Stock market prices.
Lo, Andrew W.
Stock Market Prices
Since the catastrophic stock market crash of October 1929 and the
resulting Great Depression, economists and policymakers have been
extremely interested in the behavior of financial asset prices. The
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 and the creation of the Securities and
Exchange Commission were direct consequences of the turbulent markets of
the 1920s, and much subsequent regulatory legislation has been designed
to reduce the wild price swings generally associated with
"speculative" investors. In the wake of the more recent
"October Massacre," understanding how and why equity prices
fluctuate has never been more important. This summary describes some of
what my coauthors and I have learned recently about the random nature of
stock price movements.
The Random Walk
One of the earliest characterizations of rationally determined
stock prices is the random walk model, which says that future price
changes cannot be predicted from past price changes. First developed
from rudimentary economic considerations of "fair games," the
random walk has received broad support from the many early empirical
studies confirming the unpredictability of stock returns, generally
using daily or monthly returns of individual securities.
However, one of my papers with A. Craig McKinlay shows that the
random walk model does not fit aggregate weekly returns during
1962-87.(1) In fact, the weekly returns of a portfolio containing one
share of each security traded on the New York and American Stock
Exchanges (called an "equally weighted" portfolio) exhibit an
autocorrelation of 30 percent, implying that about 10 percent of the
variability of next week's return is explained by this week's
return! An equally weighted portfolio containing only the stocks of
"smaller" companies, companies with relative low market
values, has an autocorrelation of 42 percent and is as high as 49
percent during 1975-87.
This fact surprises many economists because a violation of the
random walk hypothesis necessarily implies that price changes can be
forecast to some degree. The existence of these weekly correlations
suggests that there are unexploited profit opportunities. Two other
facts add to this puzzle: 1) weekly portfolio returns are strongly
positively autocorrelated, but the returns to individual securities
generally are not; in fact, the average autocorrelation across
securities is negative (but insignificant); and 2) the predictability of
returns is quite sensitive to the holding period: serial dependence is
strong and positive for daily and weekly returns but is virtually zero
for returns over a month, a quarter, or a year.
Lead-Lag Effects, Contrarian Profits, and Size
Since the autocorrelation of portfolio returns is the sum of the
individual stocks' autocorrelations and their
cross-autocorrelations (for example, the correlation of this week's
return on stock A with next week's return on stock B), we look to
the cross-autocorrelations to explain the fact that portfolio returns
are forecastable and individual stock returns are not. MacKinlay and I
find that these cross-autocorrelations are strongly positive and exhibit
a distinct lead-lag pattern: the returns on "larger"
stocks--stocks with larger market values--almost always lead those of
"smaller" stocks.(2) That is, this week's returns of
large stocks can forecast next week's returns of smaller stocks,
but not vice-versa. Since individual stocks are weakly negatively
correlated on average, the positive correlation of weekly portfolio
returns is completely caused by these lead-lag effects.
Such effects are also an important source of the apparent
profitability of contrarian investment strategies, strategies that buy
"losers" and sell "winners." For example, suppose
the market consists of only two stocks, A and B, with returns that are
uncorrelated individually but positively cross-correlated. If A's
return is higher than the market this week, the contrarian will sell it
and buy B. But if A and B are positively cross-autocorrelated, a higher
return for A today implies a higher return for B tomorrow (on average).
Thus the contrarian investor profits (on average) from buying B.
Although A's past returns cannot be used to forecast its future
returns, they can be used to forecast B's future returns, and
contrarian trading strategies inadvertently benefit from this.
Our results show that at least half of the expected profits from
one particular contrarian strategy are the result of lead-lag effects.
Economic models attempting to explain the 30 percent autocorrelation in
portfolio returns now must do so in a very specific way: they must
provide a mechanism by which the returns of smaller companies lag those
of larger ones.
Other aspects of the behavior of stock returns also seem to be
related to the company's market value or "size." For
example, small stocks are largely responsible for the "January
effect," an empirical regularity in which equity returns over the
past 25 years have been consistently higher than usual between the last
few trading days of December and the first few of January. Also, the
returns of small stocks are generally more volatile than those of large
stocks. Moreover, for the contrarian trading strategy that MacKinlay and
I examine, small stocks tend to yield higher expected profits. These
empirical observations probably signal substantial differences between
the ecomonic structure of small and large corporations. But how these
differences are manifested in the behavior of equity returns cannot be
reliably determined through data analysis alone.
In a related context, MacKinlay and I have shown that when
empirical facts motivate the search for additional empirical facts in
the same data, this can lead to anomalous findings that are more
apparent than real.(3) Moreover, the more we scrutinize a collection of
data, the more likely we are to find interesting (spurious) patterns.
Since stock market prices are perhaps the most studied economic
quantities to date, financial economists must be particularly vigilant.
