compute and compare the cross-market correlations for these variables
both for the crisis and for the tranquil periods. Failure to control for
global shocks or macro fundamentals can produce an upward bias in the
estimated correlation coefficients.
A high correlation among the variables could simply be the result
of the similarities in economic fundamentals and common global shocks.
To correct for this, a second measure of correlation was computed from
the residuals in lieu of the actual series. These residuals were
obtained by running a several regressions (levels data). A total of five
regressions, one each for the variables of stock return, interest rates,
exchange rates, and foreign reserves produced five sets of residuals
series for each of the five sample countries. The regressions were run
on a set of macroeconomic variables (levels), which were chosen for
their theoretical and empirical relevance. The first residual series for
the stock return was obtained by regressing it on nominal exchange rate,
interest rate, price level, and the US interest rate. Likewise, we
specify the other equations for the variable of interest rates, exchange
rates, and foreign reserves, and ran regression for each of the five
countries (5,6) The U.S. interest rate serves as a proxy for global
shock and tacitly recognizes its influence on the emerging markets.
These residuals, and not the actual series, were used to compute the
correlations which produced ten pairs of such coefficients for each of
the five variables. Interest rates were regressed on money supply,
foreign reserve, price level, and U.S. Treasury bond rates. Nominal
exchange rates were regressed on money supply, real exchange rates, bank
credit, and trade volume. Foreign reserves were regressed on money
supply, nominal exchange rate, pride level, and interest rates.
We employ the methodology developed by Forbes and Rigobon (1999)
and Baig and Goldfajn (1999). We apply a two-sample t-test to check
whether correlations are significantly different in two periods. The
test hypotheses are the following:
[H.sub.0] : [[rho].sup.0.sub.i,j] [greater than or equal to]
[[rho].sup.1.sub.i,j] [H.sup.1] : [[rho].sup.0.sub.i,j] <
[[rho].sup.1.sub.i,j]
Where [[rho].sup.i.sub.i,j] is the correlation coefficient between
country i and country j over period t. The tranquil and crisis period is
denoted by "0" and "1" respectively. Baig and
Goldfajan (1999) derived following test statistic:
T = [[bar.x].sub.0] - [[bar.x].sub.1]/[([s.sub.0.sup.2]/[n.sub.0] +
[s.sub.1.sup.2]/[n.sub.1]).sup.1/2] (1)
'The test statistics follows the t-distribution, and degrees
of freedom are calculated as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (2)
[[bar.x].sub.t], and [s.sub.t.sup.2] refer to the estimated sample
mean and variance, and [n.sub.t] refers to the sample size. The
correlation coefficients are transformed through a Fisher procedure. The
estimated correlation coefficients are approximately normally
distributed, with mean and variance given by:
[[micro].sub.t] = 1/2ln (1 + [[rho].sup.t.sub.i,j]/1 -
[[rho].sub.i,j.sup.t])
[[rho].sub.t.sup.2] = 1/[n.sub.t] - 3 (3)
We also apply the likelihood ratio test to investigate the
significance of the groupwise correlations. Following Valdes (1997) and
Pindyck and Rotemberg (1990) the hypotheses under test can be stated as
follows:
[H.sub.0] : No groupwise correlations
[H.sub.1]: The null is not true
The test statistic: LR = -N log[R] is [chi square] distributed with
1/2q(q - 1) degrees of freedom. Where, [absolute value of R] is the
determinant of the correlation matrix, N is the number of observation in
the pooled sample, and q is the number of series being tested.
IV. RESULTS
Tables 1 and 2 present residuals correlations of stock returns
controlling for macroeconomic fundamentals and global shock. The
two-sample t-test under this scenario reveals that eight of the ten
pairs of residual correlations are significantly greater in the crisis
period. Further, the signs of correlations change from a strong negative
to strong positive; for the pairs of Malaysia-Thailand and the
Philippine-Thailand. However, Indonesian markets do not show significant
increase in the correlations in the crisis period compared to Malaysian
and the Philippine markets, after controlling for fundamentals.
Therefore, it appears that the contagion is present in the stock
markets. This is supported by rise in correlation in the crisis period,
even after controlling for fundamentals and a global shock in the other
markets. Furthermore, the LR test reveals statistically significant
group-wise correlations of residuals of stock returns for both tranquil
and crisis period.
Tables 3-4 present residual correlations for interest rates after
controlling for macro fundamentals and global shock. The two-sample
t-test shows that nine of the ten pairs of residual correlations are
significantly greater in the crisis period. The correlations for the
pairs, Indonesia-Korea, Indonesia-Thailand, Korea-Malaysia, and
Korea-Philippine change from mild negative to strong positive. This
implies that even after controlling for fundamentals and a global shock,
contagion seem to permeate in to the interest rate markets; and that it
increases in the crisis, compared to the tranquil period. Even though
the LR test fails to establish statistically significant group-wise
correlations for the residuals for the tranquil period; it shows
significant group-wise correlations for the crisis period.
