Whether globalization in form of FDI enhances national wealth: empirical evidence from Lithuania/Ar visada globalizacija, vykstanti tiesioginiu uzsienio investiciju forma, didina nacionalini turta: lietuvos atvejis.
Tvaronaviciene, Manuela ; Kalasinskaite, Kristina
1. Introduction
Foreign direct investment (FDI) almost unanimously is seen as
driving force of economic growth. Such belief is especially viable among
politicians of developing countries, striving to accelerate economic and
technological development, to enhance competitiveness of host economies.
Unquestioning of FDI impact, in some cases, leads to unforeseen
consequences, which not always comply with expectations. Lack of deeper
FDI phenomenon consideration triggers risk of negative cost-benefit
results of globalization for FDI recipient country. Cost in this case
embraces various tax exemptions and privileges provided by host country
to foreign origin proprietorship in local enterprises. Benefits, in
their turn, are much more implicit, and hard to estimate; as alternative
case, when the same enterprises would be run by local capital, remain a
hypothetical case.
In order to trace effects of foreign ownership on capital recipient
country, theoretical framework has to be developed. FDI does not
comprise homogeneous theory as is connected to multifaceted aspects of
interrelated fields, such as, economic growth, international economics,
international strategic management and industrial organization.
Interdisciplinary nature of FDI conditions variety approaches towards
FDI, what, in its turn, does not fit into one consistent track. Authors,
as a rule, elaborate chosen topic into different directions. Such range
of scientific interests could be understood and justified after getting
acquainted with a variety of foreign proprietorship emerging forms,
which, according to formal agreement, later is being statistically
recorded as inward (respective to host country) FDI.
2. Foreign proprietorship forms considered as foreign direct
investment
In order to discuss theoretical framework of FDI cost-benefit
analysis for host country, and answer the question, if FDI enhances
national wealth, clear understanding of FDI phenomenon, at first, is
required. Frequently foreign direct investment is understood as capital
inflows of foreign capital, i.e. coincided with financial capital, put
into host country enterprise. Alas, such perception is incomplete; it
does not embrace other legislative forms of FDI entrance, which cannot
provide additional capital in any form and still be considered as
foreign direct investment. Foreign direct investment may appear not only
through input of foreign capital, but, according to international
agreement, FDI would be recorded in a case of purchase of stake of host
country enterprise that is owned by residents of the investing country.
Foreign direct investment implies full or partial acquiring of local
enterprise, what leads to obtaining rights of considerably significant
degree of control by the investor over the management of the enterprise.
Conventionally, FDI is established when a foreign investor in local
company owns 10 percent or more of the ordinary shares or voting power.
If foreign investor owns share of authorized capital, which is lesser
than 10 percent, such investment is considered as foreign portfolio
investment (FPI). Hence, foreign investments are generally referred to
investments made by individuals or enterprises that have their center of
economic interest in an economy other than the economy in which they
invest. As it was provided above, these international acquisitions of
economic interests take two major forms: foreign direct investments and
foreign portfolio investments (Goldstein, Assaf 2006). To generalize,
there is a rather thin line between FDI and FPI. FDI embraces not only
additional inflow of financial capital, but as well appears in case of
enterprise ownership origin change. Ownership change, e.g. from local to
foreign, not necessarily has to affect activity of local company.
Despite this there is FPI, which is supposed to have other function than
control in case of stake is being acquired; FDI as well does not mean
automatic influence on management of FDI recipient company.
Interest in management usually is being expressed, when FDI takes
the following forms: greenfield, mergers and acquisitions (M&A), and
joint ventures (Raff et al. 2009). Greenfield FDI is involved in
establishing new production, distribution or other facilities in the
host country. In the context of transition economies the term
"brownfield FDI" is often used to describe situation, when a
foreign investor formally acquires a private firm (Meyer, Saul 2001) or
purchases it from government (Buckley, Casson 1998; Tvaronaviciene,
Kalasinskaite 2007). In that case, origin of capital changes from local
to foreign. Consequences of such change can have a very wide range; i.e.
from negative, to non-existent or, what is usually expected, positive to
company, industry, and, respectively welfare enhancing for a host
country (Tvaronaviciene, Grybaite 2007).
