Qualifications or philosophy? The use of blue slips in a polarized era.
Black, Ryan C. ; Madonna, Anthony J. ; Owens, Ryan J. 等
Presidents employ a number of institutional powers in their quest
to influence public policy. Of these, the ability to fill vacancies to
the federal judiciary is perhaps the most influential. Federal judges
are imbued with lifetime tenure, and, as such, they can represent a
like-minded president long after that president retires. Given the
importance of federal judgeships, it is not surprising that opposition
party senators use their advice and consent power to scrutinize and
obstruct some of their nominations. Senators can employ anonymous holds
to block judicial nominations from the chamber floor (New York Times
2010), they can filibuster to prevent nominees from receiving up or down
votes, and they can discretely block or delay a judicial nomination by
returning a negative "blue slip" to the Judiciary Committee
chair.
Political observers have argued the increasing use of obstructive
tactics has had profound implications for the judiciary's ability
to handle its caseload. For example, placing the blame on minority party
Republicans, Judiciary Committee Chairman Patrick Leahy (D-VT) argued
that the Senate has laggardly confirmed Obama's nominees--that it
was much slower than it was under President Bush (Leahy 2013). This
criticism was not confined to Democrats. In his 2012 year-end report on
the federal judiciary, Chief Justice Roberts argued that it was vital
that the president and Congress provide for the "appointment of an
adequate number of judges to keep current on pending cases"
(Roberts 2012). In June of 2012, the president of the American Bar
Association (ABA) wrote a letter to Senate Majority Leader Harry Reid
(D-NV) and Senate Minority Leader Mitch McConnell (R-KY) expressing
"grave concern for the longstanding number of judicial vacancies on
Article III courts" (Robinson 2012). Finally, Senator Lindsey
Graham (R-SC) argued that senators should only block
"unqualified" nominees, as opposed to those they disagreed
with on philosophical grounds (Podgers 2012). (1)
Senator Graham's statement highlights an important issue for
scholars who study the nomination process. In an era marked by high
political polarization, how does a nominee's perceived
qualifications influence individual senators? To answer this question,
we first focus on the conditions under which senators block or delay the
president's judicial nominations through the blue slip process. We
argue that senators who are ideologically distant from presidents are
more likely to employ negative blue slips. Perhaps more importantly,
though, we discover that this proclivity is exacerbated when the nominee
is perceived as less qualified. That is, in the past, when the
ideological distance between home state senators and the president was
less severe, presidents could use legal credentials to prop up district
court and circuit court nominees who shared his views. Today, in a
Senate marked by high polarization and few moderates, the president
cannot. Qualifications only appear to mitigate the negative effect of
ideology among district court nominees and not among the more powerful
circuit courts of appeals. This finding represents a shift in nomination
politics and shows that nominations for circuit court positions have
become more contentious. While the limited time period of available data
constrains our ability to make broad generalizations, we are
nevertheless led to believe that senators will continue to oppose
nominees on the basis of their ideological positions--regardless of
qualifications.
In what follows, we theorize conditions under which senators might
return negative blue slips (or refuse to return them at all) for
judicial nominations and thereby obstruct the president's judicial
nominations. While the blue slip process is certainly not the only way
to block a nomination, we choose to focus on it for three reasons.
First, the largely anonymous nature of Senate procedure makes data
difficult to come by--and we were able to capture an important snapshot
of data on blue slips. Second, we believe our findings regarding blue
slips can be applied to other forms of obstruction such as holds and
filibusters. Finally, negative blue slips are often dispositive. As we
discuss later, it is a very rare to see a committee chair schedule a
hearing on a nomination that a senator blue slipped. We next explain our
data, present our statistical model, and discuss our results. We
conclude with a discussion about the future of judicial nominations.
Obstruction in the Modern Senate: Filibusters, Holds, and Blue
Slips
Since the latter half of the twentieth century, senators have
increasingly used their institutional tools to obstruct Senate business,
block disfavored legislation, and slow up the president's
nominations (Binder and Smith 1997; Koger 2010; Wawro and Schickler
2006). Scholars have noted that the increasing use of obstructive
tactics coincided with growth in the size and scope of the federal
government. As the size of the executive and legal branches grew, along
with the workload of the Senate, so too did the number of measures
obstructed. Why senators increasingly used these tools--especially as
the amount of Senate business increased--seems obvious: they could exact
concessions from time-starved party leaders and presidents.
With the threat of obstruction present, the Senate majority leader
must balance legislative priorities with time. Thus, for much of the
business that gets scheduled in the Senate, the process is a consensual
one in which the majority and minority party leaders forge unanimous
consent agreements (Ainsworth and Flathman 1995; Smith and Flathman
1989). Bills or nominations that are not granted unanimous consent
agreements are frequently not considered on the chamber floor. When
party leaders cannot corral their members, they do not move the bill to
the floor. The tenuous nature of scheduling thus provides significant
leverage to each individual senator. And when it comes to nomination
politics, those same concerns affect the president's nominees.
To be sure, the Senate's rules allow a supermajority of the
chamber to proceed to a vote on an obstructed measure through the
cloture process. Still, such a process is time consuming and generates
significant opportunity costs. A cloture petition must lie over for two
calendar days before it is voted on. Then, for much of the
chambers' history, an additional 30 hours of debate and amending
activity could occur before a final vote is taken on the bill or
nomination. (2) The Senate simply lacks the time to move cloture on
every obstructed bill or nomination. Indeed, as if to underscore the
problems facing Senate leaders--and highlighting the power of individual
senators--much of the obstruction we observe is merely the tip of the
iceberg, representing only a small slice of the possible obstruction
that occurs outside public view. That is, the threat of obstruction
often keeps legislation and nominations off the floor, making it
remarkably difficult to measure just how much obstruction actually
exists. When Senate leaders alter legislation in response to threatened
obstruction or obstruction outside public view, they frequently escape
our attention. (3)
Among the many institutional tools available to senators, a few,
which arise from the chamber's lack of a simple-majoritarian rule
for ending debate, stand out, especially to presidents on the wrong end
of them. Manifest filibusters tend to get discussed the most, but holds
and blue slips are also a function of this unlimited debate power. We
examine each of these powers but focus primarily on the blue slip and
its role in judicial nominations.