For exchange rates, the cross-market correlations increase
significantly for seven pairs, from the tranquil to the crisis period
after controlling for macro fundamentals and global shock. These results
are presented in Tables 5 and 6. The LR test reveals statistically
significant group-wise correlations for the crisis period. In
particular, after controlling for the economic fundamentals, there is no
evidence of significant groupwise correlations for the tranquil period;
whereas it turns out to be very significant for the crisis period.
Tables 7 and 8 report the cross-market correlations for foreign
reserve, for both the tranquil and the crisis periods. The two-sample
t-test shows that cross-market correlations are significantly higher in
the crisis period. When economic fundamentals are not controlled, six of
the ten pairs of correlations increase significantly during the crisis
period. Nine of the ten pairs of residual correlations of foreign
reserves increased significantly in the crisis period. The LR test
reveals significant group-wise correlations for both the tranquil and
the crisis periods.
Sensitivity Analysis
Our finding that correlation coefficients increase significantly in
the crisis period compared to the tranquil period is notably obvious.
Various sensitivity tests were conducted whereby outliers were excluded
or sample periods in the data were changed. The results appear to be
relatively robust with respect to this test.
V. POLICY ISSUES
Crises can be transmitted either through temporary or permanent
channels. In the case of former channels, short run isolation
strategies, e.g., capital control can be effective in controlling
contagion. If crises are transmitted mainly through latter channels that
existed even before the crisis, then short run isolation strategies will
only delay countries adjustment to a shock. Since we find evidence of
contagion even after we control for macro control and global shocks, we
argue capital controls as an effective method in controlling contagion.
At the same time, policies should also aim at reducing countries'
vulnerability to long- run linkages through trade, macro economic
interdependence, and financial linkages. Even though we find evidence of
herding contagion in the Asian crisis, it is possible for the markets to
have long run linkages.
The 1990's Asian financial crisis has invoked strong interest
in the search for its causes and for a prescription for future guidance.
Most agree that lack of transparency, poor market structure and
excessive capital flows were at the center of the crisis. The
similarities across the victims were sufficient for developing common
guidelines. Policy however, must be tailored to the specific needs and
structure of a particular nation. Knowledge of the early warnings signs
can help policy makers initiate measures even prior to the onset of a
crisis, or to minimize its effects when it takes place.
Both the Mexican and the Asian crises point to the risk of currency
peg. Usually maintained to the US dollar, peg masks real fall in the
value of the domestic currency and thus makes it difficult to respond to
sudden shock like large capital outflows. Even so, peg is adopted for
non-market or political reasons. Strong external link facilitates
transmission of contagion via co-movement of exchange rates. While
foreign direct investment aids economic growth, speculative capital
inflow remains a major threat. Sound macro policy along with strict
accountability act as deterrent against speculation. As the recent
crises demonstrate, peg policy contains seeds of the crisis. In small
economies, peg increases financial instability, reduces export
competitiveness, widens trade deficit, and encourages speculative
attack. Large foreign debt hastens a crisis. In flexible rates regime
information availability makes the agents aware of the risk and allows
policymakers to respond, as needed.
Manipulative exchange rate to gain competitive advantage in the
short run is not uncommon, although it can be very risky in the long
run. In a non market exchange rate regime, trade tends to favor some
nations at the expense of others, threatening international monetary
stability and promoting "beggar thy neighbor policy" (Corsetti
et al., 1999). It happens by creating a parallel flow of capital to
balance the trade sector.
Sudden capital flows can trigger crisis, destabilizing the exchange
rate market. Capital outflows can be associated with dumping local
currency and lead to devaluation, as in Thailand. Capital outflow due to
exchange rate crisis is a symptom of fundamental problems, not a cause
of the crisis. Unlike Korea and Thailand, Malaysian achieved limited
success by capital control. Yet such control is not recommended because
the costs often exceed the benefits.
Strong banking sector helps maintain sound economic fundamentals.
When banks receive implicit government backing, a fragile financial
structure can result (Dekle and Kletzer 2001). Repressive financial
system also leads to total breakdown (Edward 2001). Anay distortions
cause market overreaction, promote herding behavior, and lower economic
activities far more than initially anticipated (Chang and Velasco 1999).
