A worrisome crop? Is there market power in the U.S. seed industry?
Kalaitzandonakes, Nicholas ; Magnier, Alexandre ; Miller, Douglas 等
The Obama administration has promised to strengthen antitrust
enforcement and to reverse the more laissez-faire guidelines of the
previous administration.
In this context, the U.S. Department of Justice has recently
focused its attention on certain agricultural industries, including the
U.S. seed industry. The primary areas of concern are the growing level
of market concentration and the potential use of market power by seed
firms.
Markets are said to be concentrated if a few firms hold a
relatively large share of the market, and high concentration is one of
the criteria used by federal antitrust authorities when they evaluate
the competitive conditions of a particular market. Firms in a highly
concentrated market may be able to exert market power and raise prices
above a competitive level, to the detriment of buyers. However, high
concentration does not necessarily imply the exertion of market power.
Economic theory predicts that prices may be kept at or near competitive
levels under the threat of entry by new suppliers, even in industries
that are highly concentrated. Also, the market may be contestable and
remain relatively competitive if potential entrants do not face costs
that existing firms can avoid, there are no inherent legal barriers to
entry, and entry and exit are relatively costless (i.e., there are no
sunk costs). Several economists have noted that firm entry in the U.S.
seed industry may be limited by large entry costs due to high research
and development investments and regulatory compliance costs as well as
by the complexity of intellectual property rights. These circumstances
could limit market contestability and increase the likelihood that firms
exert their market power.
At the same time, other authors have noted that the presence of
some market power in the U.S. seed industry may not be completely
undesirable. Seed firms engaged in the development of new genetics and
biotech traits are expected to charge prices above marginal costs in
order to recoup the fixed costs of R&D. Without the existence or the
prospect of earning prices above marginal costs due to market power, the
seed firms would have no incentive to use more efficient technologies,
improve product quality, or introduce new seed varieties and biotech
traits. Therefore, some authors have proposed that the key question to
be addressed is whether concentration and potential presence of market
power in the seed industry permits firms to make profits well above
those necessary to recoup their R&D investments.
In this study, we report empirical measures of price mark-ups
attributable to market power in the U.S. seed industry between 1997 and
2008 - a period characterized by the vertical integration of leading
multinational biotechnology firms in this industry. We then calculate
the revenues from the estimated mark-ups, compare them with approximate
measures of aggregate R&D expenditures in the industry, and draw
conclusions about their proportionality over the period of analysis.
These results provide insight on the dynamic efficiency of the industry.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Structural Evolution
Understanding the structural evolution of the U.S. seed industry
can help put in context the current considerations of concentration and
market power. Since the emergence of a commercial seed industry in the
United States over 150 years ago, assets have changed hands frequently
and most of today's leading seed companies are the products of
mergers and acquisitions. Until the late 1960s, assets in the seed
industry were primarily traded among seed companies. Starting in the
1970s, however, petrochemical and pharmaceutical multinational companies
became primary acquirers. Much of this activity has been traced to the
introduction of the Plant Variety Protection Act of 1970, which promised
to increase returns from plant research and attracted R&D-minded
multinationals. However, this wave of mergers and acquisitions had
little subsequent discernible impact on the structure of the seed
industry because the petrochemical and pharmaceutical multinationals
mainly acquired and merged small and medium-size regional seed
companies, which lost market share over time. Both independent market
leaders (e.g., Pioneer, Dekalb) and smaller regional and local seed
companies maintained their market positions despite the significant
capital resources of the new multinational entrants.
Significant consolidation in the U.S. seed industry did not occur
because the cost advantages of operating at higher production levels
(i.e., economies of scale) were limited and barriers to entry were
rather low. In principle, large investments in breeding research and
specialized know-how implied that potential scale economies could be
significant. Indeed, only a few large seed companies maintained
extensive breeding efforts and developed proprietary varieties. Further,
substantial time lags between genetic research and commercialization of
improved varieties created potential entry barriers. Yet the need for
geographic adaptation of all new seed varieties placed bounds on R&D
scale economies. Importantly, it also created commercial opportunities
for specialized breeding (foundation seed) companies, which minimized
entry barriers. They developed and broadly licensed proprietary
varieties to a large number of small regional and local seed companies,
which in turn adapted them to their local conditions.