The importance of size would be much more convincing if it were based on
a model of economic equilibrium in which the relationship between size
and the behavior of asset returns is well articulated. I hope to provide
such a model in the near future.
Nonsynchronous Trading
Perhaps the simplest explanation of the predictability in returns
is a kind of measurement error to which financial data are particularly
susceptible, often called the "infrequent trading" or
"nonsynchronous trading" problem. This arises when prices
recorded at different times are treated as if they were sampled
simultaneously. For example, the daily prices of financial securities
quoted in the Wall Street Journal are usually "closing"
prices, prices at which the last transaction in each of those securities
occurred on the previous business day. If the last transaction in stock
A occurs at 2 p.m. and the last transaction in stock B occurs at 4 p.m.,
then included in B's closing price is information not available
when A's closing price was set.
This can create spurious predictability in asset returns since
economywide shocks will be reflected first in the prices of the most
frequently traded securities, with less frequently traded stocks
responding with the lag. Even when there is no statistical relationship
between stocks A and B, their measured returns will seem
cross-autocorrelated simply because we have mistakenly assumed that they
are measured simultaneously.
MacKinlay and I have constructed an explicit model of this
phenomenon that is capable of generating size-determined lead-lag
patterns (since small stocks trade less frequently than large stocks
do), and positive portfolio correlation in weekly returns.(4) Using this
frame-work, we can estimate the degree of nonsynchronous trading
implicit in the observed means, variances, and autocorrelations of the
data. With weekly returns, the infrequent trading necessary to produce
an autocorrelation of 30 percent is empirically implausible, requiring
securities to go for several days without trading on average. Therefore,
infrequent trading may be responsible for a portion of the observed
autocorrelation, but it cannot explain all of it.
Long-Term Memory
In contrast to the positive autocorrelation MacKinlay and I find in
short-horizon stock returns, others have reported negative serial
correlation in longer-horizon (three-to-five-year) returns for the
longer 1926-87 sample period. This may be a sympton of "long-range
dependence" or long memory in asset returns, a kind of dependence
often found in natural phenomena. Unlike conventional models of economic
time series in which shocks of the remote past have little influence on
the distant future, the serial dependence of long-memory time series
decays far more slowly. This has profound economic and econometric implications: long-range dependence can change the optimal portfolio mix
drastically for any individual and also affects the statistical
procedures that we use to learn about asset returns.
To test for long memory in stock returns, I develop a statistic
based on Benoit Mandelbrot's "rescaled range," which is
robust to the short-horizon serial correlation discussed above.(5) In
contrast to an earlier study that claims to have uncovered long memory
in the stock market using Mandelbrot's procedure, I show that there
is no evidence of long-range dependence in daily, weekly, monthly, or
annual returns over various sample periods once short-term correlations
are properly taken into account. Joseph G. Haubrich and I have also
looked for long-term memory in aggregate output, with much the same
results.(6) Although we show that long-range dependence can arise
naturally in an equilibrium model of real business cycles, the current
empirical evidence is not supportive.
Directions for Future Research
Perhaps the most pressing fact in need of a theory is that the
predictability of stock returns is strongest for weekly holding periods.
Several equilibrium models of time-varying expected rates of return
already have been proposed as explanations of long-horizon return
predictability, but they require unrealistic parameter values to capture
weekly variations in stock price changes. Moreover, none of the models
is yet able to generate the kind of lead-lag structure exhibited by the
data. This suggests the need for innovation in asset pricing paradigms,
perhaps by a more explicit modeling of learning behavior, the
transmission of information, and the microstructure of financial
markets. Although traditionally considered inappropriate for academic
scrutiny, subjects such as technical analysis and market psychology may
play an important role in future models of rational economic equilibrium
in asset markets.
(1)A. W. Lo and A. C. MacKinlay, "Stock Market Prices Do Not
Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test,"
NBER Reprint No. 1180, May 1989. (2)A. W. Lo and A. C. MacKinlay,
"When Are Contrarian Profits Due to Stock Market
Overreaction?" NBER Working Paper No. 2977, May 1989. (3)A. W. Lo
and A. C. MacKinlay, "Data-Snooping Biases in Tests of Financial
Asset Pricing Models," NBER Working Paper No. 3001, June 1989.
(4)A. W. Lo and A. C. MacKinlay, "An Econometric Analysis of
Non-synchronous Trading," NBER Working Paper No. 2960, May 1989.
(5)A. W. Lo, "Long-Term Memory in Stock Market Prices," NBER
Working Paper No. 2984, May 1989. (6)J. G. Haubrich and A. W. Lo,
"The Sources and Nature of Long-Term Memory in the Business
Cycle," NBER Working Paper No. 2951, April 1989.