How useful is the golden triangle law in economics?
Skare, Marinko
Introduction
Consistent and equilibrium dynamics between unemployment, prices
and output in turn determines the state of the economy path or in A. W.
Phillips' (1962) words "the course of economic affairs".
Our perspective is in the tradition of Phillips' view on
quantitative relations between employment, inflation and growth.
"Consideration of the average level of employment brings us to
the question of the relations between employment, or unemployment, and
inflation and the rate of growth".
Large body of literature on unemployment, inflation and growth
phenomena is present in economic discipline. That is strong evidence on
why it is important to study the nature of these phenomena in economics.
Studies researching phenomena in question were mainly looking for a
bivariate relationship between the phenomena losing sight on a possible
simultaneous relationship among all three phenomena in question. The
same point was put forward by Phillips (1962) in his article. Having
this in mind, this paper addresses exactly the issue of possible long
run relationship existing between inflation, unemployment and output.
For this purpose, UK economy was selected because of historical long
time series availability. Study results presented in this paper show
that better forecasting of macroeconomic indicators can be obtained if
micro and macroeconomic indicators are grouped under three main economic
forces--inflation, unemployment and output. Equilibrium relationship
between these three economic forces determine past and future economy
path. Policy makers not having knowledge on the equilibrium relationship
between them cannot achieve steady state (internal equilibrium) in the
economy. Design of efficient policy measure is virtually impossible
since policy makers do not know what relationship holds between economic
policy targets--prices, employment and output. Since close relationship
between the targets of planned policy actions is unknown, it is not
realistic that instruments of the same policy (inflation, unemployment
and growth) will have positive effect on the economy. Quite contrary,
results presented in this paper show policy makers would cause less
damage to the economy when not interfering in the economy rather than
using vague economic policies designed in the absence of information on
quantitative relationships between the objectives of economic policy.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 1 shows the
importance of the subject under investigation. Body of literature
presenting evidence on the importance of the topic researched in this
study is presented in the Section 2. Data and methodological framework
is set up in the Section 3. Empirical results validating the hypothesis
of inefficient policy actions in the presence of vague knowledge on
relationship that holds between inflation, unemployment and output are
shown in Section 4. The final section offers concluding remarks and
research implications for policy practitioners and the field of
economics.
1. Related literature
A vast number of studies have been carried out studying the
relationship between unemployment and gross domestic product,
unemployment and inflation (1) (Philips' curve). Arthur M. Okun
(1981) examines the nature of the relationship between inflation,
unemployment and output stressing policymakers are faced with the
inflation-unemployment tradeoff issue followed by the output-money
nature of monetary phenomena. Macroeconomic measurements and forecasts
have a large influence on the economy but lack in efficiency, accuracy
and bias whenever economic shocks are present (Bratu 2012).
Macroeconomic variables in turn affect financial markets leading to a
domino effect by transferring risks and uncertainty between the two
(Hsing 2011). Quantitative relations but also the effects of lag appears
to be largely important both for fiscal and monetary policy (Jovanovski,
Muric 2011). Fiscal sustainability although important for small open
economies (Stubelj, Dolenc 2010) is subject to the law of the golden
triangle. Kaldor (1992) noticed: "Policymakers are confronted with
a trade-off between inflation and unemployment characterized by a
traditional Philips curve. Price stability requires lower output, and
high levels of output and employment entail inflation. Society can
achieve more output if, but only if, it is prepared to accept a higher
rate of inflation. By their influence on the level and growth of nominal
income, the fiscal-monetary authorities determine the inflation rate. In
that sense, inflation is always a monetary (or, more accurately, a
monetary-fiscal) phenomenon. The growth of nominal income also
determines the output of customer goods, and so output and employment
are equally monetary phenomena".
The trade-off issue was exposed by James Tobin (1996): "The
output/price or unemployment/inflation trade-off is inexorable, that is
to say, it can't be eliminated or mitigated by altering the
fiscal/monetary policy mix. Another way to put the point is this: A
certain volume of aggregate demand will place the economy at a certain
point on the aggregate supply (AS) curve relating output to price level
or on the short-run Phillips curve relating unemployment to
inflation".
Kaldor (1992) observed unemployment as labour productivity related
issue associated to the unemployment-output relationship linked to the
price level through the wage levels: "When unemployment is general
it must be the result of either a reduction in the marginal productivity
of labour relatively to other factors or an increase in the cost of
labour; and whatever the cause, the remedy will always involve either an
increase in marginal productivity or reduction in labour cost".
Phillips theory was strongly criticized by Phelps (1967) and
Friedman (1968) disputing observed unemployment-inflation empirical
relation and inferred connotations for policy makers and monetary policy
regulators.
There is wide agreement about the major goals of economic policy:
high employment, stable prices (Hooker 2002; Nakon, Pescatori 2010) and
rapid growth (Thirlwall, Norman 1970). There is less agreement that
these goals are mutually compatible, or, among those who regard them as
incompatible, about the terms at which they can and should be
substituted for one another. There is least agreement about the role
that various instruments of policy can and should play in achieving the
several goals.
Song et al. (2012) show the importance of economic growth
convergence theory for large economies as China.
2. Data and methodology
Long-term relationship between inflation, unemployment and output
in United Kingdom over the period 1851-2011 is examined in this study.
Long time series data lacking in robust data on unemployment for such a
long time period limited the analysis. Time series data for unemployment
were derived following Boyer and Hatton (2001), Reno (2010) as well as
data from (Mitchell 1988), Hicks and Grahame (1999). Time series data on
output and price level were obtained from Measuring Worth (2012)
database.
Because of the observable stationarity in the data (after proven
implementing unit root and cointegration tests) we use standard VAR and
SVAR approach to examine potential long run link between prices,
unemployment and growth in the United Kingdom. Following analysis
results, long run equilibrium path between prices, unemployment and
output was investigated. We estimate the UK potential output with the
standard Hodrick-Prescott filter (1997) model. With the data collected,
long term equilibrium model for inflation, unemployment and output for
United Kingdom was set.
