Does the government size affect output growth in developing countries? Evidence from selected ASEAN countries.
Kaushik, Neetu ; Dhakal, Dharmendra ; Upadhyaya, Kamal 等
Abstract
This paper studies the effect of government size economic growth in
selected AEAN countries. A standard growth model is developed in which
the output growth is a function of the size of government, growth in
labor supply and total stock of capital as percentage of GDP. The
estimated results suggest that increase in the capital stock is the
primary factor that helps to grow the economy. Government size did not
have either positive or negative effect on output growth. Growth rate of
labor does not affect the output growth in Thailand, Malaysia, and
Indonesia. In case of the Philippines labor supply seems to have a
negative effect on output growth probably because of excess labor supply
in relation to other inputs.
JEL Category: E61, H50, O40
Key words: government size, economic growth, ASEAN countries,
growth model
I. INTRODUCTION
The relationship between the size of government and economic growth
has been a debatable issue for several decades. In early fifties and
sixties there was some consensus among development economists as well
the policy makers that an ideal system is a mixed economic system in
which the government sector requires to play an important role in the
economy. Particularly, in developing countries where there was not
enough infrastructure development the government had to play an
important role in developing modern modes of transportations as well as
communications. In addition to developing the infrastructures some
governments are also engaged in supplying the basic goods as well as
services to the general public at some fair price to ensure that the
people at the margin have access to the basic needs.
By early eighties it was realized that mixed economic system with
big government sector essentially distorts the production as well as
consumption in the economy which eventually slows down the pace of
growth. That is why the last two decades of twentieth century saw a
massive privatization in developing countries. The industrialized
countries, particularly the USA and the United Kingdom started to reduce
the size of government arguing that the smaller government with less
economic regulation is much better for growth of an economy. The
recession that started in 2008 brought the issue of role of government
again in the forefront. Many social scientists now have started arguing
that we need a bigger government in order to sustain economic growth
(Madrick, 2008; Sachs 2009). In view of this controversy in this paper
we estimate and analyze the effect of government size on economic growth
in selected ASEAN nations (Association of South East Asian Nations)
namely, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and Thailand. We hope that
the findings of this paper will shed some light on the relationship
between government size and economic growth in Southeast Asian
countries.
II. REVIEW OF LITERATURE
As indicated above the issue relating to the government size and
economic growth has been an issue of contention for a long time. Tomas
Hobbes in 1651 described life without government was "nasty,
brutish, and short" and argued that the law and order provided by
government was a necessary component of civilized life (Gwartney et al.
1998). Obviously, Hobbes was indicating that the role of government in
maintaining the law and order, protecting the property rights smooth
functioning of the judicial system was important in a society not only
in maintaining a civilized society but also to enhance economic growth.
In other words, secure property rights, contracts enforcements and a
stable monetary regime provide the foundation for a smooth operation in
a market economy (Gwartney et al. 1998).
In addition to ensuring the smooth operation of market economy the
government also provides stimulus for economic growth by providing
quality infrastructures and public goods which market often fails to
supply. There is no contention on the provision of public goods by the
government either in well-developed western nations or in developing
countries of Asia or Africa. Although the infrastructures such as roads,
railways, and public utilities can be supplied by the private sector but
because of its high cost to build and the free rider problem the private
sector shy away from such ventures forcing the governments to provide
these services.
Social services such as providing social security to the
marginalized group of the society, health care and education for the low
income people of the society have become other responsibilities of the
government. In most developed countries expenses for providing these
services have been skyrocketing over last few decades which is bloating
the government budgets leading to a continuous growth of the government
size. Often it is argued that such expenses do help the economy to grow
by creating additional demand for goods and services through multiplier
effect. But the effectiveness of such government programs on economic
growth is still an empirical question.
There are several empirical studies on the government expenditure
(size of government) and its relationship with economic growth. The
findings of these researches are inconsistent. In other words, some
researchers find government size negatively affecting the economic
growth and other find this not to be true. A careful look, however,
reveal that the findings that these differences are due to the measure
of government size and type of countries studies e.g. rich and poor
(Bergh and Henrekson, 2011). When looked at the industrialized countries
there is almost a unanimous consensus that the size of government and
per capita real GDP growth are negatively associated (Di Pietro et al.,
1993) and it is also found that during the economic downturn the
government size grows (Bergh and Henrekson, 2011).