The potential economies of scale in distribution and marketing of
seeds were even more limited. With crop yields being the primary
differentiating factor among seed brands, smaller regional companies
could effectively compete against much larger national and multinational
firms with extensive marketing and distribution networks. The regional
seed companies produced and distributed a small number of varieties
within limited geographic regions where they demonstrated competitive
yield performance. The regional firms were often relatively more
profitable as they were able to avoid the excessive inventory costs that
frequently hampered the national firms.
By the early 1990s, many of the multinational firms that led the
mergers and acquisitions activity in the previous two decades had
divested their seed assets. A handful of multinationals with significant
investments in biotechnology, however, maintained or expanded their
presence in the U.S. seed industry.
The 1990s | Since the advent of agricultural biotechnology research
in the mid-1970s, superior seed genetics (germplasm) were recognized as
an essential complementary asset for delivering new biotechnologies. For
the commercial introduction of a new biotech product to be successful,
the intellectual property, the biotechnology know-how, and the seed
germplasm base had to be coordinated. This need for coordination led to
a wave of strategic mergers and acquisitions.
Strategies to vertically integrate seed and biotechnology assets
are as old as the agricultural biotechnology industry itself For
example, biotechnology pioneers like David Padwa (founder of the early
biotechnology start-up Agrigenetics) began to acquire regional seed
companies in 1975 in order to finance biotechnology research and deliver
its products to the market. Other leading biotechnology start-ups (e.g.,
Calgene, Biotechnica International, and Mycogen) had similar strategies
and acquired a number of firms in the seed industry in the 1980s and
1990s. Multinationals Monsanto and DuPont, which acquired the two
largest independent seed firms, were latecomers in the seed industry. In
the late 1990s, both of those companies reversed their longstanding
strategies to become technology providers in favor of becoming more
vertically integrated firms.
One reason that vertical integration became a dominant strategy
among biotech companies was that the first agricultural biotech products
to reach the market demonstrated a low degree of appropriability. That
is, biotech companies were unable to secure appropriate returns on their
R&D investments through relationships with seed companies governed
only by contract. Intellectual property rights overlapped and were
heavily contested. A number of multiparty intellectual property disputes
for key technologies (e.g., insect and herbicide resistance) reached the
courts and amply demonstrated the lack of definitive intellectual
property rights among biotechnology leaders. Similarly, a relatively
large number of biotechnology companies pursuing similar commercial
biotech products provided evidence of significant imitation.
High-quality proprietary seed germplasm was therefore in a
relatively strong position. Given short supplies and significant
development lags, germplasm could command a significant share of the
innovation profits forthcoming from weakly appropriable agricultural
biotechnologies. Under such conditions, vertical integration into the
seed business and ownership of germplasm became a primary strategy of
agricultural biotechnology firms for profiting from their innovation. Of
course, some of the prospective profits from biotechnology were
transferred to seed assets and capitalized in the lofty prices paid for
firms in relevant mergers and acquisitions.
The low appropriability position of agricultural biotechnology
relative to complementary germplasm assets was one economic factor
arguing for biotechnology firms vertically integrating into the seed
business. Another factor was the relatively high transaction cost for
coordinating biotechnology and germplasm through contracts. Early in the
innovation cycle, there were significant impediments to structuring
complete contracts that would distribute value appropriately among
contracting parties and motivate appropriate behavior. Because of
significant time lags in the development of high-yielding germplasm with
desirable traits, contracts that coordinated biotechnology and seed
assets had to be constructed years before reaching the market. Such
contracts were necessarily incomplete, as it was impossible to predict
all relevant technological and commercial possibilities being created.
Accurate valuations of the individual contributions of the
interdependent biotechnologies and germplasm to the final technological
advance (e.g., higher yields) were also difficult to assess. Incomplete
contracts would predictably lead to costly renegotiations, disputes, and
delays. On the other hand, ownership of both technological and seed
assets allowed firms to bypass such costs, providing additional economic
reasoning for vertical integration of such assets.