All listed above forms of FDI may be financed by different
combination of financial sources. FDI may consist of equity capital (the
foreign investor's purchases of shares in an enterprise home
country), reinvested earnings (share of earnings not distributed as
dividends by affiliates or remitted to the investor origin country, but
rather reinvested in the host country) and loans comprising of
short-term and long-term borrowings. Foreign direct investment
statistically can be recorded as FDI flows or cumulative FDI. FDI flows
represent yearly FDI and do not take into account other time periods,
when FDI occurred. Another measurement, FDI stocks, represents the value
of the share of the capital and reserves (including retained profits)
attributable to the foreign enterprise, plus the net indebtedness of
affiliates of the parent enterprise. To put it another way, FDI stocks
could be perceived as accrued inflows. For analysis purposes, usually
cumulative FDI measure, is being used, as FDI inflows, as a rule, are
uneven and too insignificant if to compare to value added generated in
industry and even more insignificant in the whole country's
context.
Despite FDI stocks there is a more relevant measure of foreign
proprietorship, in case of estimation of its effects on host country
development, distinction between FDI flows and FDI stocks retains its
importance for deeper understanding processes, which, actually, are
conditioned by FDI flows.
To generalize, diversity of activities forms, which fall under
definition of FDI and variety of ways to obtain stakes in local
companies (direct input of financial means, reinvesting of profits,
loans and buy-out) condition complicity of task to perform cost-benefit
analysis of FDI for host country. Superficially judging, host country
performs the role of foreign capital recipient. As FDI sources are
detailed, it becomes clear that foreign direct investment might not mean
any financial investment for local company. Privatization, which is
associated with transformation of state ownership to private one, in
case of FDI can lose this core essence, e.g. as evidence from Lithuania
verifies, in some cases local state capital was replaced by foreign
state capital with specially devised conditions for avoiding competition
in local market (Ginevicius, Tvaronaviciene 2004).
Studies devoted to FDI impact on development of transition
countries suggest that positive effects are quite fragile and combined
with widespread usage of tax holidays, subsidies and acquisition
discounts, leave uncertainty about relation of direct effects and
economic growth in these countries (Jensen 2006). State policies towards
FDI as a rule are costly to host countries and not necessarily efficient
(Durham, Benson 2004; Tvaronaviciene et al. 2009); therefore estimation
of benefits conditioned by globalization processes remains the main
scientific concern and issue to be tackled.
In order to construct theoretical framework letting to perform FDI
cost-benefit analysis let us briefly overview germination of FDI theory.
3. Approaches towards plausible FDI effects
At the end of the 50's FDI has been prevailingly explained
within the framework of neoclassical theories (Buckley 2006). According
to the theory capital moves from countries where the interest rate is
low to those where the interest rate is higher. The theory assumes risk
neutrality, absence of transaction costs and barriers. These assumptions
do not correspond reality, and when risk, uncertainty and barriers to
the movement of capital among nations are introduced, the theory loses
its predictive ability.
Neoclassical trade theory, which assumes that trade patterns are
determined by relative supplies of factors of production (e.g. skilled
and unskilled labour, capital and natural resources) and/or by
differences in tastes and technology, could not either explain why FDI
in various forms take place (Hosseini 2005).
Hymer analyzed multinational enterprises and FDI focusing on
strategic behaviour of firms, the structure of markets and their
interactions on the basis of industrial organization theory, which
includes a study of market imperfections. The theory was further
extended by Kindleberger, and became known as Hymer-Kindleberger
paradigm (Hosseini 2005). Adoption of complex approach towards FDI, and
taking into account factors comprising a set of capital inflows or
ownership share acquisitions in various economy sectors let to reveal
controversial effects of separate FDI cases in Lithuania (Ginevicius,
Tvaronaviciene 2004). Ability of foreign direct investors to repatriate capital and remit profits appeared to be a rather significant criterion
by tackling certain industry (Ginevicius, Tvaronaviciene 2004). Those
findings are consistent with conclusions of other authors (Leahy,
Montagna 2000; Tarzi 2005), claiming that specific market structures in
FDI receiving industries and forms of foreign capital entry condition,
finally, positive or detrimental impact of globalization on separate
economic sectors, which indirectly affects the whole local economy.
Attempts to combine firm and market structure level have been made
by Japanese scientists Kojima and Ozawa and are known as The Kojima
Hypothesis. According to authors, host country's industrial
policies complement stimuli for FDI provided by market structures in
particular industry (McClintock 1988).
In our research we adopt industrial organization approach, assuming
that market structure and form of FDI entry, which in its turn reflects
reaction to state policy, conditions positive or detrimental impact on
industry development. Another, new in FDI scientific literature,
assumption roots in decreasing-returns tendencies highlighted by the
neoclassical growth model.