A. Equilibrium assumptions
Following procedure from (Skare 2010) optimal GDP, inflation and
unemployment rates for the United Kingdom were obtained.
With the three golden nodes for the UK economy identified, a golden
triangle model can be fully set and developed approach used in devising
and implementing appropriate economic policy. To calculate the output
gap series over the sample period standard HP filter was used:
[T.summation over (i=1)][([y.sub.t] - [s.sub.t]).sup.2] +
[lambda][T-1.summation over (t=2)][(([s.sub.t+1] - [s.sub.t]) -
([s.sub.t] - [s.sub.t-1])).sup.2]. (1)
B. Inflation, unemployment, output in the United Kingdom
(1851-2011): a VAR model
In this section we examine the dynamic effects between inflation,
unemployment and output in a VAR framework. To identify long run
relationship between unemployment, inflation and output in UK we use a
stationary, stable VAR(3) process of the form:
[y.sub.t] = v + [A.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] + ... + [A.sub.p][y.sub.t-p] +
[BD.sub.t] + [u.sub.t]. (2)
In order to test whether inflation, unemployment and output are j
ointly determined (and their behaviour) we use a VAR system with three
variables or a three dimensional VAR(p):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (3)
where: Inflat (Inf) = inflation rates in the United Kingdom
1851-2011; Unem (Unm) = unemployment rates in the United Kingdom
1851-2011; Output (Out) = output growth rates in the United Kingdom
1851-2011.
To check the stability of the process in (2) we use:
[[alpha].sup.n] - [a.sub.1][[alpha].sup.n-1] -
[a.sub.2][[alpha].sup.n-2] ... [a.sub.n] = 0
[n.summation over (i=1)] [absolute value of [a.sub.i]] < 1 (4)
and
det([I.sub.K] - [A.sub.1]z - ... [A.sub.p][z.sup.p]) [not equal to]
0
for [absolute value of z] [less than or equal to] 1.
The roots of the polynomial are > 1 in absolute values([absolute
value of z] = 1.0262/1.2662/1.7801/1.7801/
1.8200/1.8200/2.1537/2.1537/3.1464). To confirm the stationarity of the
data and the stability of the VAR model standard unit roots
(Dickey-Fuller, Phillips-Perron, GLS-detrended Dickey-Fuller,
Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin, Elliott, Rothenberg, and Stock
Point Optimal and Ng and Perron) tests were performed. All tests show
stationarity of the data in levels and strong rejections of the unit
root presence in the series. Additional tests based on the group series
rather than individual series, i.e. panel data unit roots test (Levin et
al. 2002; Breitung 2000; Im et al. 2003), Fisher-type tests using ADF
and PP tests (Maddala, Wu 1999; Choi 2001; Hadri 2000) also confirms the
stability (stationarity) of the VAR process.
C. Lag selection criteria (VAR(p) Order)
Before we continue with the VAR modelling and before testing for
the causality relations between inflation, unemployment and output we
proceed with the VAR(p) order, i.e. optimal lag length selection.
Following Akaike (1969, 1971) VAR order selection criteria's and
procedures (Lutkepohl 2007) we estimate appropriate lag length as in:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (6)
HC and HQ support VAR(1) order, suggesting one lag length, FPE, AIC
and LR supports the VAR(3) order with p = 3. Starting from the
theoretical and also logical assumption that with a one lag length
rigidity in the data (especially for unemployment and inflation should
be expected) we choose the VAR(3) order for our VAR model as suggested
from the tests results. Using VAR lag exclusion Wald test we check lag
length for the model once more since appropriate lag length selection is
crucial for our VAR model. Lag exclusion Wald test support the results
of the selection criteria above (joint lags for the VAR model is 3)
suggesting no exclusion in the second and third lag in the VAR model.
Following Ho and Sorensen (1996) recommendation on the criteria to use
we decide to go with VAR(3) model. The VAR order chosen was also
scrutinized by the Granger causality relation with causality link
strongly depending on the lag length pointing to the weak causality
between inflation and unemployment in the first lag (as theoretically
expected) contrary to the much stronger causality in the third lag.
Post-estimation VAR order test also validated the lag length of (3) that
we choose for the VAR model.
D. Testing for causality
We use pairwise Granger causality test to find out the nature of
causality between inflation, unemployment and output in the United
Kingdom for the period 1851-2011. Condition of
Granger causality is defined as (Vercelli 2005):
(...)[Y.sub.n] is a cause of [X.sub.n+1] if
F([X.sub.n+1]/[[OMEGA].sub.n]) [not equal to]
F([X.sub.n+1]/[[OMEGA].sub.n] - [Y.sub.n]). (7)
In other words, the stochastic variable [Y.sub.n] Granger-causes
the stochastic variable [X.sub.n+1] when the past and present values of
[Y.sub.n] have "some unique information about what value
[X.sub.n+1] will take in the immediate future" (Granger, Joyeux
1980).
Bierens (2007) Granger causality condition form as: (...) Yt does
not Granger-cause [x.sub.t] if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (8)
If [y.sub.t] Granger-causes [x.sub.t] then one can predict
[x.sub.t] better using the whole past of the [x.sub.t] and [y.sub.t]
processes then using only the past of [x.sub.t]:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (9)
Pairwise Granger causality test (Block Exogenity Wald Test) results
infer a one way causality between output and inflation (inflation does
not Granger-cause output). Bidirectional (bilateral) causality between
inflation and unemployment show strong evidence in favour of the
Phillips curve hypothesis. For inflation and unemployment causality runs
from inflation to unemployment and unemployment to inflation (both
hypotheses are strongly accepted at 5% significance level). Hypothesis
that change in unemployment influence (Granger cause) output growth
dynamics is accepted both with the hypothesis that output growth Granger
cause changes in unemployment (two-way causality between output growth
and unemployment). Results presented in the table for the Granger
causality test for the series provide solid evidence of Granger
causality running (one-way between inflation and output), bilateral
causality between inflation/unemployment and two-way causality between
output/ unemployment in the United Kingdom during the sample period.
