The state of competition of the Turkish banking industry: an application of the Panzar-Rosse model/Konkurencija turkijos bankininkystes sektoriuje: Panzar-Rosse modelio taikymas.
Aktan, Bora ; Masood, Omar
1. Introduction
In recent years, a continuously increasing number of papers have
investigated competition in the banking industry. Globalizations and the
liberalization of financial markets have raised broad interest in this
topic. Obviously, competition in the banking sector has a major impact
on the wealth of consumers and companies and affects the performance and
financial condition of the banks. This further initiated the mergers
among banks and other financial institutions causing drastic changes and
competition in the structure of the banking industry.
Turkish banking industry forms a great part of the whole financial
system in the country's dynamic economy. Most of the transactions
and activities of money and capital markets are carried out by banks.
Most State banks were established to finance a particular industry such
as agriculture i.e., Ziraat Bank, but private banks generally have close
connections to large industrial groups and holdings.
How have competitive conditions in Turkey changed the overall
banking and regulations in the country in the last decade? By the scope
of this paper, we answer this question by using econometric techniques
to examine the nature of competitive conditions in the market of the
major Turkish banks.
One of the most popular methods used to assess the competition in
the banking industry is the Panzar and Rosse Model. Seminal articles by
Rosse and Panzar (1977), Panzar and Rosse (1982, 1987) provide an
excellent framework for assessing degrees of competition in the banking
industry. However, the empirical translation of this approach into an
econometric specification is ambiguous and allows for some degrees of
freedom. The model uses cross-sectional data to assess the competitive
behavior of banks based on the comparative static properties of
reduced-form revenue equations. It explains revenues from input prices,
among other factors. In this setting, the sum of the elasticities of a
bank's total revenues to its input prices provides a pivotal
statistic to test for monopoly and perfect competition. Moreover, under
certain assumptions this statistic can also serve as a measure of the
degree of competition in the banking sector.
The motivation behind our research is, limited literature tackling
the market structure of the Turkish banking sector. This study
contributes to the literature on market structure in Turkish banking
systems by using a larger sample of banks over a significant amount of
time. As we measure the competitiveness through our dataset collected
from 17 major banks in the Turkish banking sector. It helps us to relate
the contestability indicators and to explain differences in the degree
of competition across Turkey. The aim of this research is to provide
empirical evidence on the level and evolution of competition in the
Turkish sector. For this purpose, we employ Panzar-Rosse model, which
enables calculation of a measure of market structure, the /-statistic,
as the sum of the elasticities of total revenues of the bank with
respect to its input prices.
The paper is organized as follows: Following the introduction,
Section 2 discusses the previous studies, Section 3 presents a brief
situation of the Turkish banking system, Section 4 introduces the
Panzar-Rosse Model and the characteristic of the data used in the paper,
Section 5 provides the empirical findings and Section 6 finally
concludes with a short summary.
2. Previous Studies
The theory of contestable markets developed by Baumol et al. (1982)
stated that oligopolies and monopolies sometimes behave very much like
perfectly competitive firms. There have been few applications of the
contestable markets theory on the banking industry. Studies by Shaffer
(1982, 1983, 1994), Nathan and Neave (1989) and Molyneux et al. (1994,
1996) are the most significant among many others. They employed tests
developed by Rosse and Panzar (1977) and Panzar and Rosse (1987) to
examine the competitive conditions in the banking industry in the U.S.,
Canada, Japan and Europe.
Nathan and Neave (1989) found some evidence that the U.S and
Canadian banking markets exhibit characters of contestability.
Shaffer (1982) reported the first application of the Panzar-Rosse
test to banking data, obtaining 0 < H < 1 for a sample of banks
based in New York. Using European banking data for 1986-89, Molyneux et
al. (1994) obtained 0 < H < 1 for France, Germany, Spain and the
UK, and H < 0 for Italy. Using 1992-96 data, De Bandt and Davis
(2000) obtained 0 < H < 1 for France, Germany, Italy and the US.
Similar results were reported by Nathan and Neave (1989) for Canada,
Molyneux et al. (1996) for Japan, Staikouras and Koutsomanoli-Fillipaki
(2006) for the enlarged European Union. Hondroyiannis et al. (1999)
assessed competitive conditions in the Greek banking system in 19931995
and found that the banking industry in Greece had a monopolistic
competition. Bikker and Haaf (2002) investigated competitive conditions
and concentration in the banking markets of 23 industrialized countries
by using Panzar-Rosse model along with Bresnahan (1982) model. Their
results reveal that banking markets of the industrialized countries are
characterized by monopolistic competition and sometimes even perfect
competition cannot be excluded. Casu and Girardone (2006) employed both
structural concentration measures and Panzar-Rosse model to investigate
competitive conditions in European Union banking markets. Based on their
results, while they argue that the degree of concentration is not
necessarily related to the degree of competition their /-statistic
reveals that there is a monopolistic competition in the EU market.