Notable, that some authors (e.g. Romer 1986, 1993), oppositely,
model increasing returns of FDI through knowledge spillover, as,
according to them, "idea gaps" between developed and
developing economies exist, and those spillover effects (Borensztein et
al. 1998) tend to growth as that gap shrinks. In current years, if to
take into account globalization rate, claims about "idea gaps"
appear to be not sufficiently grounded anymore. Other authors claim
(e.g. Adekola et al. 2008; Tvaronaviciene, Degutis 2007), that
organizational culture of foreign capital firms differs from local
firms' culture and therefore foreign firms are more efficient. We
stick to economic theories, and support protagonists of diminishing
returns approach. If FDI takes form of capital investments, then returns
diminish as neoclassical growth model suggests; though it does not mean
capital investments do not play an important role in contemporary
economy (Tvaronavicius, Tvaronaviciene 2008). On the other hand, if FDI
enters by acquiring local company's stake, then it is most likely,
that after "spillovering", company being controlled by foreign
capital would crowd local companies out of market or start to repatriate
profits. Market structure here plays a crucial role, hence diminishing
FDI returns obtain especially relevant context when considered through
industrial organization theory lenses (Kottaridi 2005). Separate bulk of
literature on relationships between FDI and bankruptcies of host country
firms exist (e. g. Jensen 2006). Within framework of this paper we are
not going to elaborate the mentioned aspect, just restrict ourselves to
noticing existing ample empirical evidence for crowding in on locals. In
those, listed above, cases diminishing of initial positive (if such
indicated) impact would be considered as highly plausible. In order to
test hypothesis of diminishing FDI effect on host economy industries,
empirical research has to be performed. Before providing theoretical
framework for such research, let us just notice that the results of
numerous empirical studies are very heterogeneous (Tiiks 2007). Besides
proofs of some negative impacts of FDI, the positive effects of FDI on
economic growth were also claimed to be only transitory, i.e. not
permanent (Kenen 2007; Tvaronaviciene, Kalasinskaite 2007). Those
opinions are consistent with our hypothesis of changing impact of FDI
after medium-term period of time span passes; phenomenon appearing as
consistent pattern, despite an array of other economic growth drivers
exists (Lapinskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2009).
We emphasize, that aim of this research is to provide a conceptual
framework enabling evaluation of FDI impact on development of separately
taken industries. Impact itself is understood like process, which is
complex and changeable. We would try to reveal and summarize the cases
of the changing FDI effect on economic development and to provide a
quantitative assessment of globalization effect, which takes form of
FDI. Outcomes are being estimated looking from the point of individual
economic sectors, which naturally affect the entire Lithuanian economy
development. The period of 1996-2007 serves as time span being targeted.
4. Assessment of the impact of FDI on main economic sectors'
expansion
Adopted theoretical assumptions about different impact of FDI on
different sectors of economy depending on their market structure and
hypothesis of changing effects of FDI has led us to the theoretical
framework, which could be presented by the following sequential steps.
1. Strength of linear relationship between values added generated
in main economic activities and FDI, directed to respective economic
activities is being determined. For that purpose statistical data of the
11-year period, i.e. for 1996-2007 are being used. Expected outcome is
indication of different impacts of globalization on development of main
branches of local, in our case Lithuanian, economy. Those branches,
which develop more as a result of globalization, are being considered as
enhancing national wealth.
2. Manufacturing sector, towards which significant share of overall
FDI, was channelled is being scrutinized, i.e. strength of linear
relationship for sector comprising economic activities for the 11-year
period (1996-2007) and two shorter periods, i.e. 1996-2002 and
2002-2007, is being tested.
3. In case, strength of relationships calculated for 11 years
(1996-2007) and for comprising 7-year (1996-2007) and 6-year (2002-2007)
periods change, non-linear relationship for longer, i.e. the 11-year
period is being indicated. Assumption is that in case of significant
change of correlation coefficients values during the first and the
second comprising time periods, non-linear equation for the whole
1996-2002 time period should considerably differ from linear expression.
If the assumption is verified, we would consider non-linear function for
identification of plausible fluctuations of FDI impact during 6-7
(medium-term)-year period.