The filibuster allows an individual or a group of senators to
obstruct or block a measure that enjoys the support of a chamber
majority. The term "filibuster" is perhaps most frequently
associated with stories of Southern senators in the mid-twentieth
century delivering lengthy, round-the-clock speeches against Presidents
Kennedy's and Johnson's civil rights legislation. In these
episodes, senators attempted to kill bills by preventing final passage
votes on them. Because there was no formal method to limit an
individuals' ability to debate a measure by a simple majority,
senators would seek to consume so much time on the Senate floor that the
session would expire.
The hold, also a function of the unlimited debate power, is a
request by a senator to her party leader to delay floor action on a bill
or nomination. When a senator seeks to place a hold on a measure or a
nomination, he essentially notifies his party's leader of his
intent to object to the measure or nomination when or if it is brought
to the Senate floor. (4) While it is ultimately still up to the majority
leader to determine whether to honor a hold, the failure to do so can
have far-reaching implications for the calendar, the majority's
ability to conduct business, and for the president's ability to get
his legislation through the Congress. As Oleszek (2008, 1) points out, a
majority leader that ignores a hold might "precipitate objections
to unanimous consent agreements and filibusters" and thereby stall
action on important agenda items.
The blue slip, essentially a more formal version of a hold, is an
institutional tool senators use to support or oppose judicial nominees.
(5) A blue slip is a tool that home state senators can use to support or
oppose a federal judicial nominee to a position in their state. Each
blue slip provides the name of the nominee, the name of the senator, and
a request that the senator provide the Judiciary Committee chair with
information on the nominee. More specifically, when the Senate receives
the president's nomination to the judicial vacancy, the nomination
is referred to the Judiciary Committee. The committee counsel, in turn,
delivers a "blue slip"--a blue slip of paper--to the
nominee's two home state senators. (6) Unlike the norm of
senatorial courtesy, the blue slip is not limited to home state senators
of the president's party. All home state senators have blue slip
rights that they employ to support or oppose judicial nominees to lower
federal courts.
Upon receiving the blue slip, a senator has three options: she may
return the blue slip to the chair with a positive recommendation; she
may return it with a negative recommendation; or she may fail to return
it at all. When a senator returns a blue slip to the Judiciary Committee
chair with a positive recommendation, she shows that she will not hold
it up (Binder 2007). On the other hand, if she returns a negative blue
slip or fails to return it, she shows opposition to the nomination. An
unreturned blue slip traditionally has been treated the same as a
returned negative slip. Just how this blue slip treatment affects the
nomination depends on the Judiciary Committee chair and political
context.
The effects of a negative blue slip have varied dramatically
between 1913--when the first blue slip appeared (Binder 2007;
Sollenberger 2010)--and today. (7) Chairs initially did not treat blue
slips as dispositive. Rather, the chair used the blue slip to determine
how much resistance to expect from home state senators regarding a
nominee. When Senator Eastland took over as Judiciary Committee chair
(1956-78), he significantly changed blue slipping policy. During his
tenure, a negative blue slip or unreturned blue slip from a single home
state senator blocked any further action on the nomination. Why Eastland
changed blue slipping policy is unclear, though racial politics likely
had something to do with it, as Eastland could use committee rules to
block pro--civil rights nominees from reaching the bench (Sollenberger
2010, 130). While later Judiciary Committee chairs would also alter
their treatment of negative blue slips depending on political context, a
single blue slip continues to impose a strong and negative effect on any
nomination's chance of success. As such, senators today use blue
slips "as a means to defeat, not merely delay, a nominee; and
perhaps prevent the nomination from being made in the first place"
(Denning 2001, 87). (8)
As we have discussed, the blue slip is not the only tool used to
block judicial nominations prior to floor consideration. Indeed, the
support of both home state senators' is sometimes not enough to
secure a nominees confirmation. During the 111th and 112th Congresses,
several of President Obama's nominees were supported by both home
state senators. For example, during the 112th Senate, both Tenth Circuit
nominee Robert E. Bacharach and First Circuit nominee William Kayatta,
Jr., were supported by their home state Republican senators (Senator
James Inhofe (R-OK) and Senator Tom Coburn (R-OK) for Bacharach and
Senator Susan Collins (R-ME) and Senator Olympia Snowe (R-ME) for
Kayatta). Despite their support, Republicans blocked their confirmation,
citing the "Leahy-Thurmond" Rule, which holds that the
opposition party will refuse to hold votes on circuit court judges
within six months of a presidential election (Sanchez 2012a, 2012b).
While holds and manifest filibusters represent serious problems for
judicial nominees, we focus on blue slips for several reasons. First,
holds are rarely publicized, and comparatively few obstructed nominees
are subjected to a filibuster or cloture vote on the floor. Second, our
findings regarding the role of ideology and qualifications in the blue
slip process should be applicable to other forms of obstruction. Third,
negative blue slips are almost always dispositive. For example, Senator
Barbara Boxer's (D-CA) threat to withhold her blue slip had
President George W. Bush nominated Christopher R. Cox (R-CA) to the
liberal Ninth Circuit led Cox to withdraw his name from consideration
(Denning 2001). Indeed, among the three Congresses we study, the chair
held a confirmation hearing in only 17.65% of cases where a senator
returned a negative blue slip.
Just as we know little about obstruction more broadly, we know
little about the conditions under which senators employ the blue slip to
oppose judicial nominees. The anonymity of this and other prefloor
dilatory tactics has made comprehensive empirical analysis difficult.
That is not to say that we know nothing about blue slips. On the
contrary, a handful of well-executed studies shed light on these powers.
Consider, for example, Binder (2007), who analyzes Senate Judiciary
Committee archival records to determine when the Senate began using blue
slips. Binder's findings suggest that blue slips arose as a means
of reducing uncertainty about the fate of judicial nominees in an era
before the Senate could invoke cloture stop a filibuster.