Structural change and concentration r Motives aside, the vertical
integration of the biotechnology firms substantially changed the
ownership structure of the U.S. seed industry. A number of medium and
large independent seed firms (e.g., Pioneer, DeKalb, Northup King, and
Golden Harvest) became part of integrated multinational firms (e.g.,
DuPont, Monsanto, and Syngenta) with assets in biotechnology and other
markets.
While the changes in the ownership structure were drastic, the
changes in the level of concentration of the U.S. seed industry were
quite moderate. Since the early 1990s, the four-firm concentration ratio
and the eight-firm concentration ratio have been fairly stable. Other
measures of industry concentration also indicate similar patterns in the
U.S. seed industry. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, which is the sum of
squared market shares for all firms in an industry, takes values between
zero and 10,000, and higher values indicate increasing market
concentration. As shown in Figure 1, the index values for the U.S. seed
industry over the period 1992-2008 have stayed close to 1800, which is
typically assumed to separate moderate and high levels of concentration
in industries. This threshold level for HHI was reached or exceeded in
1992, 1994, 1996, 1999, 2000, 2007, and 2008.
Under the moderate to high levels of industry concentration
depicted in Figure 1, two key questions emerge: Do firms in the U.S.
seed industry have significant market power? If so, to what extent do
they exercise that power? To answer those questions, we first review the
existing literature on this topic in the next section. Then, we present
our own estimates of market power and the level it is exercised in the
U.S. seed industry.
Empirical Estimates of Market Power
There is limited empirical evidence on the presence of market power
in the U.S. seed industry. A handful of recent studies have examined the
pricing decisions of seed firms based on new empirical industrial
organization-type models of the firm's profit function. In a 2002
paper, Fernandez-Cornejo and Spielman constructed a profit function for
a representative seed firm and used the profit-maximizing conditions to
derive a model of the firm's price-cost margin as a function of the
industry HHI statistic, cost indices, the responsiveness of buyers to
changes in seed prices (i.e., the elasticity of demand), and the
responsiveness of seed firms to the prices charged by other seed firms
(i.e., the conjectural elasticity). Based on industry-level data, the
authors found that the direct market power effect on the price-cost
margin was positive but not significantly different from zero. Also, an
increase in market power tended to reduce the processing costs and
R&D costs, but the latter effect was not significantly different
from zero. Thus, the authors concluded that the primary effect of
increasing market power on seed margins is the improved processing cost
efficiency.
In a 2008 paper, Shi, Chavas, and Stiegert used farm-level
observations on seed price, quantity, and location from 2000 to 2007 to
estimate a model of the implicit value associated with individual traits
in hybrid seed corn. The model incorporates a generalized form of the
HHI statistic to account for the local pricing effects associated with
differentiated (i.e., multiple trait) products in the corn seed market.
The authors found that three of the four main biotech traits (corn borer
and rootworm resistance and two forms of herbicide tolerance) attract
significant price premiums and that roughly 8 percent of the price of
seed corn is associated with market power held by the seed companies.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A few studies have examined the possibility of market power by
analyzing the seed buyer's decision process. Their findings
highlight the importance of farmer-specific and regional difference in
the values assigned to particular seed traits. In a 2002 paper,
Alexander and Goodhue used a calibrated model of a representative
buyer's decision to adopt seed corn varieties with four specialized
traits (high yield, insect resistance, herbicide tolerance, and high oil
content). They then used the model to simulate the net revenue and
break-even yield for each seed type under various cropping conditions
and found that the herbicide-tolerant seed was roughly priced at the
producer's reservation price. That implies the seller could be
exerting market power and extracting the full consumer surplus from
homogeneous buyers. In contrast, insect-resistant seeds were priced
below the buyer's reservation price so that the farmer captured
some of the surplus and the seller was not exerting full market power.
In conclusion, the authors noted that the likely heterogeneity among
seed corn buyers would reduce the seller's ability to exert market
power and capture the farmers' surplus value from the hybrids.