To check the causality between output, inflation and unemployment
we use the standard F-test for the parameter restrictions and a Wald
test for Granger causality (Table 1); causality of inflation for output:
[H.sub.0]: [[alpha].sub.12,i] = 0, i = 1, ..., p, (10)
causality of unemployment for output:
[H.sub.0]: [[alpha].sub.13,i] = 0, i = 1, ..., p. (11)
Following (9) and (10) we set up a model to test for Granger
causality of the form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (12)
We also test for the instantaneous causality between output,
inflation and unemployment following the null:
[H.sub.0]: E([u.sub.1,t][[u'.sub.2t]) = 0. (13)
The null hypothesis of no instantaneous causality between
unemployment/output ([y.sub.2], [y.sub.3]) to inflation ([y.sub.1]):
[H.sub.0]: [[alpha].sub.12,1] = [[alpha].sub.13,1] =
[[alpha].sub.12,2] = [[alpha].sub.13,2] = [[alpha].sub.12,3] =
[[alpha].sub.13,3] = 0, (14)
is strongly rejected inferring instantaneous causality between
unemployment/output and inflation in the United Kingdom. Testing no
instantaneous causality for inflation/unemployment and output:
[H.sub.0]: [[alpha].sub.11,1] = [[alpha].sub.12,1] =
[[alpha].sub.11,2] = [[alpha].sub.12,2] = [[alpha].sub.11,3] =
[[alpha].sub.12,3] = 0, (15)
is also rejected at 1% level validating instantaneous causality
between unemployment/output and inflation. Instantaneous non-causality
between inflation/output and unemployment:
[H.sub.0]: [[alpha].sub.11,1] = [[alpha].sub.13,1] =
[[alpha].sub.11,2] = [[alpha].sub.13,2] = [[alpha].sub.11,3] =
[[alpha].sub.13,3] = 0, (16)
is also rejected at 1% level confirming instantaneous causality
relations between all variables in the VAR(3) model we set. Although
causality does not necessarily involve causality in strong sense of the
word, finding causality in both directions (bilateral causality) between
inflation, unemployment and output is encouraging for our hypothesis of
quantitative relations existence among the three economic variables in
short and long run.
E. Estimated VAR(3) diagnostics and model adequacy (robustness)
In this section we test our VAR(3) model for consistency and
robustness with standard tests applying (residual autocorrelation,
nonormality, conditional heteroskedasticity). Using aforementioned
statistical tools we check the VAR(3) model underlying the data
generation process for the time series variables of inflation,
unemployment and output.
1. Analysis of residuals
To check the model consistency we first graph standardized
residuals, residual autocorrelations and cross correlations. We can see
that properties of the residuals of the estimated VAR(3) model suggest
no normality or ARCH problem in the model. After the descriptive
analysis of the residuals we check the model for the residual
autocorrelation with the Portmanteau (Lutkepohl 2007):
[H.sub.0]:[R.sub.h] = ([R.sub.1], ..., [R.sub.h]) = 0 (17)
and Breusch (1979) - Godfrey (1978) LM test:
[H.sub.0]: [D.sub.1] = ... = [D.sub.h] = 0. (18)
Tests show that null hypothesis of no serial autocorrelation in
residuals can not be rejected validating the descriptive results above.
2. Checking nonnormality in the VAR(3) model
Nonnormality test (Cholesky, Doornik-Hansen, Urzua, Jarque-Bera)
results of the VAR(3) model show no incidence of nonnormal residuals in
the model (checking the normality of the white noise process). Results
of the nonnormality tests proves that our stationary, stable VAR(3)
process is normally distributed.
3. ARCH-LM test for conditional heteroscedasticity
Fitting a multivariate ARCH(q) model to the estimation of the
residuals from the VAR(3) model we test the null of no conditional
heteroscedasticity in the residuals:
[H.sub.0]:[[beta].sub.1] = ... = [[beta].sub.q] = 0 no conditional
heteroscedasticity
[H.sub.1]:[[beta].sub.1] [not equal to] 0 or [[beta].sub.1] [not
equal to] 0, .... (19)
Results of the ARCH-LM test show that the null is not rejected and
there are no ARCH effects in the residuals.
4. Stability analysis of the VAR model
Estimated VAR(3) parameter constancy over the sample period and
inferred stability of the estimated model is checked with CHOW and CUSUM
tests, eigenvalues position over the unit circle recursive estimates and
recursive residuals plotted.
Recursive estimates do not indicate parameter instability in the
estimated VAR(3) model. All parameter estimates lies in the 95%
confidence interval. Stability is also proven the by recursive residuals
plot. All residuals lie within the 95% confidence interval indicating no
instability. The CUSUM test for corresponding VAR(3) model shows that
parameters estimates in the estimated VAR(3) model are stable
(statistical results fall within 1% significance band) suggesting that
the parameters estimates in the model are robust. Chow test for
structural change or a break point in the model (break-point and
forecast tests) indicate no structural break or parameters structural
change in the model not rejecting the null of parameters constancy over
the full sample period.
F. SVAR model for output, inflation and unemployment
To best analyse the dynamic properties of the estimated VAR(3)
model we use a SVAR model of the form (Lutkepohl 2007):
A[y.sub.t] = [A.sup.*.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] + ... +
[A.sup.*.sub.p][y.sub.t-p] + [B.sup.*.sub.0][x.sub.t-q] + [C.sup.*]
[D.sub.t] + B[[epsilon].sub.t], (20)
with:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (21)
3. Empirical results
Results obtained from VAR(3) model estimation show presence of a
long-term relationship between unemployment, inflation and output in the
United Kingdom. Table 1 summarizes the Granger-causality results for our
three-variable VAR and variance decomposition from the recursive VAR
ordered (Stock, Watson 2001) as Inflation [right arrow] Unemployment
[right arrow] Output. Granger-Causality results with p-values from the
F-statistics test reveal that inflation account for predicting
unemployment, i.e. Granger-cause unemployment at 5% significance level
while unemployment help to predict inflation at 10% significance level
(p-value 0.07). Inflation predictive values over output are at 1%
significance level (p-value 0.00) with movement in unemployment causing
movement to output (p-value 0.18) indicating Granger-noncausality
between unemployment and output. Joint significance of unemployment and
output shows that both variables are important for predicting future
values of inflation (p-value 0.00).