Using a different approach to examine the effects of blue slips,
Slotnick (1980) interviewed 10 senators in 1980, just after Senator Ted
Kennedy's (D-MA) modification of blue slip policy, to determine
their opinion on the institutional practice. (9) Denning (2001, 2002)
briefly examines the constitutionality of blue slips, and suggests
reforms to the appointment process. (10) Sollenberger (2010) analyzes
how different Judiciary Committee chairs have treated blue slips across
time and political contexts. Steigerwalt (2010) examined newspaper
articles that addressed senators' negative blue slips for circuit
court nominations between 1985 and 2006. She examined the published
incidents (i.e., those in which a senator publicly claimed credit for
the obstruction) in which senators used their blue slips to block or
delay a nomination. Steigerwalt shows how, as nominations proceed
through different stages of the nomination process, different actors can
intervene to influence outcomes. Finally, Black, Madonna, and Owens
(2011) examine the conditions under which senators exercise their blue
slipping privileges, finding that senators who are ideologically distant
from the president are more likely to return negative blue slips.
While all of these studies tell us important information about the
blue slip, they do not directly address the question the two questions
we ask here: (1) Among all the possible judicial nominees that could be
blue slipped, when do modern senators actually employ negative blue
slips?; and (2) How do judicial qualifications influence the behavior of
blue-slipping senators? (11) We seek to build off these important works
and improve our understanding of blue slips, of Senate obstruction, and
of the role of qualifications among nominees to lower federal courts.
A Theory of Blue Slip Behavior
Following the existing literature on nominations politics, we argue
that senatorial ideology and the perceived qualifications of the nominee
will influence a senator's decision to return a negative or
positive blue slip. Both features, we believe, combine to influence blue
slip behavior. A host of studies show that ideological considerations
strongly influence the behavior of senators and presidents during the
nomination process. When determining whom to nominate, presidents
consider the ideology of pivotal members of the Senate. As one of
President Bush's staffers stated in 2001: "It doesn't do
the president any good to send up nominees who are on suicide missions.
We have to be sensitive to the winds that blow in the Senate, which is
evenly divided ... We need to be sure we're doing the right thing
politically and philosophically" (Binder and Maltzman 2009, 77).
Similarly, Binder and Maltzman (2009) show that presidents take longer
to fill lower-court vacancies when facing ideologically distant blue
slip senators and less time to fill them when they enjoy home state
senators of their own party. Nemacheck (2007) illustrates that when
presidents make Supreme Court nominations, they follow either an
informational strategy or a political strategy, depending on the
composition of the Senate. Moraski and Shipan (1999) and, later, Johnson
and Roberts (2004) further show that the president's selection
turns on the identity of relevant legislative pivots.
On the senatorial side, numerous studies highlight the importance
of ideology in a senator's decision to support or oppose a nominee.
Binder and Maltzman (2002) and Martinek, Kemper and Van Winkle (2002)
show that political and ideological considerations lead to confirmation
delay. Binder and Maltzman (2009) shows that nominees to federal circuit
courts are less likely to be confirmed when their home state senator is
ideologically distant from the president. And, Cameron, Cover, and Segal
(1990) demonstrate that ideology and nominee qualifications combine to
influence a senator's confirmation vote (see also Epstein and Segal
2005). We take these studies to suggest that senators will employ their
blue slip privileges in an ideological fashion. As senators become more
distant ideologically from the president, they will be more likely to
return negative blue slips. That is,
Policy Agreement Hypothesis: As the ideological distance between a
senator and the president increases, the senator will be
increasingly likely to return a negative blue slip. (12)
Despite the high levels of attention given to the role of ideology
in the nomination process, we believe that nominee qualifications should
also influence member decisions. In a number of instances, senators
justified their decisions to oppose a nomination on the grounds the
nominee was not sufficiently qualified. Perhaps the most famous example
of this was the defeat of President Nixon's Supreme Court nominee,
G. Harrold Carswell. Responding to concerns about Carswell's
record, Senator Roman Hruska (R-NE) was famously stated that "Even
if he is mediocre, there are a lot of mediocre judges and people and
lawyers. They are entitled to a little representation, aren't
they?" (Epstein and Segal 2005, 66). Harriet Miers, too, saw her
chances of becoming a justice disappear after serious concerns arose
over her lack of judicial experience.
This list, of course, is not limited to Supreme Court nominees.
Consider Michael Wallace's nomination to the Fifth Circuit. The ABA
determined, based on Wallace's previous experience on the Legal
Service Corporation, that he displayed a lack of judicial temperament.
As such, the ABA held that Wallace was not qualified to serve. Shortly
thereafter, Wallace withdrew his nomination. Janice Rogers Brown, too,
saw her nomination to the DC Circuit stall and then nearly fail after a
majority found her "qualified," but a sizeable minority of the
ABA rated her as not qualified. Additionally, empirical evidence further
supports the argument that nominee qualifications are important (Epstein
and Segal 2005; Martinek, Kemper, and Van Winkle 2002; Scherer, Bartels,
and Steigerwalt 2008).
We likewise believe that perceived nominee qualifications will
influence senators' blue slip behavior. When a senator perceives
the nominee to be more qualified, she will be more likely to return a
positive blue slip. Conversely, when the senator perceives the nominee
to be less qualified, she will be more likely to return a negative blue
slip.
Perceived Qualifications Hypothesis: A senator will be increasingly
likely to return a negative blue slip when the nominee appears less
qualified for the bench.
We also believe that senators will be more likely to return
negative blue slips for circuit court nominations because of those
courts' abilities to make important legal policy. "The
[federal] circuit courts play by far the greatest legal policy-making
role in the United States judicial system" (Cross 2007, 2). Circuit
courts wield tremendous power because they rule on nearly every issue
before the federal judiciary and are rarely audited by the Supreme
Court. According to the Administrative Office of the United States
Courts, in 2008, the circuit courts of appeals disposed of 29,608 cases
after oral hearings or submission on briefs, and a decade earlier in
1997, they terminated 25,840 such cases. (13) And, the Supreme Court
rarely reviews circuit decisions (Kaheny, Haire, and Benesh 2008).
Indeed, as Brudney and Ditslear (2001) show, the Supreme Court reviewed
roughly 0.2% of circuit court decisions in 2000. Because circuit courts
rule on many contemporary pressing issues and know that the Supreme
Court reviews only a small percentage of their cases (and therefore
rarely reverses them), circuit judges have broad discretion (Bowie and
Songer 2009; Klein and Hume 2003). As such, senators are likely to
exercise more caution--and, thus, return more negative blue slips--when
examining circuit court nominees.
