Working and earning under different rules: what the United States can learn from labor market institutions in other developed countries.
Freeman, Richard B.
Working and Earning Under Different Rules: What the United States Can
Learn from Labor Market Institutions in Other Developed Countries
Labor markets are the most idiosyncratic feature of developed
countries, differing across national lines in more ways than markets for
goods, finance, and the like. Some advanced capitalist countries are
highly unionized; others are largely nonunion. Some countries rely on
specific institutions to set pay: courts determine pay increases in
Australia; the government extends collective bargaining agreements throughout the economy in Germany; in Japan, a large proportion of pay
consists of bonuses, and the Shunto Offensive sets standards for wage
increases throughout the economy. The United States, Canada, and the
United Kingdom rely more on the free operation of markets.
There is a similar range of variation among countries in programs
and institutions to aid those without work. Some countries have
extensive income maintenance, social welfare, and labor market mobility
and training programs, devoting considerable resources to redistributing
income. Sweden is the typical example, but throughout Western Europe unemployment insurance systems have been more generous than the American
system. The United States has relatively limited social welfare programs
for most workers and for those without work, and relies to an
unprecedented extent on the private charitable sector to deal with many
social problems.
One of the most striking features of the 1980s was the substantial
divergence in institutions and outcomes among developed western
countries, often in ways that contravened the patterns of previous
postwar history. The United States, which traditionally had higher rates
of unemployment but relatively shorter durations of joblessness than
Europe, experienced a "jobs explosion" with resultant lower
unemployment than Western Europe. At the same time, the United States
suffered rising inequality in earnings and poverty rates that eventually
exceeded those in many other developed countries, and lost much of its
lead in productivity and real earnings per person. The proportion of the
work force organized in trade unions fell dramatically in the United
States while remaining at higher levels in many other countries,
including Canada. In earlier decades, the United States led the world in
reducing working time toward the 40-hour week and extending vacation and
holiday pay, but in the 1980s American workers put in more hours than
did workers in Europe.
When unemployment rates rose in Europe in the early 1980s, most
discussion of the difference between Western European and American labor
markets focused on the advantages of labor arrangements of the U.S.
style. The buzzword was "flexibility" of markets. Some
analysts argued instead for "neocorporatist" arrangements,
such as Sweden's, with central labor unions, employer
confederations, and the state regulating the labor market. But most
discussion focused on the problems of unemployment insurance systems
that grant high benefits for years, long-term labor contracts that make
firing workers difficult and hiring presumably more expensive, and so
on. There was much concern with what Western Europe could learn from the
flexible arrangements of the United States, but little thought as to
what the United States might learn from European labor institutions.
The situation is the early 1990s looks quite different. There are
rising inequality, high rates of poverty, particularly among children,
homelessness, and related social problems in the United States.
Unemployment rates, while still moderate, are now higher than those in
West Germany. Widespread concern about the quality of the American labor
force and American managerial practices has raised serious doubts about
the way the United States has responded to the economic changes of the
past decade or so. From an American perspective, the question is how
foreign countries avoided some of our problems. We now need to ask what
we can learn from our OECD peers to improve our society and our
competitive economic performance.
The NBER's labor program has begun a large research endeavor
to understand the operation of labor markets and income
maintenance/safety net programs in other countries. We began with a
research project comparing the United States with Canada. Ultimately
there will be research projects on different aspects of labor relations
and income maintenance programs in the United States and other OECD
countries:
1) The Operation of Works Councils
Within Enterprises
2) Private Firm Training of Workers
3) Wage Structures and Alternate
Wage-Setting Systems
4) Income Maintenance and Social Welfare Programs
5) Programs to Aid the Extremely Poor
Some Early Results
A key area in which the U.S. labor market has diverged from many
other OECD countries is the representation of labor at enterprises and
in national economic decisionmaking. While the decline in union density
is not unique to the United States - density dropped in the United
Kingdom during Mrs. Thatcher's term in office, in the Netherlands,
in Japan, and in France - nowhere has density fallen as much as in the
private sector of the United States, and it has remained high in many
other OECD countries, such as Germany, Belgium, Denmark, Sweden, and
most notably Canada.
At the same time, most European countries have developed and
strengthened the powers of "works councils," designed to allow
management and labor to treat local workplace problems cooperatively.
The United States, by contrast, has come to rely increasingly on the
competitive market and on legal means of regulating local workplace
arrangements, through legislation and judicial intervention. Consistent
with the mixed results of the U.S. system, the European experience with
quality-of-work circles and other innovative labor practices is that for
labor-management cooperative arrangements to work, workers must be given
some genuine authority or influence over decisions, by legislation or
through union activity. The interesting question, on which research has
yet to speak, is the extent to which these differing practices affect
productivity and worker well-being in, say, similar plants of comparable
multinational firms across the countries.
Although earnings differentials between more and less skilled or
educated labor, and equality among workers, appear to be rising in most
developed countries - presumably as a result of shifts in demand based
on technological and other factors, and to the growth or world trade -
the extent of the increase seems less extensive elsewhere. In Canada,
wage differentials between more and less educated workers barely
increased in the 1980s, while the differentials skyrocketed in the
United States. One reason is that the number of college graduates grew
more rapidly in Canada than in the United States in the 1980s. In
Sweden, earnings differentials also rose. Swedish employers, unions, and
workers came to realize that wage differentials had been compressed too
much to make economic sense, and centralized collective bargaining broke
down. However, the levels of differentials and increases are magnitudes
different from those in the United States. Only in the United Kingdom
have earnings differentials seemingly risen as much as in the United
States.
Canada's experienced in the 1980s, when rates of poverty, in
particular among children, fell below those in the United States, shows
that alternative income maintenance programs in very similar economies
can produce substantially different outcomes. The Canadian systems of
child support, unemployment insurance, and health insurance appear to
have worked better in "leaning against the wind" of rising
inequality than comparable American programs. While virtually all
research shows that there is a substantial labor supply response to
providing benefits for those who are not working, extending the
durations of unemployment benefits and linking benefits to work -
"workfare" - appears to induce high labor participation,
particularly of women. The Swedish welfare system is largely a workfare
system. The relatively generous unemployment insurance entitlements in
Canada appear to have induced a substantial number of women, who
otherwise would not have worked, to work for at least part of the year.
Surprisingly, countries with very different labor market
arrangements - the United States, with its decentralized, largely
nonunion system, and Sweden, with its highly coordinated union system -
had quite similar macroeconomic outcomes, with better employment
experiences but productivity and real wage experiences that were
relatively poorer than countries with less "extreme"
arrangements. The implication is that there may be quite different paths
to the same macroeconomic outcomes, even though the systems produce
different microeconomic outcomes.
Overall, the NBER project on "working and earnings under
different rules" will widen the range of economic experiences and
data on which labor economists and others test theories and derive
generalizations about the operation of market economies. The project
should increase our understanding of which aspects of economic behavior
are universal and which are influenced by laws, culture, and so forth.
While the project is empirical at its core, it has a potentially close
tie with modern game - theoretic analyses of markets that show that
rational behavior can lead to very different outcomes depending on the
precise rules of the game. The question of how different labor practices
fit together into a "system" - for instance, whether one can
adapt European works council or German apprenticeship programs, or
Japanese style labor relations, to other countries - also calls out for
theory as well as evidence.