The competition between ports.
Popa, Catalin ; Beizadea, Haralambie ; Nistor, Filip 等
1. INTRODUCTION
In the 1970s, almost every port provided the same basic package of
services to almost every customer. The late 1980s saw the emergence of
major changes. Customers began to ask ports to provide a greater variety
of services. Providing value-added services is a powerful way for ports
to build a sustainable competitive advantage. Shippers and port
customers are becoming increasingly demanding and now they tend to look
at value-added logistics services as an integral part of their supply
chain. In the recent years, many important international shipping
companies have merged into bigger and stronger entities. These newly
emerged entities are nowadays very important players on the
transportation market and their needs have increased accordingly. As a
result, ports must attempt to satisfy these needs by offering
differentiated services. This poses a particular challenge for port
management.
2. COMPETITIVE PORTS
The degree of competition of a maritime port is exploited on two
different levels, as follows:
1. Between the seaport itself and the others seaports in
competition.
With respect to this first case, usually the seaports in
competition try to adequate their superstructure and infrastructure to
those of the others rival ports. Following this policy, every port must
to keep itself in line with the state-of-the-art of the qualitative
improvement of the other competitive ports, if it wants to stay in
competition. The shipping companies choose the ports where to make their
stopping calls. Therefore, a seaport may be excluded because of the lack
in the supply of structures and services in line with the technological
requirements of the cargo fleets, such as and adequate deep of the
water, modern terminal equipment, efficient inter-modal links, etc.
Obviously, a similar exclusion implies enormous losses for the port and
regional economy.
2. Between the seaport itself and the others industrial locations
in the hinterland.
In this second case, the location choice of the industry may be
addressed towards the maritime locations far away from the seaport
region, but that are for different reasons much more attractive from the
economic point of view for the establishment of their industrial
complexes. In this case, the incidence of the costs of transport in
order to transfer the goods from/towards the inland location is really
low. Within the sphere of the seaport competition, the most important
location choice is taken by the big line shipping companies when they
plain the stopping calls of their fleet, both at a continental and
regional level (Kreukels & Wever, 1996).
The competition is held, more and more global and involves
marketing strategies that focus more niches and types of customers with
special needs, leading to customized products of high quality, produced
and distributed at low cost components from multiple sources globally,
with reduced life cycles (Chlomoudis et al., 2002), with complex range
of variety and reduced delivery times and reliable.
Ports have a role that goes far beyond traditional short-term
objectives, operational, simple delivery of basic services to the ship
and cargo, as the interface between land and sea, and is now ideal
places to locate features that add value the load within the logistics
industry, but also in aspects of leisure and tourism (Bichou & Gray,
2004).
If a main port wants to stay in competition with the other main
ports of the continent, then it is fundamental to guarantee the
availability of free land for the operations related to the handling of
the containers, and for the activities of distribution and logistics.
This point remarks the importance of the accessibility to the economic
resources of the seaport. Competition is key ports and has been
advocated by the European Union with its various packages of measures to
improve efficiency and transparency of the ports, bringing them closer
to the market where possible, particularly in concessions with a view to
regularly lead to port scanning each terminal to the market to see if
there are other companies doing the same port service with lower costs,
lower prices and better quality, so-called competition in the market.
Ports also have to compete more aggressively for their
participation in major logistics networks, which compete reaching
distant hinterlands and diffuse (Heaver et al., 2001). On the other
hand, is now the ports of the same region are increasingly competing
with each other, there are clusters of ports with the same type of
supply and located within a region, competing with other clusters of
ports other regions and there are "ranges" of ports of the
same region, in this case, each port with different offers that may or
may not be coordinated.
The commercial success of a port could rise from a productivity
advantage in traditional cargo-handling service, from value-added
services, or from a combination of the two. The most productive ports
will be those that are equipped to handle large cargo volumes and/or
significantly reduce unit costs through efficient management. Shippers
and carriers select individual ports not only based on their cargo
handling service capabilities, but also on the benefits they are capable
of "delivering". Unless a port can deliver benefits that are
superior to those provided by its competitors in a functional aspect,
port customers are likely to select ports based merely on price. This
fact raises the question of how a port can achieve value
differentiation.
Various studies show that the most successful ports are those that
not only have a productivity advantage in cargo-handling services, but
that also offer value-added services. Even though, it continues to be a
need for ports that provide the basic, traditional cargo-handling
function, and that there are still many customers for such services.
Perhaps it is for this reason that many ports in developing countries
still concentrate on improving their productivity with regard to
traditional port functions, instead of building up value-adding
logistics services.
However, it is clear that, in the future, there will be fewer ports
that prosper only in this area. Rather, we will see the dominance of
superior service leaders that possess both a productivity advantage and
a value-added service advantage. In between traditional service ports
and superior service ports are the leading-edge service ports. These are
the ports that are on their way to becoming superior service ports. A
number of ports have responded to this trend by focusing on value-added
services as a mean of gaining a competitive edge. In this content,
value-added service refers to the process of developing relationships
with customers through the provision of a customized offer, which may
include many aspects of value-added activities.
