The determinants of individual saving and investment outcomes.
Madrian, Brigitte C.
Over the past 30 years, employer provided defined contribution (DC)
savings plan largely have displaced traditional defined benefit (DB)
pensions in the private sector. In 1975, there were 2.4 active defined
benefit plan participants for each participant in a private sector
defined contribution savings plan. By 2007, these proportions had almost
reversed, with 3.4 active defined contribution savings plan participants
for each defined benefit plan participant. As this shift puts more and
more individuals in the position of having to self-manage the process of
saving for retirement, a natural question is just how well are
individuals doing, and what factors affect their retirement saving
outcomes. My research over the past several years has tried to address
these broad questions.
Institutional Features and Savings Outcomes
Much of my recent research evaluates the effects of different
institutional features on individual savings and investing outcomes. One
example of such a feature is the default--that is, what happens if an
individual does nothing? As an example, in a typical employer-sponsored
savings plan, individually are only enrolled if they actively elect to
join the plan: the default is non-participation. Some companies,
however, have a different default--they automatically enroll employees
in their savings plan unless employees actively opt-out.
My research with several different collaborators, most notably
David Laibson, James Choi, Andrew Metrick, and John Beshears, shows that
changes in the nature of savings plan defaults have a tremendous impact
on realized outcomes. We examine savings plan participation rates for
employees hired before and after several firms instituted automatic
enrollment and find that participation is substantially higher under
automatic enrollment. (1) One concern with automatic enrollment is that
it may "coerce" employees into savings plan participation. If
so, we would expect that many participants under automatic enrollment
should eventually opt out of the savings plan. But we observe very low
attrition rates under either an opt-in or an opt-out participation
regime. High participation rates and low attrition rates under automatic
enrollment suggest that most employees do not object to saving for
retirement. In the absence of automatic enrollment, however, many simply
delay joining their savings plan.
Interestingly, the impact of automatic enrollment on savings plan
participation is not very dependent on the existence or generosity of an
employer match) This finding is significant because many extensions of
automatic enrollment (for example, the recently adopted KiwiSaver
program in New Zealand, or the Automatic IRA proposals in the United
States) do not require an employer match but nonetheless allow
individuals to opt out.
Automatic enrollment also affects savings plan contribution rates
and asset allocations. In an opt-in regime, employees must choose a
contribution rate and asset allocation when they enroll. Under automatic
enrollment, the company specifies a default contribution rate and asset
allocation for employees who don't actively choose otherwise. In
companies without automatic enrollment, the modal contribution rate
tends to be the match threshold (the contribution rate at which
employees receive the full employer match). In contrast, the modal
contribution rate of participants hired under automatic enrollment is
the automatic enrollment default chosen by the company (initial defaults
of 2 percent or 3 percent of pay, usually below the match threshold, are
typical). This shift in the modal contribution rate is driven not only
by the increased participation generated by automatic enrollment (which
moves people from zero to a positive contribution rate), but also by
individuals who would have otherwise contributed at a higher rate but
who instead remain at the automatic enrollment default.
Similar patterns hold with respect to asset allocation. A large
fraction of savings plan participants stick with the employer-chosen
default asset allocation under automatic enrollment, even when the
default is an allocation that very few savings plan participants
actively elected prior to automatic enrollment. Asset allocation
defaults also matter outside the context of automatic enrollment; in
companies that direct matching contributions to employer stock, very few
employees actively change their allocation ex post, even when they have
the ability to do so. (3)
Why do defaults have such a persistent effect on outcomes? One
explanation is that the default is perceived as an endorsement of a
particular outcome. There is some evidence consistent with this notion.
(4) First, savings plan participants who were themselves not affected by
automatic enrollment are more likely to have an asset allocation that
mirrors the automatic enrollment default in effect for more recently
hired employee cohorts if they themselves did not elect savings plan
participation until after automatic enrollment was adopted. Second,
savings plan participants who were subject to automatic enrollment but
who take action to move away from the automatic enrollment default have
asset allocation outcomes that are closer to the default portfolio than
do participants not affected by automatic enrollment--that is, their
movement away from the default is complete.
A second explanation for the persistence of defaults is that
opting-out of a default may be cognitively difficult. For example,
initiating savings plan participation in the absence of automatic
enrollment is a complicated choice that involves electing both a
contribution rate and an asset allocation. Automatic enrollment
simplifies this decision by decoupling participation from these other
ancillary choices. Evidence that such complexity matters comes from two
recent papers that evaluate a low-cost manipulation called "Quick
Enrollment". This intervention reduces the complexity of savings
plan enrollment by allowing employees to elect participation at a
contribution rate and asset allocation pre-selected by their employer.