The first step of analysis attempts to identify FDI impact on the
main branches of economy by using correlation-regression analysis; the
period for analysis embraces years 1996-2007 (initial data and detailed
results of quantitative analysis are presented in Appendix 1). To
generalize, relationships between share of GDP generated (mill LTL) in
main branches of Lithuanian economy and share of FDI (mill LTL) directed
into same branches are as follows. Correlation coefficient between
agricultural sector and FDI channeled to agriculture is 0.49 (weak
relationship), correlation coefficient between the same variables in
manufacturing is 0.98, in construction and services 0.96 and 0.98,
respectively. In case of not going into further analysis, suggested
corollary would claim existence of positive relationship between FDI and
sector growth, which meant FDI enhances growth almost in all main
sectors of economics.
Following elaborated framework for further scrutinizing we choose
manufacturing branch, which among neighbouring Latvia and Estonia
attracted the highest share of FDI (Kalasinskaite 2009). Manufacturing
branch is being comprised of the following main economic activities:
manufacturing sector of food products, manufacturing sector of textile,
manufacturing sector of refined petroleum and supply of electricity, gas
and water. The relationships in the latter sector will not be considered
within framework of this research due to high level of state regulation,
which, to our mind, distort GDP and FDI national wealth enhancing or
deteriorating relationships.
Quantitative evaluation results (correlation coefficients) of
relationships between GDP and FDI in each mentioned manufacturing
sector, differ across sectors and different length time spans. E.g., if
for the industrial manufacturing branch the value of correlation
coefficient equals 0.98, respective correlation coefficients for
comprising activities vary between 0.529 and 0.843 for the same 11-year
period (Table 1). In order to test if character of relationship between
sector FDI and GDP changes, correlation coefficients for shorter time
periods were indicated. It appeared, that when considered 11-year period
is being split into two medium-term periods, character of relationship
changes significantly, e.g. in manufacturing sector correlation
coefficient of 0.529 for the 1996-2007 period changes to 0.260 for
1996-2002 and to -0.297 for the 2002-2007 period; correlation
coefficient in manufacturing sector of textile changes from 0.843 to
0.909 and -0.735, when considered time period is being split into two.
In manufacturing sector of refined petroleum correlation coefficient of
0.701 changes to 0.295 and 0.480 respectively (Table 1). Initial data
and detailed results of quantitative analysis are presented in Appendix
2 (Appendix 2.1, 2.2, 2.3 indicate data and correlation coefficients for
indicated above time periods used for analysis purposes).
Corollary, which can be drawn, is that assumption about changing
impact of FDI on economic development of recipient sector has been
verified. The idea we offer is tentative, and we have no final proof of
its validity, nor is such proof likely to become available. Anyway,
admitting that the process is highly complex and changeable, we believe
it is important to develop conceptual framework letting to indicate
possible cases of such FDI impact change.
As it was indicated above, in further analysis we admit, that in
case of significant change of value of correlation coeficients during
the irst and the second periods, into which considered 11-year time span
is split, non-linear equation for the whole 1996-2002 time period could
be used for prediction about a possible change in character (strength or
direction) of relationship between GDP and FDI after 6-7 years have
passed. We make an assumption that in case non-linear function
considerably differs from linear expression, change of FDI impact on
development of FDI- recipient-sector is more plausible. The non-linear
(or curvilinear) relation was calculated with "Mathematics"
computer software. On the basis of the software-produced relationship
between the gross domestic product (GDP) and FDI, the assessment of FDI
influence character on development of considered economic activities is
being obtained (Figs. 1, 2, 3).
Non-linear relationship obtained for food product manufacturing
sector resembles linear relationship. According to assumption raised, it
would indicate that character of relationship between sector GDP and
sector FDI does not change principally after medium-term period (in our
case 6-7 years) passes. According to our calculus, correlation
coefficient of linear relationship for 1996-2007 time period was 0.529
(Table 1, Appendix 3.1); while for shorter 1996-2002 and 2002-2007
periods it appeared to be 0,260 and, -0,297 respectively (Table 1,
Appendixes 3.2 and 3.3). Despite that correlation coeficients changed,
we need to take into account that values indicated appeared to be of
insignificant strength. Hence, within our theoretical framework, we can
conclude, that assumption we raised was verified, i.e. in case
non-linear relationship resembles linear for longer period, then type of
relationship between sector GDP and sector FDI does not change,
principally, if FDI impact is considered for a part of initially taken
time span. Economic interpretation could be put in the following way:
FDI impact on development of economic activity does not change because
of time lag, which may change conditions in which globalized companies
operate.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Let us scrutinize manufacturing sector of textile using suggested
theoretical framework. The non-linear relationship between FDI
channelled into textile manufacturing industry and expansion of the
industry, reflected by GDP generated in it, is being depicted by a
curve, which differs from a straight (Fig. 2).