Circuit Court Hypothesis: A senator will be more likely to return a
negative blue slip when the nomination is for a circuit court
vacancy.
In addition to their independent effects, it is likely that
ideological considerations, nominee qualifications, and court vacancy
jointly influence whether senators return a positive or negative blue
slip. Indeed, a host of empirical evidence suggests that policy and
qualifications combine to influence confirmation votes. Cameron, Cover,
and Segal (1990) show, for example, that senators vote to confirm
ideologically proximate Supreme Court nominees, even when the nominee is
considered to be poorly qualified. Conversely, they will vote to confirm
ideologically distant nominees when they have impeccable credentials
(see also Epstein et al. 2006).
At the same time, given that blue slips are returned before public
debate on the chamber floor, the mitigating effect of qualifications may
not rear its head. That is, whereas public discussion over nominees
inevitably contains frequent references to the nominee's
qualifications--who could possibly refuse to confirm someone qualified
for the job?--the same public pressure to support a qualified but
ideologically distant nominee does not exist in private. This is
consistent with our previous discussion highlighting statements made by
Senator Graham (R-SC).
Indeed, privately obstructing a qualified ideologue would seem to
be an effective strategy for opposing party senators. Rather than having
to defend publicly their opposition to a well-qualified nominee on
ideological grounds, they can simply obstruct the nomination with the
hopes that it never sees the public light of day. Killing the nomination
in the cradle saves them from having to defend their opposition on
ideological grounds. And this dynamic is likely to be most important for
nominations to the circuit courts of appeals. Thus, we expect the
following:
The Conditional Effect of Qualifications Hypothesis: A nominee's
perceived qualifications will condition the effect of policy
disagreement for district court nominations but not circuit court
nominations.
We further control for a number of additional factors that might
influence senators to return negative blue slips. We first control for
the amount of time left in the session. We expect that threats of
obstruction will be more credible--and effective--later in each session,
making the blue slip a more attractive option during this time period
(see, e.g., Koger 2010; Wawro and Schickler 2006). Next, we examine
whether senators used the blue slip to block the president's female
nominees so as to limit their future potential for higher office. During
the Bush administration, conservative commentators often argued that
Senate Democrats sought to block these nominees. As one such commentator
argued, "Senate Democrats oppose qualified conservative ... women
because they are loathe to place such judges one step from the Supreme
Court." (14)
If these stories are correct, we would expect to see senators using
blue slips against women nominated by Bush. In a similar vein, we might
expect to see senators blocking young nominees. Finally, we control for
the popularity of the president. It is well documented, for example,
that popular presidents are more likely to enjoy legislative success
(Binder and Maltzman 2004; Bond and Fleisher 1992; Light 1998). Senators
may be reticent to stand up publicly to popular presidents. We might
therefore expect that when public support for the president is high,
senators will turn to the (less public) blue slip to oppose nominees.
When, however, the president's public approval is low, senators can
publicly oppose the president with tools other than the private blue
slip.
Data and Measures
To determine the conditions under which senators employ their blue
slips, we analyzed every nomination to the federal district and circuit
courts between the 107th through 110th Congresses (inclusive)--the only
recent Congresses where blue slipping data are available. In 2001,
Chairman Leahy and Ranking Member Hatch agreed to make blue slips public
regardless of who was chair or which party controlled the Senate
(Sollenberger 2010, 130). Despite this agreement, however, the Senate
Judiciary Committee made public on the Department of Justice Office of
Legal Policy website only the blue slips during the 107th and 108th
Congresses. (15) Thankfully, Sollenberger (2010) was able to procure
blue slip data from the 109th and 110th Congresses privately from the
Senate Judiciary Committee. (16) Our unit of analysis is the
senator's blue slip per nomination--that is, the senator's
blue slip treatment of every nomination. Our dependent variable is coded
as 1 if a senator returned a negative blue slip or failed to return one
at all. (17) Just over 10% of nominations in our data set yielded a
negative blue slip.
We code our independent variables in the following manner:
Senator's Ideological Distance from President is the absolute value
of the ideological difference between the senator and the nominating
president, using the first dimension Poole and Rosenthal common space
scores (Poole and Rosenthal 1997, 2007). (18) Our measure of perceived
judicial qualifications comes from the ABA Standing Committee on the
Federal Judiciary's ratings for each nominee. (19) The ABA Standing
Committee evaluates prospective judicial nominees and issues summaries
as to those nominees' qualifications for serving on the federal
judiciary. The committee evaluates nominees' professional
competence, integrity, and judicial temperament.
After an analysis, the ABA provides a single rating to identify the
nominee's quality. During the time period under study the ABA
provided three ratings--well qualified, qualified, or not qualified.
Each nominee could receive either a unanimous or split committee rating.
For example, some nominees, like Michael W. McConnell, received a
unanimous well-qualified rating. Others, like Michael Wallace, received
a unanimous not qualified vote. Other nominees observed split votes.
Consider Glen Conrad, who was nominated to be a circuit court judge on
the Fourth Circuit. A majority of the ABA committee rated him as well
qualified while a minority rated him qualified. We took advantage of
these committee splits to create an ordinal ranking of nominee
qualifications. That is, we created a scale from 1 to 7 in which we
ranked a nominee's qualifications. A Nominee ABA Rating of 1 means
that a nominee was unanimously not qualified, while a rating of 7 was
unanimously well qualified. Each rating in between reflected a gradient
of the vote.
To examine the interactive relationship between the senator's
distance from the president and the nominee's qualifications, we
created an interactive term, which is Ideological Distance from
President multiplied by Nominee ABA Rating. To code Circuit Court
Nomination, we relied on the blue slip data provided by the Judiciary
Committee. If those data stated that the nomination was for a circuit
court, the variable receives a 1; 0 otherwise. In order to examine the
conditional relationship between the nominee's qualifications and
the court vacancy, we interacted Nominee ABA Rating and Circuit Court
Nomination.