CarboValverde et al. (2009) employed five different measures including
Panzar-Rosse H statistic to determine the degree of competition in 14
European banking industries. Their analysis yields conflicting results
contingent upon the competition indicator employed. Thus, they argued
that it is essential to employ a range of different competition measures
to determine competition behavior of countries and the studies should
consider country specific factors as well.
While most of the early applications of Panzar-Rosse model mainly
focused on the developed countries' banking industries, more recent
ones apply the model to the other markets (e.g. Masood and Aktan 2010;
Celik and Urunveren 2009; Turk-Ariss 2009; Yuan 2006; Gunalp and Celik
2006; Kasman 2001). Gelos and Roldos (2004) applied Panzar-Rosse
methodology on a sample of eight emerging markets including Argentina,
Brazil, Chile, Czech Republic, Hungary, Mexico, Poland and Turkey. Their
results indicate that market structure for the majority of countries can
be characterized by monopolistic competition and the banking industries
in the sample have not become less competitive. Kasman (2001) and Gunalp
and Celik (2006) assessed the competition in the Turkish banking
industry by using Panzar-Rosse H statistic and concluded that Turkish
banks show a monopolistic competition. While the competition of the
Latin American countries banking industries is found to be monopolistic
by Yildirim and Philippatos (2007a), Yeyati and Micco (2007)
investigated the concentration and foreign penetration on the
competitive behavior of the Latin American banking industries including
Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, El Salvador, Mexico and
Peru. They found that while concentration had no weakening effect on
competition, foreign penetration led to a less competitive banking
industry in the region. Yildirim and Philippatos (2007b) examined the
competitive conditions in the banking industries of 14 Central and
Eastern European (CEE) transition economies for the period 1993-2000.
The countries in the sample include: Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia,
Croatia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, FYR of Macedonia, Poland, Romania,
Slovenia, Slovak Republic, Russian Federation and Yugoslavia. The paper
argue that the banking markets of the countries in the sample (except
for Macedonia and Slovakia) cannot be characterized by either perfect
competition of monopoly1.
According to Blaug (1980: 118), "traditional microeconomics is
largely, if not entirely, an analysis of timeless comparative statics,
and as such it is strong on equilibrium outcomes but weak on the process
whereby equilibrium is attained". Schumpeter (1954) regarded static
theory as operating at a higher level of abstraction than dynamic
theory. Goddard et al. (2004a, b) found that convergence towards
long-run equilibrium is by no means instantaneous. Berger et al. (2000)
reached a similar conclusion by using non-parametric techniques to
measure persistence.
The New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) assesses the
strength of market power by examining deviations between the observed
and the marginal cost pricing, without explicitly using any market
structure indictor. The Rosse and Panzar (1977) reduced-form revenue
model and the Bresnahan (1982) and Lau (1982) mark-up model are two the
most popular approaches to this type of analysis.
The Panzar-Rosse approach works well with firm-specific data on
revenues and factor prices, and does not require information about
equilibrium output prices and quantities for the firm and/or industry.
In addition, the Panzar-Rosse approach is robust in small samples, while
the Bresnahan-Lau model tends to exhibit an anticompetitive bias in
small samples (Shaffer 2004). Rosse and Panzar (1977) and Panzar and
Rosse (1982, 1987), together with applications to banking by Nathan and
Neave (1989) and Perrakis (1991), assumed that firms can enter or leave
any market rapidly, without losing their capital, and that potential
competitors operate on the same cost functions as established firms.
Most previous studies that have employed the Panzar-Rosse
methodology have used data sets containing large numbers of banks and
small numbers of periods. The Panzar-Rosse methodology is only one of
the numerous ways to measure the nature of competitive conditions.
Uchida and Tsutsui (2005) used the Cournot oligopoly version of the
Monti-Klein model of the banking firm to derive a loan interest rate
setting function in terms of the cost of funds and marginal operational
costs of servicing loans and deposits (2). Matthews et al. (2007) found
evidences that the intensity of competition in the core market of bank
lending for British banks remained approximately unchanged throughout
the 1980s and 1990s. They also argued that competition appears to have
become less intense in the non-core (off-balance sheet) business of
British banks.