If theoretical framework is adopted, then assumption arises that
after medium-term period FDI reaches industry, character of FDI impact
on development of economic sector may change. Correlation coefficients
for linear relationships for the 11-year period (1996-2007) and two
compounding periods (1996-2002) and (2002-2007), respectively, are
presented in Table 1. In this case rather a controversial situation has
been revealed. If for all considered period correlation coefficient is
0.843, for 1996-2002 it equals 0.909. Correlation coefficient of linear
relationship for the 2002-2007 period appears to change considerably not
only in strength, but in direction as well, and shows a rather strong
negative relationship, i.e. is equal to -0.735. The obtained results
serve as the most vivid illustration of a scale within which
mathematical result, and, respectively economic interpretation of
received quantitative evaluation can change, when for analysis purposes
different time spans are being used. Intuition is, that the case
presented above, represents situation, when after any form of
globalization ("green field" investments or acquisitions)
positive effects in form of any kinds of tacit spillovers have
quantitatively measurable effects only in the medium-term period. Later,
we think, due to the innovation absorptive capacity, industry structure,
relationships with various market players and tilt in foreign capital
stakeholders' interests, impact of globalization on development of
local industry, plausibly, changes. Lithuanian textile manufacturing
industry's case for 2002-2007 represents the case of oppositely
changed FDI impact, as rather a strong negative interrelation between
branch's GDP and cumulative FDI has appeared.
In order to approach at least tentative generalizations, let us
take a closer look at another comprising economic activity of
manufacturing industry branch, i.e. manufacturing sector of refined
petroleum. According to suggested theoretical framework, the non-linear
relationship between cumulative FDI and GDP statistically recorded in
textile manufacturing industry during the 1996-2007 period has to be
obtained. Curvilinear expression of the considered relationship is
presented in Fig. 3. Shape of curve, reflecting nonlinear relationship
comparing to a straight, visually seems remote.
According to assumption, incorporated into theoretical framework,
it should signal that impact of FDI on development of economic activity
changes after medium-term period, i.e. quantitatively estimated effect
during the 11-year period (1996-2007) and compounding shorter 1996-2002
and 2002-2007 medium-term periods is different. Correlation coefficients
of linear relationships (Table 1) indicate that in manufacturing sector
of refined petroleum a rather strong positive relationship obtained for
1996-2007 (equalling to 0.701) changes from very weak (0.295) to weak
(0.480) if considered period is being split into two ones. These
results, interpreted economically would mean that FDI, in that case,
actually, has not contributed to development of manufacturing sector of
refined petroleum. As we see, two insights from the obtained results
might be drawn. The first, application of different economic
phenomena's estimation modes in some cases can lead to differing
conclusions; insight consistent with results received by application of
other mathematical tools of economic analysis (Tvaronaviciene et al.
2008). The second insight contains a suggestion that more close
surveillance of globalization outcomes after a certain time lag, which
in our case embraces 6-7 years, has to be performed. Conditions, under
which change of FDI impact on development of globalized economic branch
shows up, remain the object of further elaboration.
5. Conclusions
In order to decide whether globalization in form of FDI enhances
national wealth, an approach to evaluation and, consequently,
theoretical framework of analysis has to be developed. In the presented
paper elaboration of such framework is being based on an assumption that
FDI affects national wealth through impact on the development of a
particular branch of economy, which can appear to be within a wide range
of values and reflect impact which varies from significantly positive to
significantly negative. Further, assumption is being raised, that impact
of FDI can change after medium-term period (of 6-7 years) passes.
Whether the impact of FDI would change during the longer (11-year)
period, under theoretical framework suggested, can be determined from
the mathematical nature of the examined relationship (the relationship
is calculated on the basis of GDP in the branch analysed and FDI in the
branch).
If the non-linear relation for the considered (as it was mentioned
above, in Lithuanian case it embraces 11 years) period is rather close
to linear relation, it is assumed, that the mode of FDI impact on
industry development most likely would remain not changed. If non-linear
relation does not resemble linear, it is considered that the fact points
of the shift in the direction of the relation change due to the changing
impact of FDI on industry. In the latter case, i.e., in the next stage
of analysis, the period under review is split into two: the stage of the
intensive arrival of FDI, and the following stage.
