首页    期刊浏览 2025年03月03日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Trade, foreign direct investment and economic growth in selected South Asian countries.
  • 作者:Dhakal, Dharmendra ; Pradhan, Gyan ; Upadhyaya, Kamal
  • 期刊名称:Indian Journal of Economics and Business
  • 印刷版ISSN:0972-5784
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:June
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Indian Journal of Economics and Business
  • 摘要:This paper examines the dynamic relationships between foreign direct investment (FDI), trade and economic growth in India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka with the help of a VAR model and data covering 1971-2006. Before estimating the model, the time series properties of the data are diagnosed. The estimated results indicate that in India, FDI tends to cause economic growth by improving trade but there is a weak direct relationship between FDI and GDP. In Pakistan, FDI appears to cause trade but trade is not a significant factor in economic growth. In Sri Lanka, very little effect of FDI and trade on GDP is detected.
  • 关键词:Economic growth;Foreign investments;Indian foreign relations;International trade;Pakistani foreign relations;Sri Lankan foreign relations;Value-added resellers;VARs (Value added resellers)

Trade, foreign direct investment and economic growth in selected South Asian countries.


Dhakal, Dharmendra ; Pradhan, Gyan ; Upadhyaya, Kamal 等


Abstract

This paper examines the dynamic relationships between foreign direct investment (FDI), trade and economic growth in India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka with the help of a VAR model and data covering 1971-2006. Before estimating the model, the time series properties of the data are diagnosed. The estimated results indicate that in India, FDI tends to cause economic growth by improving trade but there is a weak direct relationship between FDI and GDP. In Pakistan, FDI appears to cause trade but trade is not a significant factor in economic growth. In Sri Lanka, very little effect of FDI and trade on GDP is detected.

INTODUCTION

In the past, South Asian countries, like many developing countries, adopted a policy of either restricting or discouraging foreign direct investment (FDI) by the multinational corporations (MNCs). The main reason behind such a policy was the fear that MNCs could influence the economic policies as well as the politics in host countries. Therefore, until the early 1980s, most countries in this region regulated FDI by limiting foreign ownership of local firms, and requiring foreign firms to use local resources and employment as a precondition. Such inward looking policies, combined with the policy of discouraging FDI inflows, contributed to the stagnation of South Asian economies for several decades. In contrast, during the same period, countries in East and Southeast Asia saw rapid growth, credited mainly to their open and liberal foreign trade and FDI inflow policies. By the late 1980s, many developing countries began to realize the significance of trade and FDI in economic growth. Consequently, they became more open to international trade and more receptive to FDI inflows. Developing economies even encouraged FDI inflows by providing various incentives to MNCs to move into their countries. In keeping with this trend, South Asian countries also liberalized their economies hoping to attract more FDI. This liberalization included less restrictive policies with regard to FDI, reformed financial systems, industrial policies conducive to private investment, and other institutional reforms.

There has been tremendous growth in FDI flows around the world in the past three decades. For instance, FDI flows increased from $53 billion in 1980 to more than $600 billion in 2007. Historically, developed countries have received the majority of the share of world FDI. At their peak in 2007, developed economies received 80 per cent of world FDI. More recently, FDI flows to developed countries have slumped while those to developing countries have surged. While FDI flows to developed countries fell by 16 per cent in 2004, they increased to the Asia and the Pacific region by 55 per cent.

THE FDI, TRADE AND GROWTH NEXUS

FDI is considered to be a growth-enhancing factor for several reasons. First, FDI serves as an important complement to the local economy and helps to stimulate growth of output of the host country. Trevino and Upadhyaya (2003) suggest that the impact of FDI on growth is expected to be twofold. First, through capital accumulation in the host country, FDI can be expected to increase economic growth by encouraging the incorporation of new inputs and foreign technologies in the production function of the host country (Dunning, 1993; Borensztein et al., 1998). Second, FDI augments the level of knowledge in the host country through labor training and skill acquisition (De Mello, 1997). Capital-market disequilibrium theory suggests that capital in the form of private investment will flow to those countries where the risk-adjusted rate of return is the highest. In keeping with the study by Burnside and Dollar (2000) regarding foreign aid, it has been shown that in transition economies, FDI tends to flow to those countries that have pursued market reform (Trevino, Daniels and Arbelaez, 2002). Capital-market disequilibrium theory suggests that capital in the form of private investment will flow to those countries where the risk-adjusted rate of return is the highest.