Producer heterogeneity and the implied differential valuation of
seeds and biotech traits were empirically demonstrated by Useche,
Barham, and Foltz in a 2009 paper. Using a discrete choice model, the
authors found that the estimated value assigned to particular biotech
traits varied broadly across regions and among individual farms.
The existence of only limited empirical evidence on the presence of
market power in the U.S. seed industry is not surprising because there
are some unique analytical challenges. From the supply side, the
marginal cost structure of the seed firms is difficult to model because
a large share of total costs are fixed, including plant breeding costs,
biotechnology R&D, regulatory compliance costs, advertising, and
other marketing and promotion costs. Many of those fixed costs are
associated with relatively lumpy capital assets like seed processing
plants and research laboratories, so the fixed cost component of total
cost tends to exhibit substantial step-like character as total output
increases. Consequently, the marginal costs of production can remain
relatively small over a wide range of production levels. Also, the
variable cost component may be very different across firms, and factors
that affect the heterogeneity in variable costs include all of the
potential influences on field production of seed (yields, weather, and
grower premiums), post-harvest seed conditioning (seed drying and
cleaning), additional treatments (fungicides), and distribution costs.
As well, finished seed products may be stored between seasons and the
marginal costs of seed include inventory control costs such as
warehousing charges, interest (time value), seed loss due to
deterioration, and obsolescence of products. Finally, production costs
may be reduced when two or more biotech traits are embedded in a given
hybrid, and supply-side studies of seed firms must allow for the impact
of bundling those traits on the cost structure.
Modeling demand| The task of modeling the demand side of the seed
industry is equally complex. First, the demand for seed is derived from
the demands for crop products. Accordingly, the derived demand depends
on farmers' willingness to pay for seed that generates profit from
the field crops as well as the final consumers' willingness to pay
for the end products, and those values are driven by the traits embedded
in the hybrids (e.g., length of the growing season, crop yield and
quality potential, insect resistance, herbicide tolerance). As
previously noted, several researchers have recognized that the values
may be highly heterogeneous and vary substantially across regions, seed
firms, and farmers.
The demand side may also exhibit regular temporal patterns in seed
prices that are associated with hybrid life-cycle effects. Since seed
products are both storable and differentiated, at any point in time the
number of hybrids or varieties that are available in the market includes
a mix o frelatively old and new germplasm and biotech traits.
Accordingly, buyer willingness to pay for a particular hybrid depends on
the other products available on the market, and the equilibrium price
for a particular hybrid may change over time as it moves from market
introduction to the end of its life cycle.
Given the modeling challenges, we construct models of the derived
demand for corn and soybean seed that represent the price of seed as a
function of the quantity of seed purchased and the expected crop price
just before planting time (e.g., the average January March price of the
December corn futures contract on the Chicago Board of Trade) plus
controls for hybrid life-cycle effects, trait effects, and regional
effects. There are 10 distinct biotech traits in corn hybrids aside from
conventional corn, and these are based on herbicide tolerance (Roundup
Ready, Liberty Link, and IMI), corn borer resistance, and rootworm
resistance, plus combinations (stacks) of two or more of those traits.
Also, there are three distinct soybean variety traits that provide
herbicide tolerance (Roundup Ready, sulfonylurea-tolerant, and a
combination of those two traits) and account for about 69 percent of the
observed sample. The data used to estimate the derived demand models are
annual observations for 6,170 corn hybrids and 4,232 soybean varieties
that were sold in the United States from 1997 to 2008, and the data were
acquired from DMR Kynetecs.
Among the key results that we derive from the fitted demand models
are the price flexibility coefficients for corn and soybean seed, which
measure the responsiveness of seed prices to changes in quantity
demanded. Under profit-maximizing behavior, we know that the absolute
value of the flexibility coefficients provide upper bounds on the Lerner
index, which is the ratio of the product price (P) minus marginal cost
(MC) to the price, L = (P - MC) [divided by] P. The Lerner index is zero
under marginal-cost (perfectly competitive) pricing and increases from
zero as the price increases above marginal cost. Hence the Lerner index
is a measure of the price mark-up imposed by firms in the market, and we
can use the estimated flexibility coefficient to measure the overall
degree of market power exerted by the seed firms in the U.S. market.