FDI impact on the economic development of more economically
developed countries differs from the impact of foreign capital on the
economy of less-developed countries. After the average period of 6-7
years following the inflow of FDI into the host country due to change of
companies structure in FDI receiving branches of host economy and due to
other factors, such as fast absorption of spillover effects and,
consequently, diminishing of FDI branch development enhancing power,
domination of interests of repatriating profits, etc., strength of the
FDI impact and even its trend may undergo certain changes. The analysis
of the Lithuanian manufacturing branch revealed change of FDI impact on
some manufacturing sectors' expansion: the initial positive impact
of the foreign capital in some cases appeared to be unsustainable.
Case study of Lithuanian economy appeared to be consistent with
suggested theoretical framework, which, as we see it, provides with new
approaches to FDI cost benefit analysis, which we expect would trigger
newly formulated scientific discussion about globalization consequences
and, respectively, policy implications.
Received 23 February 2009; accepted 10 January 2010
APPENDIX 1
GDP generated in main branches of economy, cumulative FDI directed
into main branches of economy and obtained correlation coefficients
for the 1996-2007 period
Agricultural branch Manufacturing
Cumulative Cumulative
Branch GDP, branch Branch GDP, branch
Years mill Lt FDI, mill Lt mill Lt FDI, mill Lt
1996 3 661.80 18.40 5 508.00 1 153.19
1997 3 990.90 49.23 6 583.00 1 524.93
1998 3 832.30 55.91 7 226.40 2 106.06
1999 3 201.70 41,80 6 879.30 2 625.08
2000 3 188.60 44.86 7 853.90 2 686.00
2001 3 055.10 50.60 8 611.00 2 728.66
2002 3 247.50 60.87 8 675.80 3 863.64
2003 3 265.90 111.74 9 828.60 4 260.18
2004 3 308.10 127.77 11 838.40 5 503.20
2005 3 661.70 168.10 13 475.00 9 457.60
2006 3 807.00 170.30 15 165.70 11 510.30
2007 4 593.20 192.13 16 525.40 12 570.90
Correlation 0.49 0.98
coefficient
Construction Services
Cumulative Cumulative
Branch GDP, branch Branch GDP, branch
Years mill Lt FDI, mill Lt mill Lt FDI, mill Lt
1996 2 045.80 10.19 16 610.10 1 568.84
1997 2 660.70 14.80 20 124.00 2 488.87
1998 3 269.90 32.55 23 036.20 4 238.37
1999 2 921.60 57,92 23 536.00 5 447.97
2000 2 441.90 69.77 25 255.90 6 198.71
2001 2 570.30 68.86 26 882.80 7 417.69
2002 2 901.60 141.76 29 199.20 8 515.60
2003 3 603.40 158.71 31 466.10 8 448.73
2004 4 102.10 194.13 34 523.00 9 028.35
2005 4 916.60 283.00 39 501.50 10 833.00
2006 6 515.70 474.80 45 142.30 13 563.70
2007 8 632.10 548.99 53 129.00 17 895.80
Correlation 0.96 0.98
coefficient
APPENDIX 2
Relationships in manufacturing branch between main manufacturing
sectors GDP and FDI, when different time periods for analysis purposes
are being used
APPENDIX 2.1
GDP generated in main branches of economy, cumulative FDI directed into
main branches of economy and obtained correlation coefficients for the
1996-2007 period
Manufacturing sector Manufacturing sector
of food products of textile
Cumulative Cumulative
Sector GDP, sector FDI, Sector GDP, sector FDI,
Years mill Lt mill Lt mill Lt mill Lt
1996 1 700.60 452.22 904.20 160.43
1997 1 891.30 555.95 1 077.90 133.86
1998 1 935.10 764.78 1 247.60 263.58
1999 1 722.30 973.96 1 308.30 289.54
2000 1 809.00 1 077.25 1 426.50 351.41
2001 1 919.30 1 157.06 1 569.80 334.17
2002 1 863.10 1 480.63 1 486.30 309.57
2003 1 982.20 1 602.02 1 477.80 303.38
2004 2 178.60 1 670.08 1 587.40 262.96
2005 2 453.50 1 618.50 1 506.80 326.90
2006 2 761.10 1 433.90 1 524.10 315.88
2007 3 479.90 1 522.58 1 477.50 310.38
Correlation 0.529 0.843
coefficient
Manufacturing sector
of reined petroleum
Cumulative
Sector GDP, sector FDI,
Years mill Lt mill Lt
1996 362.60 69.01
1997 610.60 107.55
1998 519.20 197.45
1999 410.00 303.02
2000 760.90 171.16
2001 917.50 92.65
2002 805.70 821.82
2003 927.40 779.76
2004 1 367.60 1 327.82
2005 1 801.20 4 820.00
2006 1 631.10 7 386.80
2007 1 085.90 8 097.19
