Health economics.
Grossman, Michael
In the five years since my last report on the NBER's Program
on Health Economics, members of the program have focused on the
economics of substance use and abuse and on the determinants of
pregnancy resolutions and their relation to infant and early childhood
health. Studies in the former area consider the effects of prices,
taxes, sanctions, and advertising on the use of such harmfully addictive
substances as cigarettes, alcohol, and illegal drugs. They also consider
the effects of marijuana, cocaine, and alcohol consumption on marriage
and divorce, out-of-wedlock births, participation in welfare, employment
and unemployment, and crime. Studies in the latter area investigate the
effects of public policies on whether pregnancies result in live births
or induced abortions, the effects on infant health outcomes of
expansions in Medicaid income-eligibility thresholds for pregnant women
and young children, and the process by which families allocate resources
to the health and development of their children. All of this research
takes seriously the distinction between health as an output and medical
care as one of the many inputs in the promotion and maintenance of
health.
Price Sensitivity of Cigarettes, Alcohol, and Illegal Drugs
The governments of the United States and many other countries have
chosen to regulate some addictive substances (for example, cigarettes
and alcohol) via taxation; minimum-age purchase laws; restrictions on
consumption in schools, the workplace, and public places; and stiff
fines for driving under the influence of alcohol. Other substances (for
example, cocaine and marijuana) are outlawed completely. The prices of
these substances will rise because of taxation, other forms of
regulation, and bans. Thus, measuring their responsiveness to price is
important in determining the optimal level of taxation and the impacts
of legalization. Contrary to conventional wisdom, our studies find that
the consumption of addictive substances is quite sensitive to price.
Current antismoking initiatives in the United States focus on
curtailing youth smoking. This is not surprising, as numerous studies
show that 90 percent of all smokers begin the habit as teenagers. Thus
cigarette control policies that discourage smoking in this age group may
be the most effective way to achieve long-run reductions in smoking in
all segments of the population. Using nationally representative samples
for the 1990s, Frank J. Chaloupka and I show that excise tax hikes,
which result in higher cigarette prices, have large negative effects on
teenage smoking.(1) Our study capitalizes on the substantial variation
in cigarette prices in the U.S. states, mainly caused by the very
different state tax rates on cigarettes. The proposed settlement of the
Medicaid lawsuits brought against the tobacco industry by the attorneys
general of most states, and rejected by the U.S. Senate in June 1998,
would have raised the price of a pack of cigarettes by approximately 34
percent. based on our estimates, this price hike would have reduced the
number of teenage smokers by approximately 24 percent. This would have
translated into more than 1.3 million fewer smoking-related premature
deaths in the current generation of people 17 and younger.
Chaloupka and Henry Wechsler report that smoking by college
students is almost as responsive to price as smoking by high school
students.(2) Chaloupka, John A. Tauras, and I indicate that a similar
finding holds for the use of smokeless tobacco by teenage males.(3)
Chaloupka and Rosalie Liccardo Pacula find that the benefits, in terms
of curtailments in youth cigarette smoking, attributable to price hikes
are not shared equally by all demographic groups, though.(4) For
example, among male teenagers, a 10 percent increase in the price of
cigarettes shrinks the number of whites who smoke by about 9 percent and
of blacks who smoke by 16 percent. The effects are much smaller for
white female teenagers and are nonexistent for black female teenagers.
Alcoholic beverage prices also vary among areas of the United
States for the same reason that cigarette prices vary: states tax these
beverages at very different rates. Chaloupka, Ismail Sirtalan, and I
capitalize on this variation to estimate the demand among individuals
between the ages of 17 and 29 - the prevalence of alcohol dependence and
abuse is highest in this age group - for alcohol (measured by drinks
consumed in the past year).(5) We report statistically significant and
numerically large linkages among past, present, and future consumption
of alcohol for these young people. These effects support Gary S. Becker
and Kevin M. Murphy's theory of rational addiction.(6) The long-run
elasticity of alcohol consumption with respect to its price, negative
0.65, is substantial. This elasticity, which takes account of linkages
in consumption over time, is 60 percent larger than the comparable
short-run price elasticity (which holds past consumption constant), and
is twice as large as the elasticity that ignores addiction. Thus, a tax
hike designed to curtail consumption may not have a favorable
cost-benefit ratio unless it is based on the long-run price elasticity.