We can check that for all three equations joint significance of
unemployment/output [right arrow] inflation, inflation/output [right
arrow] unemployment and inflation/unemployment [right arrow] output are
have important predictive powers and 1% significance level proving the
hypothesis of the overall Granger-causality between the three variables.
Results of the test for instantaneous causality for
inflation/unemployment/output undoubtedly show (at 1% significance
level) the presence of instantaneous causality rejecting the null of no
instantaneous causality. Empirical evidence based on instantaneous
causality is as expected from the economic theory (short-run
interrelation between inflation/unemployment/output). Evidence on
Granger-causality for such long-term causality between the variables as
the sample period in our model encourages the golden triangle hypothesis
with strong statistical significance power. Rarely is expected to find
such strong statistical significance for Granger-causality over a long
sample period due to stochastic and deterministic noise in the data
process. Significant Granger-causality found and validated in our
analysis strongly supports the thesis of the existence of quantitative
and long lasting relationship between inflation/unemployment/output in
the United Kingdom.
Forecast error decomposition results in Table 1 on the other hand
provide limited evidence on the quantitative relationship for
inflation/unemployment/output. However, this is not a surprise since the
estimated impulse response analysis is a chain causality model inferring
importance of chosen variable order (timing) for the analysis. For
example, if we run an impulse response analysis for the variable order
Unemployment--Inflation--Output we get far more considerable interaction
between the variables with less standard error and forecast error of the
variables as result of the shock in recursive VAR(3) from 20-40%.
Problem of variable ordering (timing) for the structural analysis and
quantitative relationship we explore in the model we intend to resolve
by running a SVAR model for inflation/unemployment/output.
Estimated VAR(3) model is presented below with t-statistics in
parenthesis (for details see Skare 2012):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (22)
where: [Inflation.sub.t], [Unemploymen.sub.t], [Output.sub.t] =
vector of (k = 3) observable endogenous variables with three lags;
[A.sub.i], [B.sub.j] = parameter (coefficient) matrices of (KxK)
dimension and inferred dimension in the case of deterministic vector;
[D.sub.t] = deterministic variables vector; [crisis1.sub.(t)] = shift
dummy for the 1919-1921 depression; [crisis2.sub.(t)] = shift dummy for
the 1930-1931 depression; [crisis3.sub.(t)] = shift dummy for the
1973-1975 oil crises; [crisis4.sub.(t)] = shift dummy for the 1980-1982
recession; [crisis5.sub.(t)] = shift dummy for the 1990-1992 recession;
[crisis6.sub.(t)] =impulse dummy for the 2008/09 crisis; [war1.sub.(t)]
= shift dummy for the WWI; [war2.sub.(t)] = shift dummy for the WWII;
[war3.sub.(t)] = shift dummy for the Golf war; [wcycle.sub.(t)] = wage
cycle 1851-2011; [rcycle.sub.(t)] = exchange rate (US$/[pounds
sterling]) cycle 1851-2011.
To compensate for a large stochastic trend in stationary data we
identified a large vector of deterministic variable to smooth the
stochastic noise to the data generation process. Normality test point
this was a right approach since normality conditions were largely
satisfied except for the Jarque-Berra test and the problem with
Kurtosis. Visual inspection of the residuals together with other
normality test and practice that normality assumption of
[[epsilon].sub.t] in empirical VAR modelling is difficult to satisfy
since we must account for a large number of shocks to the data
generation process especially for a large time sample as the one we
used. Following Juselius (2009) we conclude that estimates of our VAR(3)
model a robust to the deviations from normality assumption particularly
taking into account that with compensate the deviations to the data
generation process with 11 deterministic variables to cover as much as
possible extraordinary shocks occurring in the data. We check the
normality assumption also by running the VAR(3) model with lags = 30 as
suggested by the post-estimation lag order selection (LR). When a lag 20
< L > 30 kurtosis problem in the process was completely removed
proving that problem with Jarque-Bera test for normality assumptions of
the residual is owed to the stochastic nature of a large data sample and
not the problem with VAR estimates robustness.
Estimates of the VAR(3) model give us a rich insight (especially
when we estimate the VAR(30) model) to the long term relationship for
inflation/unemployment/output in the United Kingdom during 1851-2011.
Negative long-term relationship between inflation and unemployment
(Phillips curve) is validated since a statistically significant negative
coefficient account for long run relation between the two. From the
estimates you can see that the [Inflation.sub.t] =
-0.452([Unemployment.sub.(t-1]) indicating that a 1% increase in
unemployment was followed by a -0.452 percentage change drop in
inflation (Phillips curve). In the second lag, and this is a very
interesting fact, a trade-off between inflation and unemployment dies
out resulting in positive relationship during the second year shift in
the data. Now a 1% increase in the unemployment is followed by a 0.838
percentage points increase in the inflation rate. In the third year,
once again the trade-off is re-established with a 1% increase in
unemployment leading to a fall in the rate of inflation of -0.419
percentage points (statistically significant a 5%). Running the VAR(30)
model we could observe a clear trade-off pattern between inflation and
unemployment in the United Kingdom. Indeed there is a trade-off between
inflation and unemployment and Phillips hypothesis is true (with the
help of the golden triangle theory), at least when it comes to the
economy of the United Kingdom. Negative empirical relationship between
unemployment and inflation is validated. Short-term impact multiplier of
-0.452 indicate that an increase in unemployment of 1% will result in
inflation fall of -0.452 percentage point (short-run elasticity of
inflation is about -0.452 percent). Long-term impact multiplier (sum of
all short-run multipliers) equals -0.282 pointing to the straightforward
conclusion--a long-term quantitative relation between
inflation/unemployment exists and it is a trade-off relation in Philips
tradition (1958). Figure 1 display the short and long-run impact
multipliers and trade-off between inflation/unemployment/output for a
thirty year lag VAR model.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A clear trade-off pattern and a valid proof for the Phillips
hypothesis is visible from the up and down curve displaying a percentage
change in inflation due to a 1% increase in unemployment over the thirty
year lag period. In the first year, there is a negative (unit elastic)
response of inflation to a 1% increase in unemployment (Phillips
relation). In the second lag (second year) inflation response to a 1%
increase in unemployment is positive and around 2.5%. This is expected
and in agreement with the theory since after the fall in inflation in
the first year of 1% unemployment is adjusting to it (see bottom left
chart on Figure 1) and so is the output. The third lag is once again in
trade-off tradition with an estimated fall in inflation of 2% since the
unemployment adjustment in the second year (together with output
adjustment) and so on for the forward lags. Results also shade light on
the puzzled Phillips curve (high unemployment and high inflation)
experienced after the WWII in the United Kingdom and in 1970s all over
the world. The explanation is straightforward from the estimated
results. Answer lies in the wage -> output (productivity) [right
arrow] unemployment relationship and the golden triangle theory. Top
right chart on the Figure 1 clearly display the difference between the
short and long run Phillips curve. The trade-off adjusting between
inflation and unemployment is going on for over the decade. After 10-12
years of adjustment, Phillips curve takes a short rest (you can see on
the figure that impact multipliers shortly die out around 12 years).