One of the limitations of the Panzar-Rosse tests is that it gives
misleading results when the banks in question are not completely
adjusted to the market conditions. However, the test generally indicates
that the market is competitive, it checks that the monopoly power is not
been excersied. Secondly, it cannot differentiate between competitive
pricing and simple costing plus pricing. Interpreting the Panzar-Rosse
is not very clear, once this limitation taken into account.
3. The Turkish Banking Industry
Financial system in Turkey is largely dominated by commercial banks
which many transactions and activities in both money and capital markets
are carried out therefore, its banking sector is virtually synonymous
with the entire system on account of the country's economic and
historical development. As all the major economies of the world are
reeling under the pressure of financial crisis, the banking industry in
Turkey continued to grow in 2008 and foreign participation also
increased. Recent economic and financial reforms providing positive
atmosphere and attractiveness for growth encouraged many foreign banks
enter into the sector with full banking activities while forced existing
banks to restructure their organizations, operations and activities
(Aktan et al. 2009a).
Banks operating in Turkey can be classified under three main groups
as those with the permission to accept deposits (commercial or deposit
banks), those not accepting deposits (non-deposit or development and
investment banks) and participation banks which are based upon
interest-free banking (Profit/Loss Sharing). Besides, each group can be
divided into three sub-groups as state-owned, privately owned, and
foreign banks according to their ownership structures. As of December
2008, the number of banks operating in Turkey was 49. 32 of them were in
deposit banks group, 13 of them were non-deposit banks and 4 of them
were participation banks. Among deposit banks, there were 3 state-owned
banks, 11 privately-owned banks, 17 foreign banks and one bank, under
the supervision of the Savings Deposit Insurance Fund (SDIF) with 8791
branches including those abroad. In addition, 17 of the banks are listed
on the Istanbul Stock Exchange (BAT 2008).
By the end of 2008, total assets of banking sector amounted to TRY
732.7 billion ($ 481.5 billion USD). When the asset distribution of the
sector is analyzed, it is seen that 3.6% of total assets of the sector
is comprised of non-current assets in the period examined. The share of
cash and quasi-cash assets in total balance sheet size was realized as
12.9% level while the share of loans in total assets was 50.3% and the
share of securities portfolio in total assets was realized as 26.5%. The
total loans of the sector were TRY 367.6 billion ($ 241.5 billion USD).
On the other hand, total deposit of the sector amounted TRY 454.6
billion ($ 298.7 billion USD) while net profit of the period was TRY
13.3 billion ($ 8.74 billion USD) (BRSA 2009)3.
The crisis of 1999-2001 is rooted in the institutional development
of the regulatory and supervisory mechanisms in the Turkish banking
sector. Deposit insurance was introduced in 1983 in the aftermath of the
massive collapse of savings and loans institutions. The 1985 law on
banking regulations (Banking Act No. 3182), which retroactively
formalized the limited deposit insurance and made the Treasury the
principle institution responsible for bank supervision and regulation,
represented the first major attempt at regulating the banking sector.
Legislation making deposit insurance more generous contributed to
the banking sector's problems. Initially the coverage was limited
to 100% of Turkish lira deposits up to a legally set maximum and 60
percent thereafter (Banks Act No. 3182). In 1992, the coverage was
extended to foreign currency accounts. Finally, on May 5, 1994 after the
banking crisis and a run on banks, the Treasury eliminated the cap and
declared 100 percent insurance on all deposits. Although this helped to
stabilize the banking sector during the 1994 crisis, it also encouraged
further risky behavior leading up to the crisis in 1999.
In addition, financial sector regulators and supervisors lacked
autonomy, making them susceptible to political and industry pressure.
Furthermore, basic accounting, auditing and disclosure practices were
also significantly below international best practice (Aktan et al.
2009b). Honohan (1997), for example, emphasizes that Turkey's 100%
deposit guarantee and a tradition of forbearance instead of firm
corrective action encouraged excessive risk taking, increased moral
hazards and weakened market discipline. Alper and Onis (2002) argue that
the destruction of bank franchise values was the result of heavy
government intervention and unfair competition.