Sara J. Markowitz and I provide direct evidence of the impact of
changes in the cost of alcohol on one negative consequence of excessive
alcohol consumption: domestic violence toward children.(7) Using the
1976 Physical Violence in American Families survey, we find that a 10
percent increase in the state excise tax on beer would reduce the
probability of severe violence by 2 percent and the probability of
overall violence by 1 percent. Our estimates imply that a 10 percent
hike in the beer tax would have lowered the number of severely abused
children by about 132,000 in 1975. By pooling data from the 1976 and
1985 Physical Violence in American Families surveys with a set of state
dummies, Markowitz and I show that the negative tax effects are not
attributable to unobserved state factors.(8) In another study, Markowitz
and I find that the incidence of four different types of violent
behavior on college campuses falls as the price of beer rises in the
state in which the student's college is located.(9)
In several studies, my colleagues and I have analyzed the issue of
legalizing cocaine, marijuana, and heroin by providing estimates of the
price elasticities of those substances. In addition, we have examined
whether these substances are substitutes or complements for alcohol.
Chaloupka and I focus on cocaine "participation" and
"frequency-of-use-given-positive-participation" in a group of
individuals between the ages of 17 and 29, the age range in which the
prevalence of cocaine consumption is at its highest.(10) Our study draws
on cocaine prices based on purchases made by drug enforcement agents who
were apprehending drug dealers. As in the case of alcohol, we find
positive linkages among past, present, and future participation or
frequency. Our results suggest that a permanent 10 percent price
reduction that is attributed to legalization would cause the number of
young adult cocaine users to grow by approximately 10 percent in the
long run; the frequency of use among users would increase by a little
more than 3 percent. Further, the effects of temporary police crackdowns
on drugs or a temporary federal war on drugs may have created a
misleading impression about the reaction to permanent price changes.
According to our estimates, a 10 percent price hike for one year would
reduce total cocaine consumption (that is, participation multiplied by
frequency) by approximately 5 percent, whereas a 10 percent price hike
that is permanent would lower consumption by 14 percent.
Chaloupka, Tauras, and I confirm that negative effects of cocaine
price also are observed in cross-sections of high school seniors.(11)
Moreover, we report that residents of the 11 states that decriminalized
the possession of small amounts of marijuana in the 1970s are more
likely to use this drug. Henry Saffer and Chaloupka estimate demand
functions for cocaine, marijuana, heroin, and alcohol in a large
national sample of persons of all ages.(12) They obtain a consistent
pattern of negative own-price effects and of complementarity between
alcohol and illicit drugs. In a related study, Saffer and Chaloupka
report that these price effects do not differ among demographic
groups.(13) In both a cross-sectional study and a longitudinal study of
young adults, Pacula finds complementarity between alcohol and
marijuana.(14) One important implication of these findings is that the
effects of policies that curtail alcohol consumption are reinforced
because the same policies also curtail drug consumption.
Effects of Advertising on Alcohol Abuse and Cigarette Smoking
In addition to excise tax increases, restrictions on advertising
can be used to reduce alcohol abuse and cigarette smoking. For these
restrictions to be effective, though, it must be demonstrated that
advertising stimulates consumption. Many previous studies have failed to
do this because they use aggregate time-series data with little
variation in advertising. In a time series of U.S. cities, Saffer
addresses this deficiency by estimating the effects on highway fatality
rates, more than half of which involve the use of alcohol, of spot
television, spot radio, and billboard advertising of alcoholic
beverages.(15) The advertising measures vary considerably among places
at a moment in time. Saffer's results indicate that alcohol
advertising increases motor vehicle fatalities of persons of all ages
and fatalities of persons between the ages of 18 and 20. The last
finding is notable because young drivers account for a disproportionate
share of those involved in motor vehicle collisions.
In two other studies Saffer uses international data for
approximately 20 countries over a 20-year period to assess the effects
of banning advertising of alcohol and cigarettes. In the alcohol study
he reports that alcohol consumption, motor vehicle mortality, and liver
cirrhosis mortality (a standard proxy for heavy alcohol consumption) are
lower in countries that ban broadcast advertising.(16) In the cigarette
study, he finds that per capita cigarette consumption is lower in
countries that ban broadcast, magazine, billboard, and other advertising
of cigarettes.(17)
Effects of Illicit Drug and Alcohol Use
Robert Kaestner addresses the effects of marijuana and cocaine use
on three outcomes: marriage and divorce rates; the probability of being
a single parent; and welfare participation. In one study, he finds that
nonblack drag users are more likely to be unmarried because their first
marriage occurs later and their marriages do not last as long as those
of nondrug users.(18) Thus, by causing a delay in the age of marriage,
substance abuse may increase the time at risk for an unintended
pregnancy. In a second study, Kaestner finds that drug use is a
significant predictor of being an unwed mother and of having an
out-of-wedlock birth.(19) In the final study from this project, Kaestner
shows that past-year marijuana use is positively related to future
welfare participation (participation in the four years following use) by
women.(20) In related research, John Mullahy and Jody L. Sindelar find
that heavy consumption of alcohol by men and women results in
substantial reductions in employment rates and similar increases in
unemployment rates.(21)
H. Naci Mocan and Hope Corman study the effects of drug use on
crime in New York City. They use monthly data on crime rates and
drug-related deaths (a proxy for drug use) for 1970 to 1990.(22)
Controlling for arrests, the size of the police force, and the
prevalence of poverty, they find significant positive effects of drug
use on the property-related crimes of robbery and burglary. Contrary to
popular belief, however, they find no significant relationships between
drug use and the violent crimes of felonious assault and murder.