FDI flows to a host country depend on several factors. One important factor that helps to attract the inflow of FDI to a host country is its market size as measured by real GDP. The larger the size of the market in a country, the more the FDI inflow is likely to be. The inflow of FDI in turn spurs higher economic growth which attracts more FDI. Theoretically, the causality may run in both directions. In other words, the higher the economic growth, the more the inflow of FDI; and the more the inflow of FDI, the greater the growth rate of the economy.

Openness to international trade, defined as the ratio of the sum of exports and imports to GDP, is considered to be an important factor that determines economic growth. Countries that are open to trade can take advantage of efficiencies based on comparative advantage. This enhances exports as well as the level of output which leads to higher economic growth. Further, export expansion allows firms in exporting countries to take advantage of scale economies. Endogenous growth theory suggests that export-led economic growth can increase long run growth by allowing innovation growth in research and development. Dhakal et al. (2007) show that openness is an important determinant in attracting FDI. According to their study, multinational corporations prefer to move their production bases to countries where it is relatively easy to import intermediate products as well as to distribute (export) output to foreign markets. This suggests that trade also helps to grow the economy by attracting more FDI.

The influence of trade and FDI on economic growth has been discussed widely in the economic literature. Some earlier studies see exports as a main source of economic growth that helps developing countries break away from the vicious circle of poverty. In later studies, exports are seen as an important source of foreign exchange earnings necessary for developing countries for importing high-tech machinery that are crucial for competitiveness and economic growth (McKinnon, 1964). Coe and Helpman (1995) argue that trade improves domestic productivity from the spillover effects of foreign research and development. New growth theory also provides a link between trade and economic growth.

On the other hand, FDI plays an important role in providing much needed capital and technology to developing countries from industrialized countries (Saggi, 2002). By extending the hypothesis advanced by Bhagwati (1973) and Balasubramanyam et al. (1996), some studies find that growth-enhancing FDI are stronger in countries with more liberal trade regimes. The interaction of FDI with trade is likely to have a positive impact on economic growth in two ways. First, liberal trade policy in host countries attracts higher levels of FDI inflows because such policies not only allow FDI to take advantages of cheap labor but also allow a larger market. Second, the neutrality of incentives associated with exports allows investors to take advantage of economies of scale and better capacity utilization, making FDI more productive. Moreover, exports promote technological innovation and create a favorable environment for technology spillovers from FDI.

Several empirical studies have shown a positive impact of FDI inflows on economic growth of the host country. For example, Borensztein, Gregorio and Lee (1998) study the effect of FDI on economic growth in 69 developing countries over two decades and find that FDI is an important vehicle for the transfer of technology, contributing more to growth than domestic investment. Similarly, Bosworth and Collins (1999) conduct a comprehensive study on FDI, covering 58 developing countries in Latin America, Asia and Africa during 1978-1995, Their findings suggest that a one dollar increase in capital inflow (of all types) is associated with a fifty-cent increase in domestic investment. In addition, FDI appears to bring about a one-for-one increase in domestic investment. Thus, FDI appears to have a stronger impact on domestic investment than do loans or portfolio investment. In a related study on the effect of FDI on total factor productivity growth, Ericsson and Irandoust (2000) find that FDI and output are causally related in the long run in Norway and Sweden.

The above discussion indicates that economic growth, FDI and trade are closely related with one another. Intuitively, what we see is that they affect one another but we do not know in what direction the causality runs. The purpose of this paper is to examine the causal relationship between real GDP, FDI and trade.

MODEL SPECIFICATION

In order to evaluate the relationship between economic growth, trade and FDI we consider the following equation:

Y = f (FD, TR) (1)

where Y is real gross domestic product (GDP), FD is real foreign direct investment and TR is real trade, defined as the sum of exports and imports. According to the economic literature, there could be a bi-directional relation between GDP and trade. On the one hand, trade has a positive impact on GDP because more trade implies more economic activity that adds to GDP. On the other hand, some view the GDP of foreign countries as a proxy for the domestic market. That is, a larger GDP represents bigger purchasing power which results in more trade. Similarly, FDI is assumed to have a positive relationship with GDP. That is, FDI is expected to be growth-enhancing (De Mello, 1997). As mentioned above, FDI acts as an agent of international transfer of technology (Borensztein et al., 1998; Balasubramanyam et al., 1996). Foreign firms are considered more productive than domestic firms (De Gregorio, 1992; Borensztein et al., 1998) and tend to generate highly beneficial effects on domestic investment. Bosworth and Collins (1999) report nearly a one-to-one relationship between FDI and domestic investment.