Using a systematic analysis on the relationship between increases
in spending, lower rates of economic growth, high unemployment,
increases in deficits and inflation among 19 nations Cameron (1982)
concludes that high levels of spending and large increases in spending
have not caused stagflation. In addition, his conclusion also suggests
that a large and expanding welfare state is beneficial to the market
economy. Ram (1986) in his seminal paper which uses a cross-sectional
and time series data for 1960-70 and 1970-80 concludes that government
size has a positive effect on economic performance and growth. He
further concludes that government size has a positive externality effect
on the rest of the economy and the factor productivity was higher in the
government sector than in the rest of the economy during 1960s.
Landau (1993) in his cross-country analyses with 48 countries added
control variables for education, energy consumption and some dummies for
geographical variables and finds a negative relationship between
government spending and economic growth. Likewise, Marlow (1986), based
on his study of 19 countries for a period of data from 1960 to 1980 also
argues that the public sector size retards overall economic growth.
There is relatively few research on this issue with developing
countries data set. One such study is by Landau (1986) which essentially
is an extension of his earlier work mentioned above. In this study he
used 96 country cross-sectional data from 1960 to 1980 and finds a
negative relationship between the government size and economic growth in
LGCs. Guseh (1997) in his study differentiates the effects of government
size on economic growth across political and economic systems in
developing countries. The results show that growth in government size
has negative effects on economic growth, but the negative effects are
three times as great in nondemocratic socialist systems as in democratic
market systems.
III. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND, METHODOLOGY AND DATA
In order to estimate the effect of government size on economic
growth the following model is developed, which is based on the classical
growth model:
Y = f(K, L) (1)
where, Y = total output (real GDP).
K = capital stock in the economy
L = total amount of labor in the economy
Assuming a constant returns to scale an increase in either the
amount of capital or number of labor will increase the production of
total output in the economy. Once we add the government spending in
above equation we have:
Y - f(K, L, G) (2)
where, G = Government spending. The statistical form of equation
(1) is as follows:
Y = [c.sub.0] + [c.sub.1] K + [c.sub.2] L + [c.sub.3] G + e (3)
In equation (3) as indicated above [c.sub.1] and [c.sub.2] are
expected to be positive. The variable of interest is G. If it's
coefficient [c.sub.3] is positive and statistically significant
government size has a positive effect on economic growth, if it is
negative and statistically significant it has a negative effect on
economic growth. If it is not statistically significant the size of
government has no effect on economic growth. In equation (3) e is random
error term.
The first difference of log of Y gives the real GDP growth rate and
log of L gives the labor growth rate in the economy. Once these
variables are converted into growth form equation (3) can be written as:
y = [c.sub.0] + [c.sub.1] k + [c.sub.2] l + [c.sub.3] g + e (4)
where, y = real output growth rate
k = total capital stock as percentage of GDP
I = labor force growth rate
g = government spending as percentage of GDP
As indicated above this study is conducted for four ASEAN countries
namely, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand. Annual time
series data from 1976 to 2012 is used. All the data are derived from the
WDI of the World Bank.
IV. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS AND ANALYSIS
Estimations of equation (4) are reported in Table 1. In the initial
estimation an autocorrelation problem was detected for both the
Philippines and Thailand. In order to eliminate the autocorrelation
problem an AR(1) model is estimated for these two countries. All the
estimations seem fit well in terms of the sign of the coefficients of
the variables, coefficient of determination, Durbin Watson values and F
statistics.
Few interesting findings are observed from the estimated results.
First, in all the estimations the coefficient of capital growth is
positive and statistically significantly different from zero. This
finding is consistent with the conventional wisdom that in developing
countries there is a scarcity of capital, therefore, the marginal
product of capital is positive. Indeed our estimated results suggest
that if the percentage of capital as GDP is increased by 10 percent the
real GDP grows anywhere from 2.1 to 3.8 percent in these countries.
Second, the estimated coefficient of labor growth shows that an increase
in the growth of labor has no effect in output growth in Indonesia,
Malaysia and Thailand. In these countries a significant percentage of
labor force are employed in agriculture where the marginal product of
labor is almost zero or even negative. Indeed in case of the Philippines
the marginal product of labor is negative presumably because of excess
labor use and disguised unemployment.
As indicated above, the coefficient of g i.e. the government size
is the main focus of this study. The estimated results could not detect
any statistically significant effect of the size of government on the
output growth in any of the country under study except for Indonesia.