It is very advantageous for a port to be as well a logistics
centre, since the logistics centers can attract cargo that can be
shipped through the port. There is a direct positive correlation between
cargo flows at the logistics centers and the number of ships calling at
the port. In other words, the cargo attracts the ships, and the ships
attract the cargo. The port benefits by generating increased revenue and
creating additional jobs. The port can profit not only from the
logistics centre itself, but also from the increased flow of cargo
through the port. Thus, an ideal port should provide a diverse range of
services that are highly integrated. As such, there is a need to
seriously consider the increasing importance of ports in logistics
management.
Several international studies point to the autonomy of the port as
a viable factor in improving their performance, and the higher is the
aggregation of multiple ports under a single authority, the less
appetite for competition and the greater the tendency towards monopoly,
for price increases and for "administrative fat" that
translate into costs to the economy and regions.
Autonomy implies the port closest to the object manager and managed
economy, the port, which leads to greater attention and commitment and
increased competitiveness, implying greater efficiency to compete or at
least reduced costs for the customer.
Other studies indicate that competition between ports and between
terminals as key to port efficiency and price more suitable for
customers. Some authors suggest that the importance of duplication of
infrastructure in the short term to increase competition and efficiency
in order to keep prices down to the final customer.
The competition can lead to increased efficiency but also can lead
to excessive investment ability of the port infrastructure, because many
ports can invest the same kind of competing infrastructure. However, the
excess capacity of ports is essential to ensure competition between
ports, improving performance from the perspective of the customer.
Herrera and Pang (2008) state that although it is important to
maximize the output over the input, in terms of ports, it appears that
when the occupancy rate of infrastructure the port exceeds certain
levels, increase the costs of the delays to ships and cargoes.
Already a situation that encourages competition in the event of
saturation, the port authorities are obliged to increase the supply in
advance to ensure service quality and maintain / increase their market
shares, thus limiting the levels of efficiency of resources used, which,
although it could be negative for the ports as a whole, from the
standpoint of the economy in general is very positive because it reduces
the inefficiencies that would result in the transport system and its
clients. Public investment in new infrastructure (governments can do
during crisis), should take into account the existing expertise at each
port and its competitive advantages and disadvantages, and national
policy, which can lead to, for example, encourage the transfer of
certain charges between ports on grounds of national interest, regional
or local.
3. CONCLUSION
Ports should try to have efficiency levels on high when compared
with other ports, and minimize costs and maximize the quality of their
services and should have the services that the region needs, and that
its industries and importers are willing to pay the best price. No ports
competitive, the regions are not competitive and not be able to compete
with other regions to have higher GDP and higher levels of life.
Competition between ports led to specialization of port terminals and
sometimes extreme adaptation to the requirements of modern logistics
chains (Chlomoudis et al., 2002) and maritime transport, implying strong
changes in port operations day-to-day with imposing increasing pace,
intensive training, collaboration with customers, focus on quality and
introduction of private ports, through the mechanism of concessions for
the port terminals and dedicated public service and provide new
value-added services in ports.
In conclusion, impacts of port competition are:
> increasing vessel sizes;
> specialization of vessels and use of unit loads;
> vertical integration within intermodal chains;
> hub & spoke; transshipment activities;
> economic and managerial integration of logistics chain, driven
by capital flows;
> in- & outsourcing of logistic activities;
> growing public concern about the sustainability of port
activities.
4. REFERENCES
Bichou, K.; Gray, R., (2004), A Logistics and Supply Chain
Management Approach to Port Performance Measurement, Maritime Policy and
Management, Vol. 31, No 1 (2004), pp.47-67, ISSN 0308-8839.
Chlomoudis, C.I.; Karalis, V.A. & Pallis, A.A. (2003), Port
Reorganisation and the Worlds of Production Theory, European Journal of
Transport and Infrastructure Research, Vol. 3, No 1 (2003), pp. 77-94,
ISSN 1567-7141.
Heaver, T.; Meersman, H. & Van de Voorde E.(2001), Cooperation
and Competition in International Container Transport: Strategies for
Ports, Maritime Policy and Management, Vol. 25, No 3 (2001), pp.
293-306, ISSN 0308-8839.
Herrera, S.; Pang, G. (2008), Eficiency of Infrastructure: The Case
of Container Ports, Economia ANPEC (Brazilian Association of Graduate
Programs in Economics), vol. 9, No 1 (2008), pp. 165-194.
Kreukels A.M.J.; Wever, E. (1996) Dealing with Competition: the
Port of Rotterdam, TESG--Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale
Geografie, Vol. 87, No 4 (1996), pp. 293-309, ISSN 1467-9663