The above findings suggest that a thorough understanding of the relationship between economic growth, openness and FDI is necessary to analyze the sources of the dynamic relationship among the variables under consideration. Therefore, we develop a trivariate vector autoregression (VAR) model to examine the possible sources of association and dynamic linkages between GDP, FDI and trade in India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka. The logic behind applying VAR modeling is that we do not have any a priori information regarding the endogeneity and exogeneity of the variables. Since VAR models do not impose any restriction and assume that all variables are endogenous (Sims, 1980) variable, they are better than single equation models. We also conduct the Granger causality test and variance decomposition to establish a causal relationship between FDI and economic growth. This method of analysis allows us to capture the short-run dynamics between the variables.

We use annual data from 1970 to 2006. All the data have been obtained from the World Bank's 2008 World Development Indicators CD-ROM, and are expressed in real terms.

ESTIMATION AND RESULTS

As discussed above, the theoretical relationship between FDI, GDP and trade may run in one or both directions. Therefore, we specify the following unrestricted multivariate VAR model. The model consists of FD, Y and TR and is expressed as follows.

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)

where [[beta].sub.0t], [[delta].sub.0t] and [[gamma].sub.0t] are constant terms, and FD, Y and TR are all expressed in growth form at time t calculated as the first-difference of the log of the respective variables. The term at is a vector of innovations that may be contemporaneously correlated with one another, but are uncorrelated withtheir own lagged values and uncorrelated with all of the right-hand side variables, i. e., [[epsilon].sub.t] ~ IN(0, [SIGMA]). Using this VAR model, we attempt to identify the causal relation (in the Granger (1969) sense) among the variables.

Since time series data may be non-stationary and may give rise to spurious associations, it is important to test for the stationarity of the data series and the possible long-term relationships among the variables in the system. Therefore, before estimating the VAR model, we conduct tests to check the stationarity of each variable and the existence of long-term relationship between the variables.

At the beginning of the empirical analysis, we conduct a unit root test to examine the time series properties of the three variables using the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Philips-Perron (PP) tests. The unit root test results are reported in Table 1. The results show that most of the variables in the system are nonstationary at the log level. However, the first-difference of each of the variables is reported significant. A similar pattern is observed in the case of the PP test where all variables are found to be integrated of order one or I(1).

Since the variables in the system were all I(1), and may possess some kind of long-run relationship, we apply the multivariate cointegration technique developed by Johansen and Juselius (1990) to test for cointegration among the variables. Table 2 reports the results of the multivariate cointegration analysis. It provides evidence of not rejecting the null hypothesis of zero cointegrating vectors at the 1 per cent level. Therefore, the existence of a long-run relationship does not find statistical support in all three countries over the period under examination.

The next logical step involves an estimation of the VAR model as specified in equation (2). Before estimating the VAR model, we find the appropriate lag length for each model using the Akaike (1974) information criterion (AIC). The AIC criterion is defined as:

AIC(k) = Min{In ([sigma] + 2k/T) | k = 0,1, ..., m} (3)

where T is the sample size, and k is the number of parameters. From the estimated results of AIC, the optimal 1ag lengths are identified as 8 for India and Pakistan, and 5 for Sri Lanka.

Next, we employ the VAR model to analyze the short-run effects among these macroeconomic variables. As is known, the variance decompositions (VDCs) show the proportion of forecast error variance for each variable that is attributable to its own innovations, and the shocks to the other system variables. The transmission of innovations among variables may occur via many channels. This helps to explain the strength of the exogeneity of the variable. The VDCs (1, 5 and 10 years) are presented in Table 4.

India. As reported in Table 4, in the fifth year 77.7 per cent of the variability in DFD (first difference of FD) is explained by its own innovations, while after 10 years only 66.3 per cent of the variability is explained by its own innovations. Similarly, 20.75 per cent of the variability is explained by innovations in the DY (first difference of Y) shock, and 12.95 per cent in the DTR (first difference of TR) shock.