(5) At one company studied, Quick Enrollment tripled participation among
new hires relative to a standard opt-in regime. When Quick Enrollment
was made available to previously hired employees who were not
participating in their savings plan at two different firms, the
subsequent enrollment rates of these non-participants increased by 12 to
25 percentage points relative to what would have been predicted in the
absence of the intervention.
In many settings, it is hard to avoid having a default outcome. One
alternative, however, is to require individuals to make an active choice
for themselves--an "active decision." In the context of
employer-sponsored savings plans, such an approach also influences
outcomes relative to the typical norm of non-participation. For example,
research on a company that changed its savings plan enrollment regime
from one that required employees to fill out a form either affirmatively electing or affirmatively rejecting savings plan participation to a
"standard enrollment" (for example opt-in) regime finds that
savings plan participation three months after hire declined from
approximately 70 percent (when an active decision was required) to
approximately 40 percent (when no active decision was required). (6)
Requiring an active decision has an impact on asset allocation
outcomes as well. In a recent paper, Choi, Laibson, and I (7) study a
company at which employer matching contributions were originally made in
the form of employer stock, but with no restrictions on subsequent
diversification. At some point, the firm decided to require employees
instead to explicitly choose their own asset allocation for matching
contributions upon enrollment in the plan (this allocation could differ
from that chosen for employees' own contributions). Because there
were no constraints on trading out of employer stock before this active
decision was required, savings plan participants could effect the same
asset allocation for matching contributions under either regime. In
practice, however, very few participants in the initial matching regime
ever actively reallocated their match balances; in contrast, under the
active decision regime, participants tended to choose an asset
allocation for their matching contributions that largely mirrored that
chosen for their own contributions, and overall exposure to employer
stock fell dramatically as a result. In addition to highlighting the
difference in outcomes that occurs under a default versus an
active-decision-making regime, the results in this paper also suggest
that individuals engage in mental accounting and narrow framing when
making their asset allocation choices.
Compared to the effects of the different approaches to savings plan
enrollment discussed above, standard economic incentives have a
surprisingly weak impact on savings plan participation. Having an
employer match does increase participation in a savings plan, but many
eligible employees still fail to sign up in the absence of automatic
enrollment even with such a match. (8) Choi, Laibson, and I examine a
group of workers who face particularly strong financial incentives for
savings plan participation: employees over the age of 59 1/2 who are
vested, who have an employer match, and who, by virtue of their age, can
make unrestricted savings plan withdrawals with no tax penalty. Even for
this group, we find that a sizeable fraction (20 percent to 60 percent
in the seven firms we study) fail to fully exploit the employer match,
either by not participating in the savings plan or by contributing less
than the match threshold. We conclude that employer matching is less
effective at increasing savings plan participation than other
institutional approaches, such as automatic enrollment or requiring an
active decision.
An employer match has its most significant effect on the
distribution of contribution rates rather than on participation. Savings
plan contribution rates are heavily influenced by the employer-chosen
match threshold. (9) For example, in one firm that increased its match
threshold from 5-6 percent of pay to 7-8 percent of pay, the fraction of
new participants choosing to save 7-8 percent increased from 8 to 33
percent of participants, whereas the fraction of new participants
choosing to save 5-6 percent of pay decreased from 43 to 19 percent.
Information Provision and Savings Outcomes
Information provision and education also can be useful in
influencing individual behavior, and the savings domain is no exception.
In a series of papers with different collaborators, I examine the impact
of information on savings and investment outcomes. These papers find
that information provision alone is often not very effective, and that
sometimes individuals can respond to information in perverse ways.
In an analysis with Choi, Laibson, and Andrew Metrick of an
employer-sponsored financial education initiative, we find that compared
to non-attendees, employees who attend financial education seminars are
more likely to sign up for their employer's savings plan, to
increase their contribution rate, and to make changes to their asset
allocation. (10) The magnitude of these effects, however, is small, both
in an absolute sense, and compared to employees' intentions
regarding their future behavior after attending the seminars.
In another study, Choi, Laibson, and I study the impact of
information provision from the news media using a natural experiment:
the media barrage on the risk of being over-invested in employer stock
that followed the corporate accounting scandals and stock market decline
of 2000-1 (and which has become relevant once again following the more
recent market decline). (11) Three companies received particular
attention over that time period: Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing.