A strong bond market creates a sobering effect on exchange rates
volatility. Governments should promote macro and financial policies for
proper bond market development (Eichengreen et al. 2004). As part of
overall financial architecture, a sound banking system insulates an
economy from crisis. Independent regulatory bodies insure oversight and
implement rule of law. Strong viable financial institutions, with
limited regulation on capital flows and transparency can lead to the
desired outcomes and can help locate sources of financial fragility
(Cowan and Gregorio 2005; Kaplan and Rodrik 2001). Over-regulation
creates financial vulnerabilities and even causes sharp capital account
reversals. Cronyism only makes things worse. Sound 'financial
architecture,' can establish balance between exchange rate regimes,
capital flows, and currency crises. The Mexican, Asian, Russian, and
Brazilian crises point to the need for reform of financial architecture.
(7).
Trade diversification, by commodity and by regions, may shield from
the severit of contagious crisis by de-linking overly dependent trade
relation. A well planned trade expansion policy can also minimize the
risk of exposure to major external economic shock. Free trade zone or
common currency, like Euro from Australia to East Asia may be
beneficial.
Globalization and openness is desirable for benefits of the global
community but rush in to it will have undesirable side effects. Pressure
for economic liberalization will be ever greater in the future.
Increased openness adds linkages and more vulnerability in the short
run. Failure to address the changing global dynamics can produce the
exact opposite effect of free trade. Some nations may have taken
decisions when they were not ready.
VI. CONCLUSION
The empirical framework used in this paper supports herding in the
Asian crisis. When the crisis erupted in Thailand, investors quickly
pulled out of Asian economies without drawing any distinction between
them. The general consensus among the investors was, if Thailand was in
trouble, so would be other Asian "tigers".
The paper finds evidence of herding contagion among the East Asian
financial markets during the crisis period of 97. We investigated the
cross-country residual correlations among variables of currencies, stock
returns, interest rates, and foreign reserves after controlling for
macro fundamentals and global shocks. We find that correlations among
the financial markets increased significantly during the crisis,
compared to the tranquil period. Historically, some of the markets were
strongly correlated in the tranquil period and the correlations
increased significantly in the crisis periods. The evidence of herding
contagion leading to the 1997 Asian crisis seems strong.
Knowledge of the transmission of crisis, temporary or permanent is
helpful. Policy response would vary by the type of channel. The evidence
of contagion even after controlling for macro variables and global
shocks suggest that capital controls is likely to be more effective. We
find evidence of herding contagion in the Asian crisis but that does not
preclude the prospect of cross market long run linkages. The policy
should aim at reducing the vulnerability to a shock using both short run
adjustment of capital markets and long run adjustment of linkage
parameters. Monetary authorities need to monitor exchange rates
vis-a-vis balance of payments situation. Responsible fiscal policy can
help maintain appropriate interest rate which is a major force of
economic instability. These two policies must be aligned with a sensible
and internally consistent commercial policy to guide import and export
in response to emerging needs to insure both internal and external
balance.
References
Baig, T. and I. Goldfajn (1999), "Financial Market Contagion
in the Asian Crisis," IMF Working Paper, 46(2): 167-95.
Bartram, T. and Y. H. Wang (2005), "Another Look at the
Relationship Between Cross-Market Correlation and Volatility,"
Finance Research Letters, Vol. 2, 75-88.
Calvo S. and C. Reinhart (1996), "Capital Flows to Latin
America: Is there Evidence of Contagion Effect?" in Private Capital
Flows to Emerging Markets After the Mexican Crisis (G. A. Calvo, M.
Goldstein, and Eduard Hochreiter, eds.) Institute for International
Economics, Washington, D. C.
Chang R. and A. Velasco (1999), "Liquidity Crises in Emerging
Markets: Theory and Policy," NBER Working Papers 7272.
Corsetti, G, P. Pesenti, and N. Roubini (1999), "What Caused
the Asian Currency and Financial Crisis," Japan and the World
Economy, Vol. 11, 305-373.
Corsetti, G., M. Pericoli, and M. Sbracia, (2005), "Some
Contagion, Some Interdependence: More Pitfalls in Tests of Financial
Contagion," Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 24,
1177-1199.
Cowan K. and J. D. Gregorio (2005)," International Borrowing,
Capital Controls, and the Exchange Rate: Lessons from Chile," NBER
Working Papers 11382.
Dekle R. and Kletzer K. (2001), "Domestic Bank Regulation and
Financial Crises: Theory and Empirical Evidence from East Asia,"
NBER Working Papers 8322.
Dornbusch R., Y. C. Park, and C. Stijn (2000), "Contagion:
Understanding How it Spreads," World Bank Research Observer, Vol.
15, 177-97.
Eichengreen B. and P. Luengnaruemitchai (2004), "Why
Doesn't Asia Have Bigger Bond Markets," NBER Working Papers
10576.
Fratzscher M. (1998), "Why are Currency Crisis Contagious? A
Comparison of the Latin American Crisis of 1994-1995 and the Asian
Crisis of 1997-1998," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 134.
Forbes, K and R. Rigobon (2002), "No Contagion, only
Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market Comovement," Journal of
Finance 57 (5), 2223-2261.