The severe banking crisis in 1999 highlighted the need for
instituting an autonomous and independent banking supervisory and
regulatory framework. The formation of the Banking Regulation and
Supervisory Agency (BRSA) in 1999 was an important milestone in banking
regulation in Turkey. As an independent regulatory agency, BRSA was
somewhat insulated from the political pressures that plagued the
supervisory functions of the Treasury. There is some doubt about the
extent of its independence, however. According to Alper and Onis (2002)
the organization is not entirely isolated from political intervention
since the Cabinet appoints its chairman and board members. In fact, in
2000, the appointment of the first board bitterly divided the governing
coalition and the final decision was repeatedly delayed and only
approved because it was a "structural performance criterion",
which had to be met to qualify for financial assistance from the
International Monetary Fund (IMF). After the crisis of February 2001,
the autonomy and political independence of the BRSA was called into
doubt when the IMF requested the dismissal of the first set of board
members. In general, following the above-stated crisis and the
restructuring process, the banking sector showed a rapid growth
performance in 2002-2008 period and the risk management systems improved
and public supervision became more effective in Turkey.
4. Data and Method
4.1. The Data
The data used in this study were obtained from Datastream and also
collected from 17 significant banks of Turkey which are all listed on
the Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE), including Akbank TAS, Albaraka Turk,
Alternatifbank AS, Asya Katilim Bankasi AS, Denizbank AS, Finansbank AS,
Fortis Bank AS, Sekerbank TAS, Tekstil Bankasi AS, Turk Ekonomi Bankasi
AS, Turkiye Garanti Bankasi AS, Turkiye Halk Bankasi AS, Turkiye Is
Bankasi AS, Turkiye Kalkinma Bankasi AS, Turkiye Sinai Kalkinma Bankasi
AS, Turkiye Vakiflar Bankasi TAO, Yapi ve Kredi Bankasi AS. The dataset
was developed by collecting the information related to these banks.
The pooled data was made by combining the datasets from all the
banks covering the period 1998-2008. The regression analysis was
performed on this pooled data to obtain the results which are mentioned
in the next section. The mean square and double accounting techniques
were also used on the dataset, wherever required.
4.2. The Model
The test developed by Panzar-Rosse examines the relationship
between examines a relationship between input prices and equilibrium
gross revenue derived from the theory of the firm under some assumptions
about competitive conditions. They showed that the sum of the
elasticities of the reduced form revenue function with reduced prices is
a measure of competitive conditions.
Panzar-Rosse assumed long run equilibrium equations on firm's
revenue and input price vectors. Their approach was to measure the
effect of factor prices on the observed equilibrium values of total
revenue R. If R is the observed revenue and [w.sub.i] is the price of
ith input, where i = 1, 2, 3 ... n, then the test quantity of H (The
Rosse-Panzar (P-R) H statistics) is
P - [R.sub.H] = [[summation].sup.n.sub.(i=1)]
[delta]R[w.sub.i]/[delta][w.sub.i]R. (1)
In the Rosse and Panzar (1977) and Panzar and Rosse (1987) there
are four features. Firstly, under the monopoly equilibrium, sum of the
factor prices elasticities of a monopolist's reduced form revenue
must be non-positive. Secondly under monopolistic equilibrium sum of
elasticities of the of the firm's reduced form revenues with
respect to factor prices is less than or equal to unity. Thirdly, for
the firms in long run equilibrium the sum of elasticities of the reduced
form revenues with respect to factor prices of the firm must be equal to
unity. Finally, for the firms in stable, conjectural variation oligopoly
equilibrium, the sum of factor price elasticities of reduced form output
equation is negative.
In order to test the monopolistic competition Panzar and Rosse
(1987) follow the assumption regarding the way the firm's revenue
gets repositioned by market forces after an input change. Panzar-Rosse
relies on the fact that individual banks prices in response to changes
in cost, which also depends weather the banks enjoys a monopoly market
or instead is facing a competitive market.
If the banks have a monopoly power and sets its prices to maximum
profits, it chooses price so that its gross revenue responds in opposite
direction from a change in unit costs. If the market is perfectly
competitive, the industries gross revenues could rise or fall, depending
on the demand factors, but the banks entry or exit would force each
existing bank's revenue to change in same direction as its unit
costs.
The Panzar-Rosse model can be interpreted by the help of the below
Table 1 provided by Hondroyiannis et al. (1999).
Rosse and Panzar (1977), Panzar and Rosse (1982, 1987) show that
when the H-statistic is negative (H < 0) the structure of the market
is monopolistic. This case includes oligopoly with collusion, and may
include a conjectural variation short-run oligopoly. In such cases, an
increase in input prices will increase marginal costs, reduce
equilibrium output and reduce total revenue. An H-statistic of one (H =
1) is associated with perfect competition, as any increase in input
prices increases both marginal and average costs, without altering the
optimal output of any individual firm. This case also includes a natural
monopoly operating in a perfectly contestable market, and a
sales-maximizing firm subject to break-even constraints. Finally, 0 <
H < 1, is associated with monopolistic competition.