Pregnancy Resolutions and Infant and Early Childhood Health
Outcomes
Theodore J. Joyce and Kaestner assess whether recent changes in two
state policies - parental notification laws for minors seeking an
abortion and Medicaid income-eligibility expansions - are associated
with changes in pregnancy resolution. They treat changes in these
policies as exogenous shifts in the cost of abortion and birth. They
find that parental involvement laws have small effects on minors as a
group but have relatively large effects on white teens who are 16 years
of age.(23) They also report that expansions in Medicaid eligibility
raise the probability that a pregnancy is carried to term for non-blacks
but they uncover no effect for blacks.(24)
The estimated effects in this last study are based on data for
three states and do not indicate whether the reduction in the
probability of an abortion is attributable to a fall in abortions, a
rise in births, or both. Joyce, Kaestner, and Florence Kwan expand the
analysis to 15 states and investigate birth rates (births to unmarried
women aged 19 to 27 divided by the number of women in this age range)
and abortion rates as separate outcomes.(25) They find that the Medicaid
expansions are associated with a 5 percent increase in the birth rate
among white women, but the expansions do not influence the rate among
black women. Overall, there is no apparent effect on the abortion rate.
They conclude that subsidized health care for low-income pregnant women
may encourage white women to have more children than they would have
without coverage.
The Medicaid income-eligibility expansions increased the quantity
of prenatal care received by poor pregnant women in the late 1980s and
in the 1990s. Joyce reports, however, that the incidence of low birth
weight among infants born to these mothers did not decline in New York
City.(26) Kaestner obtains similar results in a national sample.(27)
While these findings raise questions about the payoffs to infant health
of investments in medical care, Christopher J. Ruhm indicates that
investments in parental time may produce benefits.(28) Using aggregate
data for nine European countries over almost three decades, he shows
that entitlements to parental leave are negatively correlated with
postneonatal and child mortality rates, presumably because leave
provides parents with more time to invest in their young children.
Joyce, Kaestner, and Sanders Korenman take a broader approach to
the production of infant and early childhood health and development by
considering the effects of pregnancy intentions on the resources
allocated to infants and children.(29) They find little evidence that
unintended pregnancy is associated with low birth weight, retarded
cognitive development, or other behavioral problems, particularly in
estimates that they obtain from sibling differences. These estimates
compare a sibling who was unwanted to his or her wanted sibling, thus
eliminating the effects of a common home environment. The authors do
find that these outcomes are related to factors correlated with family
resources, such as income, mother's education and cognitive
development, and family structure. This suggests that polices that
reduce births resulting from unwanted pregnancies may have smaller
payoffs than policies that reduce the social and environmental
deprivations suffered by households into which unwanted children are
born.
1 F. J. Chaloupka and M. Grossman, "Price, Tobacco Control
Policies, and Youth Smoking," NBER Working Paper No. 5740,
September 1996.
2 F. J. Chaloupka and H. Wechsler, "Price, Tobacco Control
Policies, and Smoking among Young Adults." Journal of Health
Economics, 16 (3), (June 1997), pp. 359- 73.
3 F. J. Chaloupka, J. A. Tauras, and M. Grossman, "Public
Policy and Youth Smokeless Tobacco Use." NBER Working Paper No.
5524, April 1996; published in Southern Economic Journal, 64 (2),
(October 1997), pp. 503-16.
4 F. J. Chaloupka and R. L. Pacula, "An Examination of Gender
and Race Differences in Youth Smoking Responsiveness to Price and
Tobacco Control Policies," NBER Working Paper No. 6541, April 1998.
5 M. Grossman, F. J. Chaloupka, and 1. Sirtalan, "An Empirical
Analysis of Alcohol Addiction: Results from the Monitoring the Future Panels," Economic Inquiry, 36 (1), (January 1998), pp. 39-48.
6 G. S. Becker and K. M. Murphy, "A Theory of Rational
Addiction," Journal of Political Economy, 96 (4), (August 1988),
pp. 675-700.