After that, a new shock, disturbance in the system set the
inflation/unemployment/output adjustment mechanism on once again. In
Figure 2 we offer the explanation for the unstable Phillips curve in UK
for 1945-1977. As claimed by the estimated SVAR model an inflation shock
increases unemployment immediately, decrease output in the first year
followed by a rise in output after the second year and remaining
constant over the year after. Phillips curve adjustment over
inflation/unemployment is continuing until the fourth year after which
adjustments and inflation/unemployment trade-off continues in the long
run but with low intensity. Inflation shock cause a rise in the price
level promptly (in the first year) but after the second year inflation
shock impact on the general price level is gradually slowing down. Shock
in the unemployment has a negative immediate response in inflation with
inflation adjusting to the shock in unemployment with a large negative
drop (inflation falls consistently). As in the case of the inflation
shock, trade-off between unemployment/ inflation is consistent and
significant until the fourth year with the trade-off slowly dying out in
the long run.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The results prove our hypothesis the Phillips curve is not vertical
in the long run but oscillating (on small scale) about the natural
unemployment rate (or in the golden triangle terminology about the
golden unemployment node). Unemployment shock points to the existence of
the hysteresis in unemployment (Song 1998). Changes in the actual rate
of unemployment have a strong impact on the natural unemployment rate
over the period of 30 years with the natural rate falling when actual
rate is below natural and contrary. Shock in the unemployment causes
immediate response in output adjusting to the new golden equilibrium. In
theory, negative effects of shock in unemployment are expected on
output. This is true if we look for a unidirectional link between
unemployment and output. Such a unidirectional relation does not exist
under the golden triangle assumptions. Final effect of the shock in
unemployment is dependent on the simultaneous changes going on between
inflation/unemployment/output. Economy is adjusting to the shocks
through the changes in the golden triangle nodes and if it is
successful, i.e. policy makers set up measure appropriate to the moment,
beginning shock in unemployment could result in output increase over
time if policy makers and golden triangle model are in synchrony. If
this is not the case, when policy makers ignores the quantitative
relationship that exists between inflation/unemployment/output they will
certainly act upon economy with inappropriate and wrong set of
instruments and policies worsening the situation in the economy. This is
in fact what happened in the United Kingdom during 1945-1977. Policy
makers completely ignored the quantitative relations that exists (and
that we proved here) between inflation/unemployment/ output (and still
do ignore) that a demand/supply shocks, together with oil shock at the
time could not be constrained by the Phillips curve mechanism alone
resulting in unstable Phillips curve for the time. There is nothing
wrong with the Phillips curve at the time but all is wrong with the
macroeconomic policy implemented and that is what triggered the chain of
events in the United Kingdom causing unstable Phillips curve appearance.
The productivity/wage gap worsened the situation at the time encouraging
unstable Phillips curve appearance. When the productivity/wage gap
diminished (around 1980) Phillips curve returned to its more traditional
form although with not so strong negative relationship between
inflation/unemployment as before the WWII. Further adjustments in the
golden triangle model are needed to return to the traditional Phillips
curve form at present. Supply shock on the price level is evident and
long lasting (twelve year cycle). Shock in the production (output)
levels drives production level up with shock effects after a two year
cycle sharply falling to zero. Shock in the production level register
positive temporary effect on future output level. Output growth is
followed by immediate drop in the unemployment rate corrected with
prompt increase in the price level (Phillips' curve theory). To
asses relative importance of individual shock in inflation/unemployment/
output we measure the forecast error variance decomposition (Fig. 3).
Shocks in the price level are dominant source for Inflation in the
United Kingdom with unemployment and output shocks explaining about 30%
of the variance in inflation. Variance in unemployment however is
significantly jointly explained by shocks in output and inflation (about
40% of the variance in unemployment) with 60% variance in unemployment
explained by the shocks in the unemployment. Output growth is important
source factor and determinant for the output growth in the long run
(about 70%). Considerable joint significance of unemployment and
inflation in output variance in the long run is about 30% suggesting
important interaction level between the variables.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Conclusions and future research
Study results point to several important conclusions. First one is
related to the traditional Phillips curve theory. Validated results in
the paper prove the existence of the Phillips curve in the United
Kingdom for the period 1851-2011. Estimated long term impact multiplier
(long run inflation elasticity) for inflation/unemployment is negative
with a value of -0.282 vindicating the negative empirical relationship
between inflation and unemployment in the United Kingdom 1851-2011.