To determine Female Nominee, we reviewed the Federal Judicial
Center Biographical Directory. (20) The vast majority of data could be
found in this database. Where those data were not available, we turned
both to the nominee's personal resume, which can be found at the
Office of Legal Policy website, or to contemporary journalistic accounts
of the nominee's characteristics. To determine Nominee's Age,
we simply determined the year in which the nominee was born and
subtracted that year from the year in which the president nominated her.
We code Days until Session Ends as the number of days between when the
president makes his nomination and the end of the Senate's session.
(21) To determine the President's Popularity at Nomination, we
visited Gallup's website and determined the president's
popularity at the time of the nomination. (22)
Methods and Results
Since our dependent variable examines the dichotomous outcome
whether a senator returns a negative blue slip, we estimate a probit
regression model and test for statistical significance using robust
standard errors clustered on the nominee. Parameter estimates for our
model are reported in Table 1.
As both the statistical significance and the sign of an interaction
term can change across a variable's range (Berry, DeMeritt and
Esarey 2010; Kam and Franzese 2007), the standard table of parameter
estimates is of little use for interpreting our main hypothesis of
interest. Thus, we follow the recommendation of King, Tomz and
Wittenberg (2000) and Brambor, Clark and Golder (2006) and turn to
predicted probabilities to examine our results. Figures 1 and 2
illustrate the relationship between ideological distance on the x-axis
and the predicted probability a senator returns a negative blue slip on
the y-axis. The solid line represents a hypothetical nominee who
receives a low rating from the ABA. The dashed line, by contrast, shows
a nominee with a high ABA rating. (23) Figure 1 shows our results if the
nomination is to a district court and Figure 2 shows the same results
for a circuit court nomination.
Starting with a district court nominee (Figure 1), we find that as
the ideological distance between a senator and the president increases,
so too does the likelihood of observing a negative blue slip.
Additionally, for low to moderate levels of ideological distance, our
results suggest little difference between nominees who are deemed to be
highly qualified versus those who are not. For higher levels of
ideological distance, however, qualifications can attenuate the impact
of ideology. More specifically, when the ideological distance is 0.80 or
above--roughly the 65th percentile value in our data--we find that
highly qualified district court nominees are significantly less likely
to observe a negative blue slip than are their less qualified
counterparts. When ideology is at its 75th percentile value
(approximately 0.84), for example, we estimate that a nominee with a low
ABA rating is roughly three times as likely to receive a negative blue
slip than a nominee with a high ABA rating (i.e., 0.27 [low ABA] versus
0.09 [high ABA}). As we note in the figure, this difference is
statistically significant for 37 percent of the observations in our
data.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
To contextualize these results, consider President Bush's
nomination of David Bunning to the Eastern District of Kentucky. Bunning
received a particularly low ABA rating: a majority of the committee
determined him to be not qualified, while only a minority deemed him to
be qualified. Despite his low qualifications, neither senator from
Kentucky opposed his nomination. Perhaps it was because they both were
ideologically close to the president. (24) Recall, further, Michael
Wallace, who received a unanimous not qualified rating. Neither senator
from Mississippi exercised his blue slip to block the nomination, likely
because they agreed ideologically with the nomination. On the other
hand, recall Frederick W. Rohlfing's nomination to the federal
district court of Hawaii. Senator Daniel Akaka's (D-HI) negative
blue slip (along with that of his colleague and fellow Democrat, Senator
Inouye), put the brakes on the nomination.
Was it coincidence that Akaka was ideologically distant from
President Bush? We think not. Was it happenstance that Akaka exercised
his blue slip after Rohlfing received a "not qualified" rating
from the ABA? Again, probably not. Indeed, if we consider the nomination
of J. Michael Seabright, whose nomination succeeded Rohlfing's, we
can observe the power of perceived qualifications. Unlike Rohlfing,
Seabright received a strong ABA vote: a substantial majority of the ABA
committee found him to be well qualified while a minority determined him
to be qualified. Akaka's ideological distance from the president,
of course, remained constant. Akaka and Inouye returned positive blue
slips for Seabright who was thereafter confirmed by the full Senate. Put
plainly, our results suggest that presidents can insulate their district
court nominees from a negative blue slip by picking nominees with strong
credentials.
We next turn to Figure 2 to determine whether a similar strategy
would work for circuit court nominees. Note, initially, that we observe
the same general relationship as shown in the panel addressing district
court nominees: increasing ideological distance from the president leads
senators to return negative blue slips. Unlike district court nominees,
however, circuit court nominees cannot be saved by better
qualifications. That is, for all values of ideological distance, circuit
court nominees with high ABA ratings are no less likely to receive a
negative blue slip than those with low ABA ratings. This finding
represents a sizable shift in nomination politics and shows that
nominations over circuit court positions have become much more
contentious than in past years. In other words, the modern Senate has
become much more active in the "consent" stage for circuit
court nominees. No longer willing to cede power to presidents who
nominate well qualified ideologues, modern senators will use their
private institutional powers to kill such nominations in their infancy.
Better to do it there than to defend later their opposition to the
nominee on ideological grounds.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Our controls performed partially as expected. Days until Session
Ends is negative and statistically significant, meaning that senators
are less likely to employ the blue slip the farther out they are from
the end of the session. When the session is just in its infancy, we
estimate a 1% chance of observing a negative blue slip. By contrast, in
the closing days of the session, that likelihood jumps to around 7%.
(25) We found no relationship between nominee age or sex and the
decision to return a negative blue slip; nor did we find any evidence to
suggest that presidential popularity influences blue slipping.
To be sure, we recognize that ideology and qualifications are not
the only factors at play. Presidents often nominate individuals after
compromising with senators. Steigerwalt's (2010) important study
highlights a number of instances in which senators used their blue slips
because the president failed to consult sufficiently with them. Clearly,
these dynamics affect the process.
Take, for example, President Bush's nomination of Helene
White. White was originally nominated to the Sixth Circuit by President
Clinton, despite Clinton's promise to then-Michigan Senator Spencer
Abraham (R-MI) that he would not do so. In response, Abraham exercised
his blue slip privileges to block White's nomination, which thus
languished for years in the Senate. After Bush became president,
Democratic Senators Levin (D-MI) and Stabenow (D-MI) used their blue
slips in retaliation to block Bush's nominations. Eventually, they
persuaded Bush to nominate White to the circuit court and, in exchange,
released their stranglehold on other nominees (Thomas 2008).