For example, the New York Times ran 1,364 stories on Enron during the
last quarter of 2001 and the first quarter of 2002, of which 112 ran on
the front page. We show that employer stock holdings in other
companies' savings plans fell by only a small amount as a result of
the news media. Even in Houston--Enron's headquarters--where the
Houston Chronicle ran 1,122 stories on Enron in the six months
surrounding the firm's collapse, employees at other companies did
not diversify their employer stock holdings. These results are
consistent with individual inertia (as described above), and also with a
mistaken perception on the part of individuals that their
employer's stock is less risky other equity investments.
Investment prospectuses are another source of information for
individual investors. In an investing experiment, Choi, Laibson, and I
evaluate the impact of information salience on investment outcomes. (12)
Subjects were asked to allocate a hypothetical $10,000 across four
S&P 500 index funds. Subjects were randomized across three
information conditions: prospectuses only (control), prospectus plus a
short summary of the fees charged by the mutual funds, or prospectus
plus a short statement of the returns since inception attained by the
mutual funds. The two treatment conditions reduce information gathering
costs and increase the salience of either fees or returns since
inception, because both of these variables are reported in the
prospectus. Subject payments were tied to the actual performance of the
chosen portfolio. Because payments were made by the experimenters,
services like financial advice were effectively unbundled from portfolio
returns. And, because all of the mutual funds in the choice set had the
same objective, that is to mimic the returns of the S&P 500 index,
the surest way to maximize returns was to choose the fund with the
lowest fees. We find that subjects overwhelmingly failed to minimize
index fund fees. When fees were made salient, average portfolio fees
fell, but most subjects still did not minimize fees. In contrast, when
returns since inception (an irrelevant statistic when comparing index
funds with different inception dates) were made salient, subjects chased
these returns. Overall, we find small effects from the salience
manipulations in this experiment, although we find these effects both
for information that should normatively matter, and for information that
should not.
In a related experiment, Beshears and I evaluate the effect of
providing investors with a traditional investment prospectus relative to
the simpler and shorter summary prospectus recently approved by the SEC.
(13) We find that the Summary Prospectus does not meaningfully alter
subjects' investment choices relative to the longer prospectus.
Average portfolio fees and past returns are similar regardless of the
type of prospectus participants received. We find some weak evidence,
however, that providing the Summary Prospectus makes subjects feel more
confident about their portfolio choices.
And in a very recent paper, the four of us and co-author Katherine
Milkman evaluate the effect of providing individuals with information on
their coworkers' behavior in an employer-sponsored savings plan. We
find conflicting evidence on the impact of receiving peer information.
For one sub-group of workers--non-unionized non-participants--peer
information increases the likelihood of subsequent savings plan
enrollment. But for another sub-group of workers--unionized
non-participants--we find that peer information actually reduces
subsequent enrollment. The effects of so-called social norms marketing are not as predictable as some of the previous literature has suggested.
(14)
Market Experience and Savings Outcomes
Finally, Choi, Laibson, Metrick, and I examine the impact of
previous market experience on savings outcomes. In one paper, we study
the relationship between employee allocations to employer stock and past
employer stock returns. We find that high past returns induce
participants to allocate more of their contributions to their
employer's stock. (15) In a second paper, we show that past returns
not only impact asset allocation, but also individual savings rates.
(16) High unpredictable and idiosyncratic lagged equity returns in an
individual's portfolio predict subsequent savings rate increases.
This contradicts the relationship predicted by standard economic theory,
but can be explained by extrapolative beliefs. When investors experience
high past returns, they forecast high future returns. This will lead to
increased savings if their elasticity of intertemporal substitution is
greater than one.
(1) B.C. Madrian and D. Shea, "The Power of Suggestion:
Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior, NBER Working Paper
No. 7682, May 2000, and Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2001, 116:
pp.1149-87; J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick,
"For Better or for Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings
Behavior, NBER Working Paper No. 8651, December 2001, and in
Perspectives on the Economics of Aging, D. A. Wise, ed., Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press, 2004, pp. 81-121; J. Beshears, J.J. Choi,
D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "The Importance of Default Options
for Retirement Savings Outcomes: Evidence from the United States,"
NBER Working Paper No. 12009, February 2006, and in Lessons from Pension
Reform in the Americas, S. J. Kay and T. Sinha, eds., New York, NY:
Oxford University Press, 2008, pp. 59-87.