The estimated corn model explains about 32 percent of the observed
variation in the seed corn prices, which is reasonably good performance
for a very large data set. From Table 1, the estimated flexibility
coefficient for the corn seed price is -0.146, which implies that the
upper bound on the corn seed mark-up (Lerner index) is roughly 14.6
percent in the U.S. market. The hybrid life-cycle component in the
estimated model indicates that the initial price of corn seed starts
low, increases until the hybrid's fourth year on the market, and
then declines until the hybrid is removed from the market. Finally, the
values associated with the individual biotech traits are positive and
statistically significant. For example, herbicide-tolerant hybrids earn
a premium that is roughly 20 percent higher than the price of
conventional seed corn, and corn borer- and rootworm-resistant hybrids
have premia that are roughly 23 percent and 29 percent higher than
conventional corn (respectively). We also find that hybrids with
multiple (stacked) traits earn higher premia, but the value of the
combined trait is less than the sum of the individual traits, which
provides evidence that the seed firms use bundled pricing strategies for
hybrids with stacked traits.
The estimated soybean model explains about 52 percent of the
observed variation in the soybean seed prices, which is expected because
the soybean seed varieties are a smaller and more homogeneous group than
the corn seed hybrids. From Table 2, we find that the estimated price
flexibility for the soybean seed price is similar at -0.175, which
implies that the upper bound on the soybean seed mark-up is roughly 17.5
percent. The fitted lifecycle component for soybean seed also indicates
that the expected price reaches a peak price at about the fourth year on
the market. Finally, we find that the estimated value for tolerance to
the herbicide sulfonylurea is not statistically different from zero, but
the Roundup Ready trait earns a premium that is about 54 percent above
the price of conventional soybean varieties. Further, the estimated
value of the combined Roundup Ready and sulfonylurea-tolerant traits (57
percent relative to conventional soybeans) is only slightly larger than
the estimated premium for Roundup Ready soybeans.
Comparison of Revenues from Mark-Ups and Premiums to Fixed Costs
With price mark-ups for germplasm and premiums for biotech traits
at hand, one way to measure the potential impact of market power in the
U.S. seed industry is to compare the industry-level revenue stream from
those mark-ups and premiums with the levels of R&D expenditures and
other relevant fixed costs for the industry. Seed companies incur large
fixed costs in the form of R&D expenditures, costs for improvements
in quality control systems, regulatory expenses, marketing costs, and
legal expenses. The revenue streams from mark-ups and premiums on traits
must be large enough to pay for these fixed costs year after year, even
though innovations and other efficiencies from such fixed expenditures
may be realized many years later. Although complete data for such fixed
expenditures are not available, we use an approximation by comparing the
revenue streams from mark-ups and premiums associated with biotech
traits to the R&D expenditures incurred by all seed companies with
meaningful breeding and biotech research activities in the corn and
soybean seed segment.
By necessity, the comparison is somewhat crude. The revenue from
mark-ups and premiums in the U.S. corn and soybean seed market does not
represent the total revenue inflow for the companies examined, some of
which have meaningful sales in other seed markets (e.g., cotton, canola,
sugar beets) and other countries. However, the U.S. corn and soybean
markets are by far the largest and most profitable seed markets in the
world and exhibit the most significant penetration of biotech traits. As
such, they contribute an estimated 75 to 87 percent of global ag biotech
revenues for the companies examined and hence the revenue stream from
mark-ups and premiums in the U.S. corn and soybean seed markets provide
a good first approximation of the relevant revenue stream. At the same
time, R&D expenditures represent only a portion of the fixed
expenses seed companies incur, though this portion is likely large.