This example highlights the weakness with using an empirical model
such as ours. Yet, we nevertheless wonder whether presidents consult
less with senators for ideological reasons. It must be more than
coincidental that Bush allegedly failed to consult sufficiently with
Senators Boxer (1.21 distance from the president), Feinstein (0.99),
Levin (1.14), and Stabenow (1.05), senators among the most ideologically
distant from Bush. In other words, while we do not believe that our
model fully captures all the dynamics that influence blue slip
behavior--we believe these unmodeled variables are highly likely to be
correlated with ideological considerations.
Discussion
The Constitution directs the Senate to advise the president on
judicial nominations and directs that nominees will only be confirmed
after the Senate's consent. Over the years, the Senate has created
a series of institutional tools that senators can employ during this
process. In recent years, filibuster, holds, and blue slips all have
taken on increased importance, and have generated heightened concern.
Yet, because they are often so secretive, these obstructive tactics have
received comparatively little empirical examination.
Our data, while limited in time, provide interesting insights into
judicial nominations--the intersection of the Senate's
institutional powers with its constitutional obligations. First, we
observe that senators are more likely to return negative blue slips when
they are ideologically distant from the president. In the modern era or
high polarization, this is frequently the case. Second, we find that
senators are more likely to return negative blue slips when judicial
nominees are perceived as less qualified. For presidents, this means
that they should be very careful when selecting nominees to positions
with home state senators who are ideologically distant and, when so
doing, they should take aims to ensure that those nominees are perceived
as well qualified as possible.
Third, and most important, we find that the mitigating effect of
qualifications is limited. When the president and home state senators
are polarized, qualifications will only resurrect nominees to district
court vacancies. When it comes to confirming circuit court nominees, the
Senate has taken back some of its institutional power. Senators will use
their private institutional powers to block qualified but extreme
nominees. Doing so allows them to block potentially
"dangerous" judges, all in the privacy of institutional
process. Thus, as presidents nominate judges to circuit court vacancies,
they face significant threats of obstruction from home state senators
who oppose them. Unless presidents nominate less ideological judges,
party polarization decreases, or the Senate changes its rules on
obstruction, we will continue to observe bitter partisan fights and
lengthy delays over circuit court nominations.
References
Ainsworth, Scott, and Marcus Flathman. 1995. "Unanimous
Consent Agreements as Leadership Tools." Legislative Studies
Quarterly 20 (2): 177-95.
Berry, William D., Jacqueline H. R. DeMeritt, and Justin Esarey.
2010. "Testing for Interaction in Binary Logit and Probit Models:
Is a Product Term Essential?" American Journal of Political Science
54 (1): 248-66.
Binder, Sarah A. 2007. "Where Do Institutions Come From?
Exploring the Origins of the Senate Blue Slip." Studies in American
Politics Development 21 (Spring): 1-15.
Binder, Sarah A., and Forrest Maltzman. 2002. "Senatorial
Delay in Confirming Federal Judges, 1947-1998." American Journal of
Political Science 46 (1): 190-99.
--. 2004. "The Limits of Senatorial Courtesy."
Legislative Studies Quarterly 29 (1): 5-22.
--. 2009. Advice and Dissent: The Struggle to Shape the Federal
Judiciary. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Binder, Sarah A., and Steven S. Smith. 1997. Politics or Principle?
Filibustering in the United States Senate. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press.
Binder, Sarah A., Anthony J. Madonna, and Steven S. Smith. 2007.
"Going Nuclear, Senate Style." Perspectives on Politics 5 (4):
729-40.
Black, Ryan C., Anthony J. Madonna, and Ryan J. Owens. 2011.
"Obstructing Agenda-Setting: Examining Blue Slip Behavior in the
Senate." Forum 9 (4): Article #9.
Bond, Jon R., and Richard Fleisher. 1992. The President in the
Legislative Arena. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bowie, Jennifer Barnes, and Donald R. Songer. 2009. "Assessing
the Applicability of Strategic Theory to Explain Decision Making on the
Court of Appeals." Political Research Quarterly 62 (2): 393-407.
Brambor, Thomas, William Roberts Clark, and Matt Golder. 2006.
"Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical
Analysis." Political Analysis 14 (1): 63-82.
Brudney, James J., and Corey Ditslear. 2001. "Designated
Diffidence: District Court Judges on the Courts of Appeals." Law
and Society Review 35 (3): 565-606.
Cameron, Charles M., Albert D. Cover, and Jeffrey A. Segal. 1990.
"Senate Voting on Supreme Court Nominees: A Neoinstitutional
Model." American Political Science Review 84 (2): 525-34.
Cross, Frank B. 2007. Decision Making in the U.S. Courts of
Appeals. Sanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Denning, Brannon P. 2001. "The 'Blue Slip':
Enforcing the Norms of the Judicial Confirmation Process." William
and Mary Bill of Rights Journal 10 (1): 75-102.
--. 2002. "The Judicial Confirmation Process and the Blue
Slip." Judicature 85 (5): 218-26. Epstein, Lee, and Jeffrey A.
Segal. 2005. Advice and Consent: The Politics of Judicial Appointments.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Epstein, Lee, Rene Lindstadt, Jefferey A. Segal, and Chad
Westerland. 2006. "The Changing Dynamics of Senate Voting on
Supreme Court Nominees." Journal of Politics 68 (2): 296-307.
Johnson, Timothy R., and Jason M. Roberts. 2004. "Presidential
Capital and the Supreme Court Confirmation Process ."Journal of
Politics 66 (3): 663-83.
Kaheny, Erin B., Susan Brodie Haire, and Sara C. Benesh. 2008.
"Change over Tenure: Voting, Variance, and Decision Making on the
U.S. Courts of Appeals." American Journal of Political Science 52
(3): 490-503.
Kam, Cindy D., and Robert J. Franzese, Jr. 2007. Modeling and
Interpreting Interactive Hypotheses in Regression Analysis. Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press.
King, Gary, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg. 2000. "Making
the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and
Presentation." American Journal of Political Science 44 (2):
347-61.