(2) J. Beshears, J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "The
Impact of Employer Matching on Savings Plan Participation Under
Automatic Enrollment," NBER Working Paper No. 13352, August 2007,
and in Research Findings in the Economics of Aging, D. A. Wise, ed.,
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2010, pp. 311-327.
(3) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Are Empowerment and Education Enough? Underdiversification in 401(k) Plans,"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:2005, pp. 151-198; J.J. Choi,
D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Mental Accounting in Portfolio
Choice: Evidence from a Flypaper Effect," NBER Working Paper No.
13656, November 2007, and American Economic Review, 99(5), (2009), pp.
2085-95.
(4) B.C. Madrian and D. Shea, "The Power of Suggestion:
Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior", op. cit.; J.
J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick, "For Better or
for Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior", op. cit.;
J. Beshears, J. J. Choi, D. Laibson and B.C. Madrian, "The
Importance of Default Options for Retirement Savings Outcomes: Evidence
from the United States," op. cit.
(5) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Reducing the
Complexity Costs of 401(k) Participation Through Quick
Enrollment[TM]," NBER Working Paper No. 11979, January 2006, and in
Developments in the Economics of Aging, D. A. Wise, ed., Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press, 2009, pp. 57-82; J. Beshears, J. J. Choi,
D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Simplification and Saving,"
NBER Working Paper No. 12659, October 2006.
(6) G. Carroll, J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A.
Metrick "Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions: Theory and Evidence
from 401(k) Saving," NBER Working Paper No. 11074, January 2005,
and Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), (2009), pp. 1639-74.
(7) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Mental
Accounting in Portfolio Choice: Evidence from a Flypaper Effect,"
op. cit.
(8) For evidence on the impact of the employer matching and savings
plan participation in 401(k)-like savings plans, see J. J. Choi, D.
Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick, "Defined Contribution
Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Decisions, and the Path of Least
Resistance," NBER Working Paper No. 8655, December 2001, in Tax
Policy and the Economy, Vol. 16, J. M. Poterba, ed., Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2002, pp. 67-113; J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian,
"$100 Bills on the Sidewalk: Violations of No-Arbitrage in 401(k)
Accounts," NBER Working Paper No. 11554, August 2005, and
forthcoming in The Review of Economics and Statistics; and J. Beshears,
J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "The Impact of Employer
Matching on Savings Plan Participation Under Automatic Enrollment,"
NBER Working Paper No. 13352, August 2007, and in Research Findings in
the Economics of Aging, D. A. Wise, ed., Chicago, IL: University of
Chicago Press, 2010, pp. 311-327. Also, in G. Engelhardt and B.C.
Madrian, "Employee Stock Purchase Plans," NBER Working Paper
No. 10421, April 2004, and National Tax Journal, 57(2), 2004, pp.
385-406, we document very high levels of non-participation in employer
stock purchase plans, despite the fact that the financial benefits
available from participation in these plans are often nontrivial as
well.
(9) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick,
"Defined Contribution Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Decisions,
and the Path of Least Resistance," op. cit.
(10) Ibid.
(11) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Are Empowerment
and Education Enough? Underdiversification in 401(k) Plans,"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2 (2005), pp. 151-08.
(12) J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian, "Why Does the
Law of One Price Fail? An Experiment on Index Mutual Funds," NBER
Working Paper No. 12261, May 2006, and in Review of Financial Studies,
23(4), (2010), pp. 1405-32.
(13) J. Beshears, J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, and B.C. Madrian,
"How Does Simplified Disclosure Affect Individuals' Mutual
Fund Choices?" NBER Working Paper No. 14859, April 2009, and
forthcoming in Explorations in the Economics of Aging, D. A. Wise, ed.,
University of Chicago Press.
(14) J. Beshears, J. J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and K.
Milkman, "The Effect of Providing Peer Information on Retirement
Savings Outcomes."
(15) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick
"Employees' Investment Decisions About Company Stock,"
NBER Working Paper No. 10228, January 2004, and in Pension Design and
Structure, O. S. Mitchell and S. P Utkus, eds., New York, NY: Oxford
University Press, 2004, pp. 121-36.
(16) J.J. Choi, D. Laibson, B.C. Madrian, and A. Metrick,
"Reinforcement Learning and Savings Behavior," Journal of
Finance, 64(6), (2009), pp. 2515-34.
Brigitte C. Madrian *
* Madrian is a Research Associate in the NBER's Program on
Aging, co-director of the Working Group on Household Finance, and Aetna
Professor of Public Policy and Corporate Management at the Kennedy
School of Government at Harvard University. Her profile appears later in
this issue.