Finally, R&D expenditures are lumpy in nature and cannot be easily
allocated among crops. As such, aggregate R&D expenditures overstate
those incurred for corn and soybeans alone. Despite the limitations, a
comparison of the revenue stream from mark-ups and premiums in the U.S.
soybean and corn seed markets with the aggregate R&D expenditures
incurred by the leading seed germplasm and biotech traits in these
markets provide valuable insight on their proportionality and their
overall direction over time. In turn, these insights help us to address
the question on the degree of market power that is exercised in these
seed markets.
The estimated mark-ups and premiums from the fitted models
presented in the previous section are used to estimate the revenue
stream over the 1997-2008 period. Specifically, for each year of the
analysis, the estimated mark-ups are applied on the total gross annual
seed sales and the estimated premiums on the gross annual revenues of
seeds with different biotech traits. As a result, the revenue stream
from mark-ups and premiums increases over time as traits become more
numerous, more valuable, and more broadly adopted.
R&D expenditures for all major developers of germplasm and/or
biotech traits in the U.S. corn and soybean seed markets and for each
year over the 1997-2008 period have been included in the aggregate
figures used here. R&D expenditures of firms that were previously
independent but were acquired or exited the industry are reflected in
the aggregate. All R&D figures were compiled from industry reports,
financial reports of individual companies, and other secondary sources.
The resulting R&D expenditures are compared to the revenue stream
from markups and premiums of biotech traits by constructing a ratio of
those revenue components to R&D investments. This index is
illustrated in Figure 2.
The size of the constructed index varies over the period of the
analysis from a low of 33 percent in 1997 to a high of 130 percent in
2008. The upward trend is expected as agricultural biotechnology entered
its commercial phase in 1996 and matured over the next 13 years through
the introduction of various biotech traits, especially in corn. Until
2005, ten years into the commercial phase of agricultural biotechnology,
revenues from mark-ups and premiums from the U.S. corn and soybean seed
markets were less than 80 percent of R&D expenditures. Over this
period of time, almost all of the revenues of the biotech industry were
generated from these two seed markets, so these figures suggest that
R&D investments were probably financed, in part, through other
productive activities of firms, speculative capital investments, and
other sources.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In more recent years, the introduction of more valuable traits (new
traits and stacks) and their broader adoption have resulted in increased
revenues that closed the gap with R&D expenditures (which were $2.4
billion in 2008). However, it appears that the seed industry did not
reach a point where revenues from mark-ups and premiums could be large
enough to fully finance R&D and maybe other fixed costs until 2008.
Given that trait markets were already quite saturated by that time
(i.e., adoption of biotech traits exceeded 87 percent and 92 percent in
the U.S. corn and soybean markets, respectively), these levels suggest
that revenues from mark-ups and trait premiums in the corn and soybean
seed markets approached R&D expenditures only during the later
stages of the commercial life-cycle for first-generation biotech traits.
Conclusion
R&D-driven industries tend to be concentrated, and the U.S.
seed industry is no exception. Concerns about the presence and use of
market power in such industries are not rare since products are
differentiated, which allows firms to set prices and charge mark-ups
that can be used to pay for R&D investments and other fixed costs.
The balance between firm profits and investments in product quality and
innovation is an important indicator of dynamic efficiency in the
marketplace - and probably a more effective gauge of competition in
dynamic and innovative industries. Because of the complex supply and
demand structures of R&D-focused industries, estimation of market
power and associated price mark-ups is not straightforward.
Nevertheless, such estimations are essential if antitrust scrutiny is to
enhance competition instead of stalling innovation. Our results suggest
that, in the case of the U.S. seed industry concentration, moderate
market power and dynamic market efficiency appear to coincide over our
period of analysis. []
READINGS
* "Agricultural Biotechnology and Industry Structure," by
M. Fulron and K. Giannakas. AgBioForum, Vol. 4 (2001).
* "Agricultural giotechnology's Complementary
Intellectual Assets," by G. Graft, G. Rausser, and A. Small. Review
of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85, No. 2 (2003).
* "An Analysis of Bundling: The Case of the Corn Seed
Market," by G. Shi, J.-P. Chavas, and K. Stiegert. Staff Paper 529,
Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of
Wisconsin-Madison, 2008.