Phillips curve does exist (at least for the UK economy). Second
important conclusion inferred from the golden triangle theory concerns
the natural rate of unemployment theory. Economies do tend toward a
specific unemployment rate but this rate isn't to be considered
natural or fixed over time. It is just one of three nodes of the golden
triangle model ensuring country's internal macroeconomic
equilibrium at certain point in time. This golden node or to say
equilibrium unemployment rate is a dynamic phenomenon, constantly
changing over time so can't be fixed to 5 or 6% as the theory of
natural unemployment rate suggests. Third conclusion to which the
results point to is that Phillips curve is not vertical in the long run
because actual rate do not equal the theoretical natural unemployment
rate. Results infer that the natural unemployment rate (our golden node)
is constantly changing over time there cannot be a vertical Phillips
curve in the long run. Estimates of the impact multipliers substantiate
this conclusion since inflation/unemployment adjustment (trade-off) is
going on over the period of 30 lags, multipliers not dies out as the
theory of natural unemployment rate demand. Inflation/unemployment long
term impact multipliers in Figure 2 validate this statement. Change in
the unemployment rate affects the inflation rate continuously. Also
cyclicality in the impact multipliers trend can be noticed. After 12
years, unemployment impact on inflation slowly settles down (the same
pattern repeats after second twelve years period at lag = 24) but never
dies out. Trade-off adjustment between inflation/unemployment in the UK
economy is ever lasting and implies no vertical Phillips curve in the
long run.
Fourth conclusion we empirically asses is that there is hysteresis
in unemployment. Impact multiplier for unemployment/unemployment (long
run elasticity for unemployment) with value 0.8279 so natural rate
unemployment dynamics is significantly affected by the change in the
actual rate of unemployment. It is the dynamics of the actual
unemployment rate that alters the natural unemployment rate within the
golden triangle model framework (together with output and inflation
dynamics).
Fifth conclusion is partially based on the Friedman-Phelps theory.
Long run impact multipliers for inflation/output (0.93) and
unemployment/output (0.21), i.e. long run elasticity coefficients show
that Phillips curve is in fact sensitive to the supply and wage shocks.
Simultaneous shocks to expected inflation supported by wage shocks and
changes in the golden triangle nodes that actual shifts the Phillips
curve. It is the simultaneous relationship between
inflation/unemployment/output that guides the shifts in the Phillips
curve. Exploring why a Phillips curve during 1945-1977 exhibits no
systematic relationship in Phillips tradition is our sixth conclusion.
Instability in the Phillips curve in the United Kingdom after WWII was
caused by the disequilibrium in the golden triangle. Particularly,
adverse supply shocks had driven by the large growth in the unit wage
costs over output per worker, oil crises, demand shocks and monetary
validation that caused large, incontrollable changes to inflation and
unemployment trend. Such large shocks could not be self-corrected just
by a Phillips curve mechanism. This, however, does not imply that a
negative systematic relationship between inflation and unemployment did
not exist in the UK economy at that time. It did, but policy makers
cannot count just on the Phillips curve correction mechanism itself to
resolve large instability shocks present at that time. This brings us to
our last conclusion. Systematic quantitative relationship between
inflation/unemployment/output exists for the UK economy as supposed by
Phillips. Our results prove that the golden triangle model exists for
the UK economy validating as such systematic quantitative relationship
for inflation/unemployment/ output. Policy makers cannot guarantee just
by using the Phillips curve mechanism to maintain targeted levels of
inflation or unemployment. Golden triangle model offers to policy makers
a set of choices to choose from when targeting main macroeconomic goals.
Failure to do so and not account for quantitative and systematic
relationship that exists between inflation/ unemployment/output in the
UK economy results in improper policy measures or inappropriate in
magnitude and timing as was the case in the United Kingdom after the
WWII and later on in 70's, 80's, 90's causing large
distress to the UK economy. This is our modest attempt to the
development of the golden triangle theory and research on the
employment/ inflation/output quantitative relationship as supposed by
Phillips long time ago hoping to encourage future research on the
subject.
Caption: Fig. 1. Estimated short and long run impact multipliers
for inflation/unemployment/output (short/long run elasticity of
inflation/unemployment/output)
Caption: Fig. 2. SVAR impulse response of
inflation/unemployment/output
Caption: Fig. 3. Forecast error variance decomposition of
inflation/unemployment/output
doi:10.3846/20294913.2014.889772
References
Acemoglu, D.; Scot, A. S. 1994. Asymmetries in the cyclical
behaviour of UK labour markets, Economic Journal 104(427): 1303-1323.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2235450
Adams, C.; Coe, D. 1989. A systems approach to estimating the
natural rate of unemployment and potential output for the United States,
IMF Working Paper. 89 p.
Aguiar, A.; Martins, M. M. F. 2005. Testing the significance and
the nonlinearity of the Phillips trade-off in the Euro area, Empirical
Economics 30(3): 665-691. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00181-005-0250-z
Akaike, H. 1969. Fitting autoregressive models for prediction,
Annals of the Institute for Statistical Mathematics 21(1): 243-247.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02532251
Akaike, H. 1971. Autoregressive model fitting for control, Annals
of the Institute for Statistical Mathematics 23(2): 163-180.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4612-1694-0_12
Altig, D.; Fitzgerald, T.; Rupert, P. 1997. Okun's law
revisited: should we worry about low unemployment, Economic Commentary
15: 1-4.
Apergis, N.; Rezitis, A. 2003. An examination of Okun's law:
evidence from regional areas in Greece, Applied Economics 35(10):
1147-1151. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/0003684032000066787
Attfield, C. L. F.; Silverstone, B. 1998. Okun's law,
cointegration and gap variables, Journal of Macroeconomics 20(3):
625-637. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0164-0704(98)00076-7
Bierens, H. J. 2007. Econometric analysis of linearized singular
dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, Journal of Econometrics
136(2): 595-627. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.11.008
Bodman, P. 1998. Asymmetry and duration dependence in Australian
GDP and unemployment, The Economic Record 74(227): 399-411.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4932.1998.tb01934.x
Boyer, G. R.; Hatton, T. J. 2001. New estimates of British
unemployment, 1870-1913, Journal of Economic History 62(3): 643-675.
Bratu, M. 2012. The reduction of uncertainty in making decisions by
evaluating the macroeconomic forecasts performance in Romania, Economic
Research--Ekonomska Istraiivanja 25(2): 239-262.
Breitung, J. 2000. The local power of some unit root tests for
panel data, in Baltagi, B. (Ed.). Advances in Econometrics. Vol. 15:
Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels.
Amsterdam: JAI Press, 161-178.