According to the Panzar-Rosse methodology, measure of market
structure is calculated as sum of the elasticities of total revenues of
the bank with respect to its input prices. It is estimated from the
following:
ln (TR) = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] ln [W.sub.L] + [[beta].sub.2] ln
[W.sup.F] + [[beta].sub.3] ln [W.sub.K] + [[gamma].sub.1] ln [Y.sub.1] +
[Y.sub.2] ln [Y.sub.2] + [[gamma].sub.3] ln [Y.sub.3] + [epsilon], (2)
where:
TR = Total Revenue
[W.sub.L] = Ratio of Personnel Expenses to Total Assets
[W.sub.F] = Ratio of Interest Expenses to Total Deposits
[W.sub.K] = Ratio of Other Operating and Administrative Expenses to
Total Assets
[Y.sub.1] = Ratio of Equity to Total Assets
[Y.sub.2] = Net Loans to Total Assets
[Y.sub.3] = Total Assets
Various assumptions are required to be made to apply to the
Panzar-Rosse methodology such as, banks are treated as single product
firms, acting exclusively as financial intermediaries that produce
interest revenues using labor, capital and intermediated funds (mainly
deposits) as inputs. Moreover it is assumed that higher factor prices
are not correlated with higher revenues generated by higher quality
services, since this may bias the computed H-statistic.
ln (ROA) = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] ln [W.sub.L] + [[beta].sub.2]
ln [W.sub.F] + [[beta].sub.3] ln [W.sub.K] + [[gamma].sub.1] ln
[Y.sub.1] + [Y.sub.2] ln [Y.sub.2] + [[gamma].sub.3] ln [Y.sub.3] +
[epsilon], (3)
where ROA = Return on Assets.
In the Panzar-Rosse framework, banks should be observed from a
long-run equilibrium perspective. The equilibrium statistic e is
calculated as the sum of the input price elasticities, and the
hypothesis that its value is 0 is tested where, if rejected, the market
is not in equilibrium.
5. Empirical Analysis
The equilibrium tests and the competitive conditions tests for
pooled data regressions on the data sample for Turkish banks over a
period of 1998-2008 are shown in the Tables 2 and 3 respectively.
The equilibrium conditions are tested using the estimation of
lnROA. The results show that it yields a R-squared value of 0.59. This
suggests that the variables that we use have a very small impact on the
variation in lnROA. We also observe that the regression coefficients are
positive, with lnWF significant at 5% level.
From the above table we observe that E-statistic of -0.048, hence
we are unable us to reject the null hypothesis at 10% level. We tested
by running a rolling regression of a 11-year window with the aim of
identifying whether the banking market was in equilibrium or not. Our
results indicate that Turkey banking sector is in an equilibrium state.
The calculated E-statistic is not significantly different from 0 at the
95% level for Turkey. The banking markets are thus in long-run
equilibrium.
The Panzar-Rosse H-statistic indicates that banks in Turkey are
operating as a whole under conditions of monopolistic competition. A
monopolistic competition structure is the existence of product
differentiation in banking and with the fact that banks tend to differ
with respect to product quality and advertising.
The competitive conditions are tested using the estimation of lnTR.
The results show that it yields a R-squared value of 0.79. This suggests
that the variables that we use have a very small impact on the variation
in lnTR. By our results we can conclude that market power resulting from
high concentration levels does not exclude competitive behavior. This
suggests that the degree of competition in banking may be affected by
different factors for differences.
Now we consider the factors which affect the degree of competition.
The sample consists of panel data for the individual profiled countries
over the period 1998-2008. The models are estimated following equation
given below:
[H.sub.i] = a + b[C.sub.i] + e , (4)
where:
[H.sub.i] = Degree of competition,
[C.sub.i] = Vector of variables.
The variables are obtained from Barth et al. (2007), Economist
Intelligence Unit Country Profiles and Turk-Ariss (2009). Ci (vector of
variables) is classified into two categories, including industry control
factors and indicators of banking structures. Industry control variables
include three variables efficiency, profitability and capitalization
levels whereas indicators of banking structures include bank
concentration foreign ownership. The description of the variables is
given in the Table 4.
The estimation results on these variables reported in Table 5.
Panel A considers the yearly-derived H-statistic as dependent variable,
and panel B uses the overall H-statistic as the dependent variable.