Correlation 0.701
coefficient
APPENDIX 2.2
GDP generated in main branches of economy, cumulative FDI directed
into main branches of economy and obtained correlation coefficients
for the 1996-2002 period
Manufacturing sector Manufacturing sector
of food products of textile
Cumulative Cumulative
Sector GDP, sector FDI, Sector GDP, sector FDI,
Years mill Lt mill Lt mill Lt mill Lt
1996 1 700.60 452.22 904.20 160.43
1997 1 891.30 555.95 1 077.90 133.86
1998 1 935.10 764.78 1 247.60 263.58
1999 1 722.30 973.96 1 308.30 289.54
2000 1 809.00 1 077.25 1 426.50 351.41
2001 1 919.30 1 157.06 1 569.80 334.17
2002 1 863.10 1 480.63 1 486.30 309,.57
Correlation 0.260 0.909
coefficient
Manufacturing sector
of refined petroleum
Cumulative
Sector GDP, sector FDI,
Years mill Lt mill Lt
1996 362.60 69.01
1997 610.60 107.55
1998 519.20 197.45
1999 410.00 303.02
2000 760.90 171.16
2001 917.50 92.65
2002 820.60 821.82
Correlation 0.295
coefficient
APPENDIX 2.3
GDP generated in main branches of economy, cumulative FDI directed
into main branches of economy and obtained correlation coefficients
for the 2002-2007 period
Manufacturing sector of Manufacturing sector of
food products textile
Cumulative Cumulative
sector FDI, Sector GDP, sector FDI, Sector GDP,
Years mill Lt mill Lt mill Lt mill Lt
2002 1 863.10 1 480.63 1 486.30 309.57
2003 1 982.20 1 602.02 1 477.80 303.38
2004 2 178.60 1 670.08 1 587.40 262.96
2005 2 453.50 1 618.50 1 506.80 326.90
2006 2 761.10 1 433.90 1 524.10 315.88
2007 3 479.90 1 522.58 1 477.50 310.38
Correlation -0.297 -0.735
coefficient
Manufacturing sector of
reined petroleum
Cumulative
sector FDI, Sector GDP,
Years mill Lt mill Lt
2002 820.60 821.82
2003 927.40 779.76
2004 1 367.60 1 327.82
2005 1 801.20 4 820.00
2006 1 631.10 7 386.80
2007 1 085.90 8 097.19
Correlation 0.480
coefficient
doi: 10.3846/jbem.2010.01
References
Adekola, A.; Korsakiene, R.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2008. Approach to
innovative activities by Lithuanian companies in the current conditions
of development, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4):
595-611. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.595-611
Borensztein, E.; De Gregorio, J.; Lee, J-W. 1998. How does foreign
direct investment affect economic growth? Journal of International
Economics 45(1): 115-135. doi:10.1016/S0022-1996(97)00033-0
Buckley, P. J. 2006. Stephen Hymer: Three phases, one approach?
International Business Review 15: 140-147.
doi:10.1016/j.ibusrev.2005.03.008
Buckley, P. J.; Casson, M. 1998. Analyzing foreign market entry
strategies: extending the internalization approach, Journal of
International Business Studies 29(3): 539-561.
doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490006
Durham, J.; Benson, A. 2004. Economic growth and institutions: some
sensitivity analyses, 1961-2000, International Organizations 58(3):
485-529. doi:10.1017/S0020818304583030
Ginevicius, R.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2004. Risk of globalization:
case study of Lithuanian economy, Ekonomicky Casopis [Journal of
Economics] 52(2): 212-231.
Goldstein, I; Assaf, R. 2006. An information-based trade off
between foreign direct investment and foreign portfolio investment,
Journal of International Economics 70(2): 271-295.
doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.12.002
Hosseini, H. 2005. An economic theory of FDI: a behavioural economics and historical approach, The Journal of Socio-Economics 34:
528-541. doi:10.1016/j.socec.2005.07.001
Jensen, C. 2006. Foreign direct investment and economic transition:
panacea or pain killer? Europe-Asia Studies 58(6): 881-902.
doi:10.1080/09668130600831084
Kalasinskaite, K. 2009. Tiesioginiu_ uzsienio investiciju_ poveikis
ekonomikos pletrai Lietuvos ir kitu_ Baltijos saliu_ pavyzdziu [The
impact of Foreign Direct Investment on economic development: case of
Lithuania and other Baltic States]. Daktaro disertacija. Vinius:
Technika. 112 p. (in Lithuanian).