For the DY variable, its own shocks account for only 48.29 per cent of the forecast variance for the fifth year. After ten years, only 27.42 per cent of the variation is explained by its own variation, 8.6 per cent by the DFD shock, and almost 64 per cent by the TR shock.

For the DTR variable, its own shocks account for only 56.1 per cent of the forecast variance for the fifth year. After ten years, it drops to 52,5 per cent; 34.75 per cent of the variation in DTR is explained by the variation in DFD, and 12.68 per cent of the variation in DTR comes from the DY shock.

In the long run, the magnitudes of the explained variability of DFD remain relatively close to the medium-run period but drop significantly for DY and DTR. DFD in the medium term is least explained by DTR. However, in the long run, its explanatory power increases significantly. We also observe that there is an indirect effect on DY via TR.

Pakistan. The high DTR variability comes from movements in DFD shocks. In the long run, almost 50 per cent of the variation in DFD comes from the DY shock. DTR explains only 5 per cent of variation in DFD both in the medium term and long term. The results also indicate that about 30 per cent of the variation in DY is explained by DFD, and DTR only explains about 6 per cent of the variation. Even though the forecast variance of DTR does not seem to be important in explaining the variance of the other variables, it explains about 64 per cent of its own variation. The rest of the variation in DTR is explained by DFD.

Sri Lanka. In the medium term the DFD shock explains 84 per cent of the variance but in the long term it drops to about 72 per cent. DY and DTR combine explains about 27% of variation in DFD. Similarly, 86 per cent of the variation in DYis explained by its own innovation and only 9.45 per cent and 4 per cent are explained by DFD and DTR. DTR explains about 63 per cent of its variation from its own shock. However, both DFD and DTR combined explain more than 35 per cent of the variation in DTR.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

During the last decade or so, developing countries in Asia witnessed strong growth in FDI and trade. India, in particular, witnessed unprecedented growth in FDI, trade and economic growth. Using multivariate VAR models, we analyze the dynamic relationships between FDI, trade and economic growth in India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka using data covering 1970-2006. To avoid possible spurious results, we test the time series properties of the data by using ADF and PP tests. We also conduct cointegration tests to rule out long-term relationships between the variables. The empirical findings indicate that most of the variables are integrated of order one. The cointegration tests indicate no long-run equilibrium relationships among DFD, DY and DTR. The forecast error variance decomposition analysis reveals information about the proportion of the movements in sequence due to a variable's "own" shocks versus shocks from other variables. The variance decomposition results indicate some very interesting results. In the case of India, FDI appears to cause economic growth by improving trade but there is a weaker direct relationship between FDI and GDP. In Pakistan, FDI causes trade but trade is not a significant factor in economic growth--only about 6 per cent of the variance in GDP is explained by trade. Finally, in Sri Lanka, only a small per centage of the variance in the variables under consideration is explained by innovations in these variables.

References

Akaike, H., (1974), "A New Look at the Statistical Model Identification". IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-19, 716-723.

Balasubramanyam, V. N., M. Salisu, and D. Sapford (1996), "Foreign Direct Investment and Growth in EP Countries and IP Countries," The Economic Journal, 106: 1, 92-112.

Barro, R. J. (1997), Getting It Right: Market and Choices in a Free Society, The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Bhagwati, J. N. (1973), "The Theory of Emerging Growth: Further Application," in Michael B. Connolly and Alexander K. Swoboda (eds), International Trade and Money, University of Toronto Press, Toronto.

Borensztein, E., J. Gregorio, and J. W. Lee (1998), "How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Growth?", Journal of International Economics, 45: 1, 115-135.

Bosworth, B. P. and S. M. Collins (1999), "Capital Flows to Developing Economies: Implications for Saving and Investment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1, 143-169.

Bruno, M. and Easterly, W. (1998), "Inflation Crises and Long Run Growth," Journal of Monetary Economics, 41: 1, 3-26.

Burnside, C. and D. Dollar (2000), "Aid, Policies and Growth," The American Economic Review, 90: 5, 847-868.

Coe, David T. and Elhanan Helpman (1995), "International R&D Spillovers," European Economic Review, 39, 859-887.

De Gregorio, Jose, (1992), "Economic Growth in Latin America," Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 39(1), 59-84.

De Mello, L. R. (1997), "Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries and Growth: a Selective Survey," The Journal of Development Studies, 34: 2, 1-34.