We observe that the sign of all the models of the industry
controlled variables is negative. This indicates that Turkish banks
which operate in more monopolistic environments are also less efficient.
Our findings are similar to Turk-Ariss (2009), but different to Casu and
Girardone (2006), who argue that banks in more competitive markets are
also more efficient. We found profitability was positive for all the
models, indicating that banks were able to achieve high records of
profitability in monopolistically competitive markets.
The capitalization is also found positive, which indicates that
lesser capitalized banks were not able to operate better in competitive
markets. We observe a negative but in significant relationship between
concentration and competition. This indicates that the degree of
competition increases with increases in market concentration across
Turkish banking sectors. It can therefore be concluded that due to high
concentration in the Turkish banking system in the last decade, the
market power for the leading firms have reduced. Our results are
henceforth in line with Casu and Girardone (2006) but opposite to
Claessens and Laeven (2004) who found a positive association between
concentration and competition.
6. Final Remarks
This paper examines competitive structures of 17 paramount banks in
the Turkish banking sectors over the period 1998-2008 and investigates
factors that can explain differences in the degree of competitiveness.
The Panzar-Rosse methodology is used to test for the competitive nature
of banking sector and also gives the measure of competition, the
H-statistic, is related to a number of industry controls and prevailing
banking structures.
Our results indicate that Turkey banking sector is in an
equilibrium state, further they are in long run equilibrium. According
to the findings, which seem consistent with the previous studies'
findings (Kasman 2001; Gunalp and Celik 2006) on the industry, the banks
in Turkey are operating as a whole under conditions of monopolistic
competition. Moreover, we observed that market power resulting from high
concentration levels in Turkey does not exclude competitive behavior.
This suggests that the degree of competition in banking was affected by
different factors for differences.
We found that Turkish banks, which operate in more monopolistic
environments, are also less efficient; however the banks were able to
achieve high records of profitability in monopolistically competitive
markets. The banks with small capital base were not able to operate
better in competitive market. Henceforth we conclude that due to high
concentration in the Turkish banking system in the last decade, the
market power for the leading firms has reduced.
References
Aktan, B.; Teker, E.; Ersoy, P. 2009a. Changing face of banks and
the evaluation of internet banking in Turkey, Journal of Internet
Banking and Commerce 14(1): 1-11.
Aktan, B.; Masood, O.; Yilmaz, S. 2009b. Financial shenanigans and
the failure of ethics in banking: a review and synthesis of an
unprecedented fraud, Banks and Bank Systems 4(1): 31-37.
Alper, C. E.; Onis, E. 2002. Soft budget constraints, government
ownership of banks and regulatory failure: the political economy of the
Turkish banking system in the post-capital account liberalization era,
Bosphorus University, Economic Departmental Working Paper, No. 02/2002,
Istanbul, Turkey, February 2002.
Barth, J.; Caprio, G.; Levine, R. 2007. The regulation and
supervision of banks around the world: a new database, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper, No. WPS 2588.
BAT 2008. Banks, Branches and Employes. Statistical Reports,
December 2008. The Banks Association of Turkey (BAT) [online] [cited 3
February 2009]. Available from Internet: <www.tbb.org.tr>.
BRSA 2009. Monthly Bulletin, Year 5, No. 46, February.
Baumol, W. J.; Panzar, J. C.; Willig, R. D. 1982. Contestable
Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich,
Inc., New York.
Berger, A. N.; Bonime, S. D.; Covitz, M. D.; Hancock, D. 2000. Why
are bank profits so persistent? The roles of product market competition,
information opacity and regional macroeconomic shocks, Journal of
Banking and Finance 24(7): 1203-1235. doi:10.1016/S0378-4266(99)00124-7
Bikker, J. A.; Haaf, K. 2002. Competition, concentration and their
relationship: an empirical analysis of the banking industry, Journal of
Banking & Finance 26(11): 2191-2214.
doi:10.1016/S0378-4266(02)00205-4
Blaug, M. 1980. The Methodology of Economics. Cambridge UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Bresnahan, T. F. 1982. The oligopoly solution identified, Economics
Letters 10(1-2): 87-92. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(82)90121-5
Carbo-Valverde, S.; Rodriguez-Fernandez, F.; Udell, G. F. 2009.
Bank market power and SME financing constraints, Review of Finance
13(2): 309-340. doi:10.1093/rof/rfp003
Casu, B.; Girardone, C. 2006. Bank competition, concentration and
efficiency in the single European market, The Manchester School 74(4):
441-468. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9957.2006.00503.x
Celik, T.; Urunveren, C. 2009. Yabanci banka giris,lerinin tiirk
bankacilik sektorune rekabet etkisi 2002-2007, Nigde University, Journal
of Economics & Administrative Sciences 2: 42-59 (in Turkish).