Breusch, T. S. 1979. Testing for autocorrelation in dynamic linear
models, Australian Economic Papers 17(31): 334-355.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8454.1978.tb00635.x
Brunner, A. D. 1997. On the dynamic properties of asymmetric models
of real GNP, Review of Economics and Statistics 79(2): 321-326.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/003465397556674
Campbell, J. R.; Fisher, J. D. M. 2000. Aggregate employment
fluctuations with microeconomic asymmetries, American Economic Review
90(5): 1323-1345. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.5.1323
Campbell, J. Y.; Mankiw, N. G. 1987. Are output fluctuations
transitory?, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 102(4): 857-880.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1884285
Choi, I. 2001. Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of
International Money and Finance 20(2): 249-272.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0261-5606(00)00048-6
Cochrane, J. 1988. How big is the random walk in GNP?, Journal of
Political Economy 96(5): 893-920. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261569
Courtney, H. G. 1991. The Beveridge curve and Okun's law: a
re-examination of fundamental relationships in the United States: PhD
thesis. Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Cuaresma, J. C. 2003. Okun's law revisited, Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics 65(4): 439-451.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0084.t01-1-00056
Davenport, P. 1982. Technical change and unemployment, Journal of
Post Keynesian Economics 1: 34-50.
Evans, G. 1989a. Output and employment dynamics in the United
States: 1950-1985, Journal of Applied Econometrics 4(3): 213-237.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jae.3950040302
Evans, G. 1989b. A measure of the U.S. output gap, Economic Letters
29(4): 285-289. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(89)90202-4
Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy: presidential
address to AEA, American Economic Review LVIII(1): 1-17.
Godfrey, L. G. 1978. Testing against general autoregressive and
moving average error models when the regression include lagged dependent
variables, Econometrica 46(6): 1293-1302.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1913829
Gordon, R. J. 1990. The Phillips curve now and then, NBER Working
Paper No. 3393, 1-20.
Granger, C. W. J.; Joyeux, R. 1980. An introduction to long-memory
time series models and fractional differencing, Journal of Time Series
Analysis 1(1): 15-30.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9892.1980.tb00297.x
Hadri, K. 2000. Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel
data, Econometric Journal 3(2): 148-161.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1368-423X.00043
Hicks, J.; Grahame, A. 1999. A century of change: trends in UK
statistics since 1900, House of Commons Research Paper No. 99/111, 1-34.
Ho, M. S.; Sorensen, B. E. 1996. Finding cointegration rank in high
dimensional systems using the Johansen test: an illustration using data
based Monte Carlo simulations, Review of Economics and Statistics 78(4):
726-732. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2109959
Hodrick, R. J.; Prescott, E. C. 1997. Postwar U.S. business cycles:
an empirical investigation, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 29(1):
1-16. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2953682
Hooker, M. 2002. Are oil shocks inflationary? Asymetric and
nonlinear specifications versus changes in regime, Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 34(2): 540-561.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/mcb.2002.0041
Hsing, Y. 2011. Macroeconomic variables and the stock market: the
case of Croatia, Economic Rersearch Ekonomska Istraiivanja 24(4): 41-50.
Im, K. S.; Pesaran, M. H.; Shin, Y. 2003. Testing for unit roots in
heterogeneous panels, Journal of Econometrics 115(1): 53-74.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(03)00092-7
Jovanovski, T.; Muric, M. 2011. The phenomenon oflag in application
ofthe measures of monetary policy, Economic Research--Ekonomska
Istraiivanja 24(2): 10 p.
Juselius, K. 2009. The cointegrated VAR model: methodology and
applications. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 480 p.
Kaldor, N. 1992. The economics and politics of capitalism as a
dynamic system. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 402 p.
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and
money. London: Macmillan. 403 p.
Levin, A.; Lin, C. F.; Chu, C. J. 2002. Unit root tests in panel
data: asymptotic and finite-sample properties, Journal of Econometrics
108(1): 1-24. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00098-7
Lee, J. 2000. The robustness of Okun's law: evidence from OECD
countries, Journal of Macroeconomics 22(2): 331-356.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0164-0704(00)00135-X
Lorenzoni, G. 2010. A theory of demand shocks, American Economic
Review 99(5): 2050-2084. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.5.2050
Lutkepohl, H. 2007. New introduction to multiple time series
analysis. New York: Springer Verlag. 764 p.
Maddala, G. S.; Shaowen, W. 1999. A comparative study of unit root
tests with panel data and a new simple test, Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics 61(S1): 631-652.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0084.0610s1631
Measuring Worth. 2012 [online], [cited 17 June 2012]. Available
from Internet: http://www.measuringworth.com
Mitchell, B. R. 1988. British historical statistics. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press. 886 p.
Nakon, A.; Pescatori, A. 2010. Oil and the great moderation, The
Economic Journal 120(543): 131-156.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02302.x
Nickell, S. 1998. Unemployment: questions and some answers, The
Economic Journal 108(448): 802-816.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00316
Okun, A. 1980. Postwar macroeconomic performance, in Feldstein, M.
(Ed.). The American Economy in Transition. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 162-170.
Okun, A. 1981. Prices and quantities: a macroeconomic analysis.
Washington: The Brookings Institution. 367 p.
Palley, T. 1993. Okun's law and the asymmetric and changing
cyclical behaviour of the USA economy, International Review of Applied
Economics 7(2): 144-162. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/758530144
Phelps, E. S. 1967. Philips curves, expectations of inflation and
optimal unemployment over time, Economica 34(135): 254-281.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2552025
Phelps, E. S.; Zoega, G. 1998. Natural rate theory and OECD
unemplyoment, The Economic Journal 108(448): 782-801.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00315
Phillips, A. W. 1958. The relation between unemployment and the
rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957,
Economica 25(100): 283-299. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2550759
Phillips, A. W. 1962. Employment, inflation and growth, Economica
29(113): 1-16. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.1962.tb00001.x
Reno, E. 2010. Statistical yearbook of the League of Nations.
Northwestern University Library. Chicago, 1-875.