Klein, David E., and Robert J. Hume. 2003. "Fear of Reversal
as an Explanation of Lower Court Compliance." Law and Society
Review 37 (3): 579-606.
Koger, Gregory. 2008. "Filibustering and Majority Rule in the
Senate: The Contest over Judicial Nominations, 2003-2005." In Why
Not Parties: Party Effects in the United States Senate, eds. Nathan W.
Monroe, Jason M. Roberts, and David W. Rohde. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 159-77.
Koger, Gregory. 2010. Filibustering: A Political History of
Obstruction in the House and Senate. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Kucinich, Jackie, and Jessica Brady. 2011. "Changes to Senate
Rules Fall Short of Drastic Proposals." Roll Call, January 27.
Leahy, Patrick. 2013. "Statement of Senator Patrick Leagy
(D-VT). Chairman, Senate Judiciary Committee. On Judicial
Nomination." January 23. http://www.judiciary.senate.gov/pdf/l-23
-13LeahyStatement.pdf (accessed January 16, 2014).
Light, Paul. 1998. The President's Agenda: Domestic Policy
Choice from Kennedy to Clinton. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Martinek, Wendy L., Mark Kemper, and Steven R. Van Winkle. 2002.
"To Advise and Consent: The Senate and Lower Federal Court
Nominations, 1977-1998." Journal of Politics 62 (2): 337-61.
Moraski, Bryon J., and Charles R. Shipan. 1999. "The Politics
of Supreme Court Nominations: A Theory of Neoinstitutional Constraints
and Choices." American Journal of Political Science 43 (4):
1069-95.
Nemacheck, Christine. 2007. Strategic Selection: President
Nomination of Supreme Court Justices from Herbert Hoover through George
W. Bush. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press. New York Times.
2010. "No Names, Please." August 19.
Oleszek, Walter J. 2008. "Holds in Senate." CRS Report
for Congress, 98-712.
Podgers, James. 2012. "Sen. Lindsey Graham: Qualifications of
Judicial Nominees Should Count More Than Politics." ABA Journal:
Law News Now, August 4. http://www.abajournal.com/news/
article/lindsey_graham_qualifications_of_judicial_nominees/?utm_source=dlvr.it&utm_medium =twitter (accessed January 16, 2014).
Poole, Keith, and Howard Rosenthal. 1997. Congress: A
Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford
University Press.
--. 2007. Ideology and Congress. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
Publishers.
Roberts, John. 2012. "2012 Year-End Report on the Federal
Judiciary." December 31. http://www
.supremecourt.gov/publicinfo/year-end/2012year-endreport.pdf (accessed
January 16, 2014).
Robinson, William T. 2012. Letter to Senators Reid and McConnell.
June 20. http://www.americanbar
.org/content/dam/aba/uncategorized/GAO/2012
jun20_judvacs_l.authcheckdam.pdf (accessed January 16, 2014).
Sanchez, Humberto. 2012a. "Mitch McConnell Objects to Senate
Democrats' Bid to Confirm 17 Judges." Roll Call, September 20.
--. 2012b. "Senate Filibusters Oklahoma Judicial
Nominee." Roll Call, September 20.
Scherer, Nancy. 2005. Scoring Points: Politicians, Activists, and
the Lower Federal Court Appointment Process. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press.
Scherer, Nancy, Brandon L. Bartels, and Amy Steigerwalt. 2008.
"Sounding the Fire Alarm: The Role of Interest Groups in the Lower
Federal Confirmation Process ."Journal of Politics 10 (October):
1026-039.
Slotnick, Elliot E. 1980. "Reforms injudicial Selection: Will
They Affect the Senate's Role?" Judicature 60 (2): 60-73.
Smith, Steven S., and Marcus Flathman. 1989- "Managing the
Senate Floor: Complex Unanimous Consent Agreements since the
1950s." Legislative Studies Quarterly 14 (3): 349-79
Sollenberger, Mitchell. 2003. "The History of the Blue Slip in
the Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 1917-Present." CRS Report
for Congress, RL 32013.
--. 2010. "Blue Slip: A Theory of Unified and Divided
Government, 1979-2009." Congress and the Presidency 37 (2): 125-56.
Steigerwalt, Amy. 2010. Battle over the Bench: Senators, Interest
Groups and Lower Court Confirmations. Charlottesville: University of
Virginia Press.
Thomas, Ken. 2008. "Senate Approves Michigan Judicial
Nominees." Associated Press State and Local Wire, June 25.
Wawro, Gregory, and Eric Schickler. 2006. Filibuster: Obstruction
and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
RYAN C. BLACK
Michigan State University
ANTHONY J. MADONNA
University of Georgia
RYAN J. OWENS
University of Wisconsin
(1.) While obstruction may be increasing in recent years, it is
certainly not new. Democratic obstruction of judicial nominees during
the Bush administration led then-majority party Republicans to threaten
drastic changes in the chambers' rules (Binder, Madonna, and Smith
2007; Roger 2008; Wawro and Schickler 2006). And it led to considerable
frustration within the Bush administration.
(2.) In response to recent complaints about the increase in Senate
obstruction, the chamber adopted several minor revisions to the rules
governing nominations during the 113th Congress. First, after a
successful cloture motion, postcloture debate over district court
nominees would be restricted to two hours. Second, postcloture debate
over lower-level executive branch nominees would be restricted to eight
hours.
(3.) Determining whether or not a successful filibuster has taken
place is almost entirely arbitrary. While some scholars define a
filibuster as an outright attempt to defeat a bill (generally by not
allowing a final passage vote), others will count attempts to delay the
vote or extract concessions as filibustering. Both perspectives require
some subjective judgment about what constitutes legitimate debate.
(4.) Generally, this is conveyed privately to the party leader. On
several occasions, senators have sought to alter the anonymous hold
procedure. A 2007 change in the Senate's rules had required
senators to publicize any holds issued after six legislative days
(provided a member objected) (Oleszek 2008). Another more recent effort
occurred on January 26, 2011, when the chamber adopted Senate Resolution
28. The resolution established a standing order requiring members to
publicize any objections to unanimous consent agreements (Kucinich and
Brady 2011).