Claessens, S.; Laeven, L. 2004. What drives bank competition? Some
international evidence, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36(2):
563-584. doi:10.1353/mcb.2004.0044
De Bandt, O.; Davis, E. P. 2000. Competition, contestability and
market structure in European banking sectors on the eve of the EMU,
Journal of Banking & Finance 24(6): 1045-1066.
doi:10.1016/S0378-4266(99)00117-X
Freixas, X.; Rochet, J. C. 1997. Microeconomics of Banking. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Gelos, G.; Roldos, J. 2004. Consolidation and market structure in
emerging market banking systems, Emerging Markets Review 5(1): 39-59.
doi:10.1016/j.ememar.2003.12.002
Ginevicius, R.; Cirba, S. 2007. Determining market concentration,
Journal of Business Economics and Management 8(1): 3-10.
Ginevicius, R.; Cirba, S. 2009. Additive measurement of market
concentration, Journal of Business Economics and Management 10(3):
191-198. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.191-198
Goddard, J.; Molyneux, P.; Wilson, J. O. S. 2004a. Dynamics of
growth and profitability in banking, Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking 36: 1069-1090. doi:10.1353/mcb.2005.0015
Goddard, J.; Molyneux, P.; Wilson, J. O. S. 2004b. The
profitability of European banks: a crosssectional and dynamic panel
analysis, The Manchester School 72: 363-381.
doi:10.1111/j.1467-9957.2004.00397.x
Gunalp, B.; Celik, T. 2006. Competition in the Turkish Banking
Industry, Applied Economics 38: 1335-1342. doi:10.1080/00036840500405656
Hondroyiannis, G.; Lolos, S.; Papapetrou, E. 1999. Assessing
competitive conditions in the Greek Banking System, Journal of
International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 9(4): 377391.
doi:10.1016/S1042-4431(99)00017-7
Honohan, P. 1997. Banking system failures in developing and
transition countries: diagnosis and prediction, BIS Economic Papers No.
39, January.
Kasman, A. 2001. Competitive conditions in the Turkish banking
industry, Ege Academic Review 1(2): 72-82.
Lau, L. 1982. On identifying the degree of competitiveness from
industry, price and output data, Economics Letters 10(1-2): 93-99.
doi:10.1016/0165-1765(82)90122-7
Masood, O.; Aktan, B. 2010. Market structure and competitive
conditions of banking industry in KSA: The Panzar-Rosse approach, Actual
Problems of Economics, January 1(103): 263-276.
Matthews, K.; Murinde, V.; Zhao, T. 2007. Competitive conditions
among the major British banks, Journal of Banking & Finance 31(7):
2025-2042. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.11.009
Molyneux, P.; Thornton, J.; Lloyd-Williams, M. D. 1996. Competition
and market contestability in Japanese commercial banking, Journal of
Economics and Business 48(1): 33-45. doi:10.1016/0148-6195(95)00047-X
Molyneux, P.; Lloyd-Williams, M. D.; Thornton, J. 1994. Competitive
conditions in European banking, Journal of Banking & Finance 18(3):
445-4 59.
Nathan, A.; Neave, E. 1989. Competition and contestabilty in
Canada's financial system: empirical results, The Canadian Journal
of Economics 22: 576-594. doi:10.2307/135541
Panzar, J.; Rosse, J. 1987. Testing for monopoly equilibrium,
Journal of Industrial Economics 35: 443-456.
Panzar, J.; Rosse, J. 1982. Structure, conduct and comparative
statistics, Bell Laboratories Economic Discussion Paper No. 248.
doi:10.2307/2098582
Perrakis, S. 1991. Assessing competition in Canada's financial
system: A Note, The Canadian Journal of Economics 22(3): 727-732.
Rosse, J. N.; Panzar, J. C. 1977. Chamberlin Versus Robinson: An
Empirical Test for Monopoly Rents. Research Papers No 77. Stanford
University, Stanford California.
Schumpeter, J. A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. London:
George Allen and Unwin.
Shaffer, S. 2004. Comment on 'what drives bank competition?
some international evidence' by Stijin Claessens and Luc Laeven,
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36: 585-592.
doi:10.1353/mcb.2004.0050
Shaffer, S. 1994. Bank competition in concentrated markets,
Business Review March/April: 3-16.