Even in case of Indonesia the coefficient is marginally significant
(only at 11% critical level). In order to see if there is any lagged
effect we estimated the model with one and two years lag of the
government size variable but the result did not change. Based on the
coefficients of the government size in all the estimations it can be
concluded that the size of government expenditure has neither positive
nor negative effect in these four ASEAN countries. In order to see if
there is any lagged effect we estimated the model with one and two years
lag of the government size variable but the result did not change.
V. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
This paper studies the effect of government size on economic growth
in selected AEAN countries namely, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines,
and Thailand. A standard growth model is developed in which the output
growth is a function of the size of government, growth in labor supply
and total stock of capital as percentage of GDP. The model is estimated
using annual time series data from 1976 to 2012. Since the initial
estimation suggested an autocorrelation problem the model is estimated
with an AR(1) term for the Philippines and Thailand. The estimated
results suggest that increase in the capital stock is the primary factor
that helps to grow the economy. Government size did not have either
positive or negative effect on output growth. Growth rate of labor does
not affect the output growth in Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia. In
case of the Philippines labor supply seems to have a negative effect on
output growth presumably because of excess labor supply in relation to
other inputs.
References
Bergh, A. and Henrekson, M. (2011), "Government Size and
Economic Growth: A Survey and Interpretation of the Evidence"
Journal of Economic Surveys, vol. 25, pp. 872-897.
Cameron, D. (1982), "On the Limits of Public Economy"
Annals of Academy of Political and Social Science, vol. 459, pp. 46-62.
Di Pietro, W. R., Sawhney, B. and Jampani, R. (1993),
"Determinants of Economic Growth: Does the Stage of Economic
Development Matter?" Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e
Commercially vol. XL, 1993, pp. 731-739.
Guseh, J. (1997), "Government Size and Economic Growth in
Developing Countries: A Political Economy Framework" Journal of
Macroeconomics, vol. 19. pp. 175-192.
Gwartney, J., Lowson, R. and Holocomb, R. (1998), "The Size
and Functions of Government and Economic Growth" Joint Economic
Committee, Washington, D.C.
Landau, D. (1993), "Government Expenditure and Economic
growth: A Cross-Country Study" Southern Economic Journal, vol. 49,
pp. 783-792.
--(1986), "Government and Economic Growth in Less Developed
Countries: An Empirical Study for 1960-1980," Economic Development
and Cultural Change, pp. 36-75.
Madrick, J. (2009), The Case for Big Government. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Marlow, M. (1986), "Private Sector Shrinkage and Growth of
Industrialized Economies" Public Choice, vol. 49, pp. 143-154.
Sachs, J. (2009), "The Case for Bigger Government" Time,
Thursday, January 8, pp. 1-3.
Ram, R. (1986), "Government Size and Economic Growth: A New
Framework and Some Evidence from Cross-Section and Time-Series
Data," American Economic Review, vol. 76(1), pp. 191203.
World Bank (1998), World Development Indicator, Washington, D.C.
NEETU KAUSHIK, Assistant Professor of Economics, Delmar College,
Corpus Christi, Texas, E-mail:
[email protected]
DHARMENDRA DHAKAL, Professor of Economics and Finance, Tennessee
State University, Nashville, Tennessee, E-mail:
[email protected]
KAMAL UPADHYAYA, Professor of Economics, University of New Haven,
West Haven, CT 06516, E-mail:
[email protected]
Table 1
Estimation of equation (4); dependent variable y
Country
Variable Coefficient Indonesia Malaysia
CONST. [C.sub.0] 10.16 0.69
(2.54) ** -1.23
k [C.sub.1] 0.34 0.21
(2.89) *** (2.49) **
l [C.sub.2] 0.05 1.49
(004) (0.96)
g [C.sub.3] 0.74 0.21
(1.60) # (0.67)
AR(1) -- --
Adj [R.sup.2] 0.288 0.143
F 5.82 2.99
D.W. 1.67 1.72
COUNTRY
Variable Philippines Thailand
CONST. 8.11 4.06
-0.87 -0.32
k 0.37 0.38
(1.91) * (2.32) **
l -5.16 1.06
(2.05) ** (1.17)
g 0.11 -0.33
(0.20) (0.40)
AR(1) 0.39 0.39
(2.12) ** (2.26) **
Adj [R.sup.2] 0.31 0.37
F 4.96 6.14
D.W. 1.73 1.94
Note: Figures in the parentheses are t-values for the corresponding
coefficients.
***, **, *. # significant at 1%, 5%, 10%, and 15% critical level
respectively.