7 S. J. Markowitz and M. Grossman, "Alcohol Regulation and
Domestic Violence Towards Children," NBER Working Paper No. 6359,
January 1998; published in Contemporary Economic Policy, 16 (3), (July
1998), pp. 309-20.
8 -----, "The Effects of Alcohol Regulation on Physical Child
Abuse," NBER Working Paper No. 6629, July 1998.
9 M. Grossman and S. J. Markowitz, "Alcohol Regulation and
Violence on College Campuses," paper presented at the annual
meeting of the American Economic Association, Chicago, January 1998.
10 M. Grossman and F. J. Chaloupka, "The Demand for Cocaine by
Young Adults: A Rational Addiction Approach," NBER Working Paper
No. 5713, August 1996; published in Journal of Health Economics, 17 (4),
(August 1998), pp. 427-74.
11 F. J. Chaloupka, M. Grossman, and J. A. Tauras, "The Demand
for Cocaine and Marijuana by Youth," NBER Working Paper No. 6411,
February 1998.
12 H. Saffer and F. J. Chaloupka, "The Demand for Illicit
Drugs," NBER Working Paper No. 5238, August 1995, and Economic
Inquiry, forthcoming.
13 H. Saffer and F. J. Chaloupka, "Demographic Differentials
in the Demand for Alcohol and Illicit Drugs," NBER Working Paper
No. 6432, February 1998.
14 R. L. Pacula, "Does Increasing the Beer Tax Reduce
Marijuana Consumption?" Journal of Health Economics, 17 (5),
(October 1998), pp. 557-86; and "Adolescent Alcohol and Marijuana
Consumption: Is There Really a Gateway Effect?" NBER Working Paper
No. 6348, January 1998.
15 H. Saffer, "Alcohol Advertising and Motor Vehicle
Fatalities," Review of Economics and Statistics, 79 (3), (August
1997), pp. 431-42.
16 -----, "Alcohol Advertising Bans and Public Health,"
paper presented at the annual meeting of the Western Economic
Association International San Francisco, June 1996.
17 -----, "The Effect of Cigarette Advertising Bans and
Warning Labels on Cigarette Smoking," paper presented at the Third
Pacific Rim Allied Economic Organizations Conference, Bangkok, Thailand,
January 1998.
18 R. Kaestner, "The Effects of Cocaine and Marijuana Use on
Marriage and Marital Stability,"Journal of Family Issues, 18 (2),
(March 1997), pp. 145-73.
19 -----, "Drug Use, Culture, and Welfare Incentives:
Correlates of Family Structure and Out-of-Wedlock Birth," Eastern
Economic Journal, forthcoming.
20 R. Kaestner, "Drug Use and AFDC Participation: Is There a
Connection?," NBER Working Paper No. 5555, May 1996; published in
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 17 (3), (Summer 1998), pp.
495-520.
21 J. Mullahy and J. Sindelar, "Employment, Unemployment, and
Problem Drinking," Journal of Health Economics, 15 (4), (August
1996), pp. 409-34.
22 H. N. Mocan and H. Corman, "A Time-Series Analysis of
Crime, Drug Abuse, and Deterrence in New York City," NBER Working
Paper No. 5463, February 1996; revised February 1998.
23 T. Joyce and R. Kaestner, "State Reproductive Policies and
Adolescent Pregnancy Resolution: The Case of Parental Involvement Laws,
"Journal of Health Economics, 15 (5), (October 1996), pp. 579-607.
24 -----, "The Effect of Expansions in Medicaid Income
Eligibility on Abortion," Demography, 33 (2), (May 1996), pp.
181-92.
25 T. Joyce, R. Kaestner, and F. Kwan, "Is Medicaid
Pronatalist? The Effect of Eligibility Expansions on Abortions and
Births," Family Planning Perspectives, 30 (3), (May/June 1998), p.
127.
26 T. Joyce, "Impact of Augmented Prenatal Care on Birth
Outcomes of Medicaid Recipients in New York City," NBER Working
Paper No. 6029, May 1997, and Journal of Health Economics, forthcoming.
27 R. Kaestner, "Health Insurance, the Quantity and Quality of
Prenatal Care and Infant Health, "paper presented at the annual
meeting of the American Economic Association, Chicago, January 1998, and
Inquiry, forthcoming.
28 C. J. Rubin, "Parental Leave and Child Health," NBER
Working Paper No. 6554, May 1998.
29 T. Joyce, R. Kaestner, and S. Korenman, "The Effect of
Pregnancy Intention on Child Development," paper presented at the
annual meeting of the Population Association of America, Washington,
D.C., March 1997.