Antitrust regulators and the Chicago school.
Coate, Malcolm B. ; Fischer, Jeffrey H.
We found the article by Erwin Blackstone, Larry Darby, and Joseph
Fuhr, Jr. ("The Case of Duopoly," Winter 2011-2011) an
interesting and useful piece on the lack of empirical or theoretical
support for the market structure/performance relationship. Economists
focused on antitrust have understood the difficulties in showing such a
relationship for decades, but the piece rightly showed how this result
extends even to duopolies.
Starting with the Reagan revolution, Chicago school insights have
dramatically reformed merger policy. A sample of data from the Federal
Trade Commission indicates that, between 1993 and 2010, the agency
challenged three-to-two mergers only 78 percent of the time-a high
fraction, of course, because often a third firm does provide a strong
competitive constraint to the other two, but far from the 100 percent
one would expect under the old Structure-Conduct-Performance (S-C-P)
school. (See Malcolm B. Coate, "Benchmarking the Upward Pricing
Pressure Model with Federal Trade Commission Evidence," Journal of
Competition Law and Economics, Vol. 7, No. 4 (December 2011.))
In our view, several factors account for this shift. First, in the
1970s, the Chicago school revolution exposed the intellectual bankruptcy
of the S-C-P paradigm. Over time, courts came to accept the bulk of the
Chicago analysis. Because merger review is effectively law enforcement,
the federal antitrust agencies had to follow suit, with the consensus
growing in the post-Reagan era.
Second, politicians understood, at least implicitly, that these
changes were good for them. An active market for corporate control easy
entry and exit from asset ownership-encourages investment by reducing
the risk of being locked into failing assets and encourages efficiencies
in asset ownership that maximize the value of those assets. These
factors are good for the stock market and, with the shift from defined
benefit to defined contribution pension plans, good for the middle
class. While Republicans have generally supported business, an entire
class of "Dow Jones" Democrats, led by President Bill Clinton,
arose to support the idea that economic growth is good for America and,
more importantly (to them), good for political careers. Recent natural
experiments in which some professional politicians deviated from the
consensus on non-antitrust issues have proved the risk of seriously
advocating archaic populist rhetoric. Today, real populism involves more
of an attack on "crony capitalism" than big business.
Third, a regulatory approach based more on in-depth, case-by-case
analysis of competition within a market, rather than a cookie-cutter
approach that summarily condemns high concentration, had great appeal to
the antitrust bar. Lawyers representing merging firms could get more
deals through while simultaneously increasing billable hours for the
more extensive analysis that the regulators expected. The revolving door
nature of bureaucracy left the antitrust agencies staffed with past or
future members of the defense bar. While there may be a fringe of true
believers left who may occasionally find themselves in positions of
authority within the agencies, even attorneys with a pro-enforcement
bias don't want to kill the goose that lays the golden egg.
Lastly, because the Chicago challenge to S-C-P was two-pronged,
involving conceptual questions and empirical tests, an effective
challenge to the Chicago school that reinvigorates the S-C-P paradigm
would likewise require theory and empirics to make the point that
structure does matter, or matters a great deal in four-to-three or
three-to-two mergers. However, industrial organization academics have
largely abandoned careful empirical work regarding structure/
performance relationships (one exception involves a series of
retrospectives done by FTC economists, focusing principally on the
petroleum industry, but also including the case study of the
Heinz/Beech-Nut baby food merger that Blackstone, Darby, and Fuhr cite).
Instead, these academics focus on increasingly complex game-theoretic
models of competition. The problem with this research is that the
resulting claims of welfare reductions from mergers are weakened by the
number of assumptions, some of which are impossible to check, embedded
in the models. (For more on this, see our 2009 paper "Daubert,
Science, and Modern Game Theory: Implications for Merger Analysis,"
SSRN # 1268386, Supreme Court Economic Review [forthcoming].) Some of
these models could be applicable to specific cases when the
market-specific facts line up with a particular model (and, we argue in
our paper, the model is empirically validated with data from the
market), but the models are far from general propositions about the
relationship between structure and performance. Overall, Chicago school
analysis remains the controlling intellectual authority in antitrust.
Blackstone, Darby, and Fuhr are right to highlight the lack of
empirical and theoretical support for the old Philadelphia National Bank
presumption that high concentration is a good predictor of poor market
performance. Well-done antitrust review already recognizes that
investigations are often fact-intensive. While it is an academic cliche
to end by calling for more research, we think it particularly relevant
here. More merger retrospectives and other empirical analyses of
structure and performance would be helpful in understanding and perhaps
generalizing the conditions under which high concentration is injurious
to consumers and when, in contrast, mergers enhance competition along
one or more important dimensions. An even more interesting line of
research would focus on how to apply the lessons learned from the Reagan
merger reforms to other areas of public policy. The fundamental problem
involves designing structures to align the political and public choice
interests with those of the reformers.
MALCOLM B. COATE AND JEFFREY H. FISCHER
U.S. Federal Trade, Commission
The opinions in this letter are those of the authors and do not
necessarily represent the views of the Federal Trade Commission, any
individual commissioner, or any commission bureau.