Dhakal, Dharmendra, Franklin Mixon, and Kamal Upadhyaya (2007), "Foreign Direct Investment and Transition Economies: Empirical Evidence from Panel Data Estimator," Economic Bulletin, 6: 33, 1-9.

Dunning, J. H. (1993), Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy, Wokingham: Addison-Wesley.

Ericsson, J. and M. Irandoust (2000), "On the Causality Between Foreign Direct Investment and Output: a Comparative Study," The International Trade Journal, 14: 4, 1-26.

Granger, C. (1969), "Investigating Causal Relation by Econometric and Cross-Sectional Method," Econometrica, 37,424-438.

Engle, R. and C. Granger (1987), "Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing," Econometrica, 55,251-276.

Johansen, S. and K. Juselius, (1990), "Some Structural Hypotheses in a Multivariate Cointegration Analysis of the Purchasing Power Parity and the Uncovered Interest Parity for UK," Discussion Papers, 90-05, University of Copenhagen. Department of Economics.

McKinnon, R. I. (1964), "Foreign Exchange Constraints in Economic Development and Efficient Aid Allocation," The Economic Journal, 74, 388-409.

Nelson, C. and C. Plosser (1982), "Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Some Evidence and Implication," Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, 130-162.

Philips, P. and P. Perron (1988), "Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression," Biometrica, 75, 335-346.

Saggi, Kamal (2002), "Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and International Technology Transfer: a Survey," World Bank Research Observer, 17: 2, 191-235.

Sims. C. A. (1980), "Macroeconomics and Reality", Econometrica, 48: 1, 1-48.

Slywester, K. (2005), "Foreign Direct Investment, Growth and Income Equality in Less Developed Countries," International Review of Applied Economics, 19: 3, 289-300.

Trevino, Len J., John D. Daniels, and Harvey Arbelaez (2002), "Market Reform and Foreign Direct Investment in Latin America: An Empirical Investigation," Transnational Corporations, 11: 1, 29-48.

Trevino, Len J. and Kamal Upadhyaya (2003), "Foreign Aid, FDI and Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Countries," Transnational Corporations, 12: 2, 119-135.

DHARMENDRA DHAKAL

Tennessee State University, U.S.A.

GYAN PRADHAN

Eastern Kentucky University, U.S.A.

KAMAL UPADHYAYA

University of New Haven, U.S.A.
Table 1
Unit Root Test

                           ADF                         PP

                             First                       First
               Log level     Difference    Log level     Difference

India      FD  -2.345437     -3.636298 **  -3.202373     -8.276264 *
           Y   -1.890715     -6.544988 *   -1.800454     -7.529541 *
           TR   0.026669     -5.299345 *    0.206818     -5.289699 *

Pakistan   FD  -3.2011070    -13.73008 *   -2.478720     -13.73008 *
           Y   -0.960479     -4.704909 *   -1.431875     -4.702186 *
           TR  -3.588611 **  -4.606025 *   -3.599697 **  -4.702186 *

Sri Lanka  FD  -2.463322     -6.656675 *   -2.442728     -6.732651 *
           Y   -2.753012     -5.116600 *   -3.051719     -5.082504 *
           TR  -3.986823 **  -6.227812 *   -4.004919 **  -6.242624 *

All variables are in log form. * and ** indicate significant at
1 and 5 per cent critical levels

Table 2
Johansen's Co-Integration Test (Variables: log FD, log Y,
log TR)

                                                  India

                                                  Trace
[H.sub.0]                      Eigen Value      Statistic

r [less than or equal to] 0     0.320738        20.43641
r [less than or equal to] 1     0.191732         7.67378
r [less than or equal to] 2     0.019484        0.649307

                                                Pakistan

                                                  Trace
[H.sub.0]                      Eigen Value      Statistic

r [less than or equal to] 0     0.499618        35.17973
r [less than or equal to] 1     0.289697        12.33110
r [less than or equal to] 2     0.031112        1.043015

                                                Sri Lanka

[H.sub.0]                                         Trace
                               Eigen Value      Statistic

r [less than or equal to] 0     0.486444        32.54009
r [less than or equal to] 1     0.263468        10.54895
r [less than or equal to] 2     0.013767        0.457462