Rothman, P. 1991. Further evidence on the asymmetric behaviour of
unemployment rates over the business cycle, Journal of Macroeconomics
13(2): 291-298. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0164-0704(91)90057-2
Samuelson, P. 2008. Thoughts about the Phillips curve, FRBB
Conference Series 53, 9-11 June, 2008, Chatham, Massachusetts.
Sogner, L.; Stiassny, A. 2002. An analysis on the structural
stability of Okun's law--a cross-country study, Applied Economics
34(14): 1775-1787. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840210124180
Song, F. M. 1998. Hysteresis in unemployment: evidence from OECD
countries, Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 38(2): 181-192.
Song, M.; Wang, S.; Wang, Z. 2012. A new method for measuring the
economic convergence and its application on central China provinces,
Economic Research--Ekonomska Istraiivanja 25(4): 925-936.
Stock, H. J.; Watson, M. W. 2001. Vector autoregression, The
Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4): 101-115.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.15.4.101
Stubelj, I.; Dolenc, P. 2010. Fiscal sustainability of EU member
states in the context of current financial crisis, Economic
Research--Ekonomska Istraiivanja 23(4): 37-62.
Skare, M. 2010. Can there be a 'golden triangle' of
internal equilibrium, Journal of Policy Modeling 32(4): 562-573.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2010.05.005
Skare, M. 2012. Discovering the inflation true nature, in Hasanov,
M. (Ed.). Inflation, Deflation and Disinflation. New York: NOVA
Publisher, 1-63.
Thirlwall, A. P. 1969. Unemployment compensation as an automatic
stabiliser, Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics
& Statistics, 23-37.
Thirlwall, A.; Norman, J. I. 1970. Okun's law and the natural
rate of growth: reply, Southern Economic Journal 37(2): 232-234.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1056140
Thurow, L.; Taylor, L. 1966. The interation between the actual and
potential rates of growth, The Review of Economics and Statistics 48(4):
351-360. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1924613
Tobin, J. 1996. Essays in economics: national and international.
Vol. 4. Hong Kong: MIT Press. 807 p.
Vercelli, A. 2005. Granger causality and rational expectations: an
uneasy marriage, in Conference Proceedings, Bologna Conference on
Causality, Probability and Rationality, May, 2005, Bologna, Italy.
Viren, M. 2001. The Okun curve is non-linear, Economics Letters
70(2): 253-257. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1765(00)00370-0
Weber, C. E. 1995. Cyclical output, cyclical unemployment, and
Okun's coefficient: a new approach, Journal of Applied Econometrics
10(4): 433-445. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jae.3950100407
Received 12 October 2012; accepted 02 January 2014
Marinko SKARE
Department of Economics and Tourism "Dr. Mijo Mirkovic",
Juraj Dobrila University of Pula, Preradoviceva 1/1, 52100 Pula, Croatia
Corresponding
E-mail:
[email protected]
(1) See Phelps (1967), Gordon (1990), Phelps and Zoega (1998),
Nickell (1998), Lorenzoni (2010), Acemoglu and Scott (1994), Adams and
Coe (1989), Aguiar and Manuel (2005), Altig et al. (1997), Apergis and
Rezitis (2003), Attfield and Silverstone (1998), Bodman (1998), Brunner
(1997), Campbell and Fisher (2000), Campbell and Mankiw (1987), Cochrane
(1988), Courtney (1991), Cuaresma (2003), Davenport (1982), Evans
(1989a, b), Keynes (1936), Lee (2000), Okun (1980), Palley (1993),
Rothman (1991), Samuelson (2008), Sogner and Stiassny (2002), Thirlwall
(1969), Thurow and Taylor (1966), Viren (2001), Weber (1995).
Marinko SKARE. Professor of Economics, Editor in Chief of the
Economic Research Journal, Member of Editorial Board of several
international journals, Faculty of Economics and Tourism "Dr. Mijo
Mirkovic" in Pula, Juraj Dobrila University of Pula. He served as
Assistant Dean for Education, Faculty of Economics and Tourism, Pula;
Assistant Dean for International Cooperation, Faculty of Economics and
Tourism, Pula, Main and Team Researcher on several scientific projects;
Former Dean of the Faculty of Economics & Tourism, Pula and Former
Vice President for International Cooperation, Juraj Dobrila University
of Pula. He is a member of the American Economic Association, Royal
Economic Society, Economic History Association, Economic History
Society, and Association for Comparative Economic Studies. He has
published several books and a large number of scientific papers on the
subject of economic growth, welfare economics and poverty, human
capital, economics in transition, economic philosophy and monetary
economics.
Table 1. VAR Descriptive Statistics for (Inf, Unm, Out)
A. Granger-Causality Tests
Dependent Variables in Regression
Regressor Inf Unm Out All (Joint significance)
Inf 0.00 0.07 0.27 0.00
Unm 0.05 0.00 0.00 0.01
Out 0.01 0.18 0.00 0.00
B. Variance Decomposition from the Recursive VAR ordered as Inf
[right arrow] Unm [right arrow] Out
B.i. Variance Decomposition of Inflation
Variance
Decomposition
(percentage points)
Forecast Horizon Forecast Standard Error Inf Unm Out
1 3.33 100 0.0 0.0
5 4.52 88.0 4.0 8.0
10 4.70 87.0 5.0 8.0
15 4.77 85.0 6.0 8.0
20 4.82 84.0 8.0 8.0
B.i. Variance Decomposition of Unemployment
Variance
Decomposition
(percentage points)
Forecast Horizon Forecast Standard Error Inf Unm Out
1 1.62 11.0 89.0 0.0
5 3.01 4.0 95.0 1.0
10 3.58 3.0 95.0 2.0
15 3.93 3.0 95.0 2.0
20 4.18 3.0 94.0 3.0
B.ii. Variance Decomposition of Output
Variance
Decomposition
(percentage points)
Forecast Horizon Forecast Standard Error Inf Unm Out
1 2.13 1.0 29.0 70.0
5 2.30 2.0 32.0 66.0
10 2.43 2.0 38.0 60.0
15 2.51 2.0 41.0 56.0
20 2.58 2.0 44.0 54.0
Source: author calculation.