(5.) The blue slip carries with it different norms than filibusters
or holds, but the procedural roots are largely the same. It applies only
to nominations for lower court judgeships, U.S. attorneys, and U.S.
marshals (Sollenberger 2003). We focus only the blue slip in relation to
judicial nominees.
(6.) Identifying the home state senators is generally an easy
calculus. Federal district court boundaries always reside within the
political boundaries of a state. And, while federal circuits span
multiple states, a norm has emerged in which the judiciary committee
sends blue slips to the senators where the retiring circuit court judge
lived (Sollenberger 2003). While there is sometimes controversy over
which state has "rights" to a seat, the normal practice is to
fill the position with a nominee who hails from the same state as the
retiree.
(7.) During its early years, blue slips were simply
information-gathering tools Senate Judiciary Committee chairs used to
evaluate nominees and the predicted opposition to that nominee (Binder
2007). A "Senator's negative assessment of a nominee was meant
to express to the committee his views on the nominee so that the
chairman would be better prepared to deal with the review of the
nomination" (Sollenberger 2003, 9).
(8.) For example, between 1979 and 1981, Ted Kennedy (D-MA) used
his power as Judiciary Committee chair to alter blue slip policy and
make it easier for President Carter to install more women, minorities,
and liberals on the bench.
(9.) Kennedy altered blue slip policy to strip politically powerful
senators (i.e., Southern conservatives) from blocking such nominations
(Sollenberger 2003). When a home state senator failed to return a blue
slip, Kennedy allowed the Judiciary Committee rather than the home state
senator to decide whether to hold a hearing on a nomination.
(10.) Other studies touch briefly on blue slips as they investigate
broader phenomena. For example, Binder and Maltzman (2004) find that
presidents, particularly in times of divided government, take more time
to seek out judicial nominees who are acceptable to ideologically
distant blue slip senators, though they do not examine whether those
senators employed their blue slips negatively. Scherer (2005) examines
how interest group mobilization affects nomination politics generally
and how the blue slip relates to senators' needs to use tools
necessary to influence outcomes.
(11.) While Black, Madonna, and Owens (2011) speak to the
ideological use of blue slips, that study tells us nothing about the
mitigating role of qualifications in the blue slipping decision.
(12.) For simplicity, we follow the literature and assume the
president nominates judges who share his ideology. We believe this
assumption biases against our hypotheses, as should the president
strategically nominative a more centrist judge, that judge is more
likely to be supported by home state senators.
(13.) This number reflects cases terminated on the merits after
oral hearings or submission on briefs. See
http://www.uscourts.gov/iudbususc/iudbus.html, Table S-2.
(14.) http://www.intellectualconservative.com/artide2786.html.
(15.) See http://www.justice.gov/archive/index-olp.html.
(16.) Sollenberger (2010, 130) states that the data from the 109th
and 100th Congresses "were provided to [him] by committee
staff."
(17.) During the time period of our sample, Judiciary Committee
chairs treated the failure to return a blue slip the same as returning a
negative one.
(18.) The results we report below are unchanged if we measure
ideological distance using the first dimension of DW-Nominate instead.
(19.) See ABA Standing Committee on the Federal Judiciary website:
http://www.abanet.org/scfedjud/.
(20.) http://www.fjc.gov/history/home.nsf/page/judges.html.
(21.) We would prefer to count the number of days between when the
blue slip was sent to the senator and the end of the session, but those
data are not available for every Congress in our data. Moreover, the
data that do state when the blue slip was sent provide only approximate
dates. At any rate, our data show that the modal number of days between
a nomination and a blue slip sent out was eight calendar days. The
median number of calendar days was 11, with a standard deviation of 11.
Thus, while the use of the nomination date is not perfect, we believe it
nevertheless captures the broader dynamic we are after.
(22.) The Gallup popularity data can be found at:
http://www.gallup.com/poll/116500/presidential
-approval-ratings-george-bush.aspx.
(23.) More specifically, we define low as being a value of 3 on our
7-point scale. This represents approximately the tenth percentile. For
the high ABA value we use the maximum in our data (i.e., a score of 7).
Because of the high frequency with which nominees receive the maximum
(in our data nearly 44% of nominees earned such a score), this value
represents roughly the sixty-fifth percentile in our data.
(24.) Or, perhaps it was because Bunning was the son of Senator Jim
Bunning (R-KY).
(25.) We use the 356 days (early) and 32 days (late) for this
counterfactual. This represents the ninety-fifth and fifth percentile in
our data, respectively.
Ryan C. Black is an assistant professor of political science at
Michigan State University. He is the coauthor of The Solicitor General
and the United States Supreme Court and Oral Arguments and Coalition
Formation on the U.S. Supreme Court.
Anthony J. Madonna is an assistant professor in the Political
Science Department at the University of Georgia. His work has appeared
in the American Journal of Political Science, Political Research
Quarterly, and the Journal of Politics.
Ryan J. Owens is the Lyons Family Faculty Scholar and an associate
professor of political science at the University of Wisconsin. He is the
coauthor of The Solicitor General and the United States Supreme Court.
AUTHORS' NOTE: We thank Mitchell Sollenherger for making his
data available. Additional thanks to Ryan Bakker, Jamie Carson, and
Richard Vining for helpful comments.
TABLE 1
Probit Regression Model of a Senator's Decision
to Return a Negative Blue Slip
Variables
Ideological Distance 6.869 * (2.555)
ABA Rating 0.430 (0.285)
Circuit Court -0.057 (6.962)
ABA Rating * Ideology -0.727 (0.374)
ABA Rating * Circuit Court -0.349 (1.044)
ABA Rating * Circuit Court * Ideology 0.297 (1.330)
Days until End of Session -0.002 * 0.001
Female Nominee -0.301 (0.236)
Nominee's Age -0.011 (0.017)
Presidential Popularity -0.009 (0.007)
Constant -4.293 (1.674)
Observations 836
log L -143.639
* p < 0.05 (two-tailed test). Probit regression model
of a senator's decision to return to the Senate Judiciary
Committee chair a negative blue slip for a judicial
nominee, 107th-110th Congresses. Standard errors
(reported in parentheses) are clustered on each of the
352 unique nominees in our data.