                                   1%                         1%
                                Critical     Max Eigen     Critical
[H.sub.0]                         Value      Statistic      Value

r [less than or equal to] 0     35.43817     12.76268      25.86121
r [less than or equal to] 1     19.93711     7.024422      18.52001
r [less than or equal to] 2     6.634897     0.649307      6.634897

                                   1%                         1%
                                Critical     Max Eigen     Critical
[H.sub.0]                         Value      Statistic      Value

r [less than or equal to] 0     35.43817     22.84863      25.86121
r [less than or equal to] 1     19.93711     11.28809      18.52001
r [less than or equal to] 2     6.634897     1.043015      6.634897

                                   1%                         1%
[H.sub.0]                       Critical     Max Eigen     Critical
                                  Value      Statistic      Value

r [less than or equal to] 0     35.43817     21.99114      25.86121
r [less than or equal to] 1     19.93711     10.09149      18.52001
r [less than or equal to] 2     6.634897     0.457462      6.634897

* indicates rejection of the null hypothesis at 0.01 critical
level. Test statistic indicates no co-integrating  equation at
0.01 level

Table 3
Granger Causality/Block Exogeneity Wald Test

Pakistan                 India                  Pakistan
Wald Test               Chi-sq       P-value     Chi-sq     P-value

DY =/=> DFD           4.183863       0.8402    11.76112     0.1622
DTR =/=> DFD          6.296528       0.6141    26.46637 *   0.0009
DY & DTR =/=> DFD    11.55238        0.7742    39.37982 *   0.0010
DFD =/=> DY          24.13167 *      0.0022    34.40316 *   0.0000
DTR =/=> DY          22.05014 *      0.0048    25.54519 *   0.0013
DFD & DTR =/=> DY    37.28374 *      0.0019    53.01118 *   0.0000
DFD =/=> DTR         13.467292 ***   0.0968     8.498589    0.3863
DY =/=> DTR          18.43635 *      0.6182     6.277244    0.6162
DFD & DY =/=> DTR    22.83660 ***    0.1182    11.73827     0.7618

Pakistan                    Sri           Lanka
Wald Test                 Chi-sq         P-value

DY =/=> DFD                 3.117808     0.6818
DTR =/=> DFD                8.174206     0.1469
DY & DTR =/=> DFD           13.73361     0.1855
DFD =/=> DY                 3.421579     0.6353
DTR =/=> DY                 1.683537     0.8910
DFD & DTR =/=> DY           4.059683     0.9446
DFD =/=> DTR            10,24224 ***     0.0687
DY =/=> DTR                 7.048786     0.2170
DFD & DY =/=> DTR          19.83910 **   0.0308

=/=> indicates does not cause in Granger sense All variables are
in log form. *, ** and *** indicate  significant at 1, 5, and 10
per cent levels

Table 4
Variance Decomposition

                India                        Pakistan
          Variance Decomposition       Variance Decomposition
                of DFD                       of DFD

Period        DFD       DY      DTR      DFD         DY      DTR

1           100.00     0.00     0.00   100.00       0.00     0.00
5            77.71    12.64     9.66    48.84      47.39     3.78
10           66.30    20.75    12.95    46.07      49.14     4.79

             Variance Decomposition       Variance Decomposition
                    of DY                        of DY

period        DFD      DY        DTR      DFD        DY       DTR

1             0.00   100.00     0.00     0.00     100.00     0.00
5             5.03    48.29    46.68    15.69      79.89     4.42
10            8.61    27.42    63.97    28.72      65.41     5.87

              Variance Decomposition       Variance Decomposition
                     of DTR                       of DTR

period         DFD      DY      DTR      DFD         DY       DTR

1             0.00     0.00   100.00     0.00       0.00   100.00
5            38.20     5.68    56.12    36.77       0.29    62.94
10           34.76    12.68    52.57    35.83       0.21     6196

                Sri Lanka

            Variance Decomposition
                   of DFD

Period        DFD         DY        DTR

1           100.00        0.00     0.00
5            84.83        3.76    11.41
10           72.36       12.36    15.28

          Variance Decomposition
          of DY

period      DFD         DY        DTR

1             0.00      100.00     0.00
5             8.01       88.44     3.55
10            9.46       86.53     4.02

          Variance Decomposition
          of DTR

period      DFD         DY        DTR

1             0.00        0.00   100.00
5            17.03       10.94    72.03
10           17.13       19.61    63.25
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有