Kenen, P. B. 2007. The benefits and risks of financial
globalization, CATO Journal 27(2): 179-183.
Kottaridi, C. 2005. The 'Core-Periphery' pattern of
FDI-led growth and production structure in the EU, Applied Economics
37(1): 99-113. doi:10.1080/0003684042000291308
Lapinskiene, G.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2009. Sustainable development accross Central and Eastern Europe: key factors driving the economic
growth of the countries, Verslas: teorija ir paktika [Business:Theory
and Practice] 10(3): 204-213. doi:10.3846/1648-0627.2009.10.204-213
Leahy, D.; Montagna, C. 2000. Unionization and foreign direct
investment: challenging conventional wisdom? Economic Journal 110(462):
80-92. doi:10.1111/1468-0297.00522
McClintock, B. 1988. Recent theories of direct foreign investment:
an institutional perspective, Journal of Economic Issues 22(2): 477-485.
Meyer, K.; Saul, E. 2001. Brownfield entry in emerging markets,
Journal of International Business Studies 32(3): 575-584.
doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490985
Raff, H.; Ryan, M.; Stahler, F. 2009. The choice of market entry
mode: greenfield investment, M&A and joint venture, International
Review of Economics and Finance 18(1): 3-10.
doi:10.1016/j.iref.2008.02.006
Romer, P. 1993. Idea Gaps and object gaps in economic development,
Journal of Monetary Economics 32(3): 543-573.
doi:10.1016/0304-3932(93)90029-F
Romer, P. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth, Journal of
Political Economy 94 (5): 1002-1037. doi:10.1086/261420
Tarzi, S. 2005. Foreign Direct Investment flows into developing
countries: impact of location and government policy, Journal of Social,
Political & Economic Studies 30(4): 497-515.
Tiiks, M. 2007. Technology-intensive FDI and economic development
in a small country - the case of Estonia, A Journal of the Humanities
& Social Sciences 11(3): 324-342.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Kalasinskaite, K. 2007. Impact of foreign
direct investments on Lithuanian banking sector, in 4th International
Scientific Conference Business and Management and 14th International
Scientific Conference, Enterprise Management: Diagnosis, Strategy,
Efficiency : Selected papers. 5-6 October, Vilnius, Lithuania. Vilnius:
Technika, 81-89.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Degutis, M. 2007. If approach to innovations
differs in locally and foreign owned firms: case of Lithuania, Journal
of Business Economics and Management 7(3): 195-203.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Grybaite, V. 2007. Impact of FDI on Lithuanian
economy: insight into development of main economic activities, Journal
of Business Economics and Management 8(4): 285-290.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Grybaite, V.; Tvaronaviciene, A. 2009. If
institutional performance matters: development comparisons of Lithuania,
Latvia and Estonia, Journal of Business Economics and Management 10(3):
271-278. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.271-278
Tvaronavicius, V.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2008. Role of fixed
investments in economic growth of country: Lithuania in European
context, Journal of Business Economics and Management 9(1): 57-64.
doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.57-64
Manuela TVARONAVICIENE. Prof., Dr, Department of Enterprise
Economics and Management, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University (Lithuania). Qualification raise: IESE Business School, Spain,
Politechnico di Milano, Italy, Harvard Business School, USA. Research
interests: economic development, foreign direct investment, business
environment.
Kristina KALASINSKAITE. PhD, Department of Enterprise Economics and
Business Management, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University (Lithuania).
Research interests: foreign direct investment (FDI) and their economical
evaluation.
Manuela Tvaronaviciene (1), Kristina Kalasinskaite (2)
Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, 10223
Vilnius, Lithuania E-mails: (1)
[email protected]; (2)
[email protected]
Table 1. Juxtaposition of correlation coefficients of linear
relationship between industrial sector GDP and sector FDI
for the 1996-2007 period and medium-term (split) periods
Manufacturing sector
of food products
(years 1996-2007)
0.529
(years 1996-2002) (years 2002-2007)
0.260 -0.297
Manufacturing sector
of textile
(years 1996-2007)
0.843
(years 1996-2002) (years 2002-2007)
0.909 -0.735
Manufacturing sector
of refined petroleum
(years 1996-2007)
0.701
(years 1996-2002) (years 2002-2007)
0.295 0.480
Source: Kalasinskaite 2009: 104-111.