* "Compliance Costs for Regulatory Approval of New Biotech
Crops," by N. Kalaitzandonakes, J. Alston, and K. Bradford. In
Regulating Agricultural Bintecbnology: Economics and Policy, edited by
R. Just, J. Alston, and D. Zilberman; Springer, 2006.
* "Concentration, Market Power, and Cost Efficiency in the
Corn Seed Industry," by J. Fernandez-Cornejo and D. Spiehnan.
Selected paper presented at the Ammal Meeting of the American
Agricultural Economics Association, Long Beach, CA, July 2002.
* First the Seed: The Political Economy of Plant Biotechnology, by
J. Kloppenburg. University of Wisconsin Press, 2005.
* "Innovation and Dynamic Efficiency in Plant
Biotechnology," by C. Pray, J. Oehmke, and A. Naseem. AgBioForum,
Vol. 8 (2005).
* "Integrating Technology Traits and Producer Heterogeneity: A
Mixed-Multinomial Model of Genetically Modified Corn Adoption," by
P. Useche, B. Barham, and J. Folrz. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, Vol. 91 (2009).
* "Intellectual Property Rights and Concentrations in
Agricultural Biotechnology," by W. Lesser. AgBioForum, Vol. 1
(1998).
* "Mycogen: Building a Seed Company for the Twenty-First
Century," by N. Kalaitzandonakes. Review of Agricultural Economics,
Vol. 19 (1997).
* "Regulation and the Structure of Biotechnology
Industries," by R Heisy and D. Schimmelpfennig. In Regulating,
Agricultural Biotechnology: Economics and Policy, edited by R. Just, J.
Alston, and D. Zilberman; Springer, 2006.
* "The Pricing of Innovations: An Application to Specialized
Corn Traits," by C. Alexander and R. Goodhue. Agribusiness, Vol. 18
(2002).
* "Vertical and Horizontal Coordination in the
Agro-giotechnology Industry: Evidence and Implications," by N.
Kalaitzandonakes and B. Bjornson. Journal of Agricultural and Applied
Economics, Vol. 29 (1997).
BY NICHOLAS KALAUTZANDONAKES, ALEXANDRE MAGNIER, and DOUGLAS MILLER
| University of Missouri
NICHOLAS KALAITZANDONAKES is the MSMC Endowed Professor of
Agribusiness at the University of Missouri, where ALEXANDRE MAGNIER is a
research associate. DOUGLAS MILLER is associate professor of economics
at the University of Missouri.
TABLE 1
Summary Results for the Estimated
Model of Corn Seed Prices
Model Estimated
Component Value
Lerner Index (overall price-cost mark-up for all hybrids) 14.6%
Herbicide tolerance trait 20.1%
Corn borer resistance trait 23.5%
Rootworm resistance trait 29.4%
Corn borer and herbicide tolerance traits 36.4%
Rootworm and herbicide tolerance traits 40.1%
Corn borer and rootworm resistance traits 36.4%
Corn borer, rootworm, and herbicide tolerance traits 53.1%
Corn borer and two herbicide tolerance traits 52.7%
Rootworm and two herbicide tolerance traits 68.6%
Corn borer, rootworm, and two herbicide tolerance traits 77.9%
TABLE 2
Summary Results for the Estimated
Model of Soybean Seed Prices
Model Estimated
Component Value
Lerner Index (overall price-cost mark-up for all 17.5%
varieties)
Roundup Ready trait 53.8%
Sulfonylurea herbicide tolerance trait -1.2%
Roundup Ready and sulfonylurea tolerance traits 56.8%
Notes: The Lerner Index value represents the overall mark-up (price
relative to marginal cost) earned by all corn hybrids and soybean
varieties. The estimated values for the individual traits represent
the expected price premium associated with each trait (or combination
of traits) relative to conventional corn hybrids and soybean varieties
that do not have biotech traits. All of the reported estimates in
Tables 1 and 2 are statistically significant at the 1% level except
the sulfonylurea resistance trait in the soybean seed price model
(Table 2).