Forbes K. and R. Rigobon (1999), "Measuring Contagion:
Conceptual and Empirical Issues," mimeo, MIT.
Kaplan E. and D. Rodrik (2001), "Did Malaysian Capital
Controls Work?" NBER Working Papers No 8142.
Khan, S., F. Islam, and S. Ahmed (2005), "The Asian Crisis: An
Economic Analysis of the Causes," Journal of Developing Areas, Vol.
39, 1, 169-90.
King, M. and S. Wadhwani (1990), "Transmission of Volatility
between Stock Markets," Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 3, 2,
5-33.
Lee, S. B. and K. J. Kim (1993), "Does the October 1987 Crash
Strengthen The Co-Movements Among National Sock Markets?" Review of
Financial Economies, Vol. 3, 89-102.
Masson P. (1998), "Contagion and Monsoonal Effects,
Spillovers, and Jump between Multiple Equilibria" IMF Working Paper
No. 98/142.
Pindyck, R. and J. Rotemberg (1990), "The Excess Co-Movement
of Commodity Prices," Economic Journal, Vol. 100, 4.
Radelet, S. and J. Sachs (1998), "The Onset of East Asian
Financial Crisis," NBER Working Papers 6680.
Sebastian E. (2001), "Exchange Rate Regimes, Capital Flows,
and Crisis Prevention" NBER Working Papers 8529.
Valdes, R. (1997), "Emerging Markets Contagion: Evidence and
Theory," Mimeo, MIT.
SALEHEEN KHAN
Minnesota State University, Mankato
FARIDUL ISLAM
Utah Valley University, Orem
KWANG WOO (KEN) PARK
Minnesota State University, Mankato
Notes
(1.) Dornbusch, Park, and Claessens (2000) define pure contagion as
comovement that cannot be explained on the basis of fundamentals or
global shocks.
(2.) See King & Wadhwani (1990), Lee and Kim (1993), Calvo and
Reinhart (1996), and Baig and Goldfajn (1999).
(3.) Rigobon and Forbes (1999) and Dornbusch, et al. (2000) also
defined contagion in similar manner.
(4.) For Tranquil period, the sample period refers to 1/1994-12/96
and for the crisis period it is 1/1997-1298.
(5.) All variables are in logs.
(7.) For more description on this issue, see Sebastian Edwards
(2001).
Table 1
Residuals Correlation (Stock Returns) Tranquil Period: (1/94-12/96)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea .225
Malaysia .677 .256
Philippines .473 .190 .493
Thailand .158 .286 -.098 -.093
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level
Macroeconomic fundamentals and global shock is controlled for
LR Test statistic = 39.321 **
Table 2
Residuals Correlation (Stock Returns) Crisis period: (1/97-12/99)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea .494 **
Malaysia .478 .691 **
Philippines .477 .711 ** .903 **
Thailand .618 ** .703 ** .634 ** .705 **
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level
Macroeconomic fundamentals and global shock is controlled for
LR Test statistic = 119.059 **
Table 3
Residuals Correlation (Interest Rate) Tranquil Period: (1/94-12/96)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea -.124
Malaysia .195 -.079
Philippines .207 -.018 .051
Thailand -.375 .268 .117 .208
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level
LR Test statistic = 15.049
Table 4
Residuals Correlation (Interest Rate) Crisis period: 1/97-12/99)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea .467 **
Malaysia .099 .489 **
Philippines .457 ** .793 ** .671 **
Thailand .458 ** .723 ** .614 ** .782 **
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level LR Test
statistic = 96.763 **
Table 5
Residuals Correlation (Exchange Rate) Tranquil Period: (1/94-12/96)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea -.043
Malaysia .201 .409
Philippines .263 .098 .253
Thailand .057 .207 .192 -.003
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level LR Test
statistic = 13.38
Table 6
Residuals Correlation (Exchange Rate) Crisis period: (1/97-12/99)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea .293 **
Malaysia .275 .669 **
Philippines -.143 .116 .444 **
Thailand .313 .698 ** .798 ** .560 **
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level;
LR Test statistic = 84.036 **
Table 7
Residuals Correlation (Foreign Reserve) Tranquil Period: (1/94-12/96)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea -.367
Malaysia -.167 -.073
Philippines .640 -.329 .130
Thailand -.224 .354 -.313 -.274
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level;
LR Test statistic = 42.083 **
Table 8
Residuals Correlation (Exchange Rate) Crisis period: (1/97-12/99)
Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines
Korea .398
Malaysia .478 ** .627 **
Philippines .670 .521 ** .532 **
Thailand .345 ** .267 .105 ** .355 **
(**) indicates statistical significance at the 1% level;
LR Test statistic = 55.1761 **