Shaffer, S. 1983. Non-structural measures of competition: toward a
synthesis of alternatives, Economics Letters 12(3-4): 349-353.
doi:10.1016/0165-1765(83)90061-7
Shaffer, S. 1982. A non-structural test for competition in
financial markets, in Proceedings of the 20th Conference on Bank
Structure and Competition Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 225-243.
Staikouras, C.; Koutsomanoli-Fillipaki, A. 2006. Competition and
concentration in the New European banking landscape, European Financial
Management 12(3): 443-482. doi:10.1111/j.1354-7798.2006.00327.x
Turk-Ariss, R. 2009. Competitive behavior in Middle East and North
Africa banking systems, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance
49(2): 693-710. doi:10.1016/j.qref.2008.03.002
Uchida, H.; Tsutsui, Y. 2005. Has competition in the Japanese
banking sector improved? Journal of Banking & Finance 29(2):
419-439. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.05.013
Yeyati, L. E.; Micco, A. 2007. Concentration and foreign
penetration in Latin American banking sectors: impact on competition and
risk, Journal of Banking & Finance 31(6): 1633-1647.
doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.11.003
Yildirim, H. S.; Philippatos, G. C. 2007a. Restructuring,
consolidation and competition in Latin American banking markets, Journal
of Banking & Finance 31(3): 629-639.
doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.06.008
Yildirim, H. S.; Philippatos, G. C. 2007b. Competition and
contestability in Central and Eastern European banking markets,
Managerial Finance 33(3): 195-209. doi:10.1108/03074350710718275
Yuan, Y. 2006. The state of competition of the Chinese banking
industry, Journal of Asian Economics 17(3): 519-534.
doi:10.1016/j.asieco.2006.05.001
Bora Aktan* (1), Omar Masood (2)
(1) Yasar University, Faculty of Economics and Administrative
Sciences, Finance Department, Selcuk Yasar Campus, 35100, Izmir, Turkey
(2) University of East London Business School, Docklands Campus,
University Way, E16 2RD, United Kingdom. E-mail: (1)
[email protected], (2)
[email protected]
Received 3 February 2009; accepted 20 January 2010
* Corresponding Author
(1) In previous studies regarding market concentration, competition
has been measured by using Concentration indices such as the Herfindahl
index (see for a broad discussion Ginevicius and Cirba 2007, 2009).
(2) For a discussion of the theoretical literature see, Freixas and
Rochet (1997).
(3) Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey FX buying rates are used
for conversion as of 31 December 2008.
Bora AKTAN is an Assistant Professor of Finance and Deputy Chair of
International Trade and Finance Department at Yasar University, Faculty
of Economics and Administrative Sciences. Prior to joining the Yasar
University, Dr. Aktan worked as both Corporate Strategy and Business
Development Director in international firms largely active in Mexico,
England and Turkey. Dr. Aktan's current research activity focuses
on global investing, financial characteristics and performance of firms
in emerging countries, emerging capital markets, energy price
volatility, and risk-return trade-off in asset prices, corporate
governance and business ethics. He has published in different refereed
journals such as Journal of Business Economics and Management,
International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, Investment
Management and Financial Innovations, Journal of Property Investment and
Finance. He is member of some professional bodies such as The
International Institute of Forecasters (IIF), The American Finance
Association (AFA), The Society for Financial Econometrics (SoFIE) and
the Financial Management Association (FMA). Dr Aktan is also on the
editorial boards of several international scholarly journals such as
Qualitative Research in Financial Markets, Journal of Applied Sciences,
Asian Journal of Mathematics and Statistics, Journal of Artificial
Intelligence, Academy of Banking Studies Journal, among others. In
addition, he serves as a board member of Economics and Financial Affairs
Committee for the Aegean Region Chamber of Industry.
Omar MASOOD is the Subject leader of banking and finance group at
the University of East London. Studied Economics and accounts as a first
degree, followed by a MBA in Finance, TLHEP Degree in Teaching Higher
Learning Education Program (TLHEP & SEDA), and PhD in Risk
Management in banking. Dr. Masood has worked as a consultant with the
World Bank and as a strategic fund analyst to several banks and other
multi-national companies. His research interests include issues related
to fund management, banking crisis, behavioural finance, Islamic
banking, political risk and international finance. He is the author of a
number of research papers which have been published in international
journals and conferences. Currently working on several funded projects
relating risk and financial management. Also leading a team working for
advising HSBC on their fund and risk management issues. Having
successfully led teams at both UBS and Goldman Sachs.
doi: 10.3846/jbem.2010.07
Table 1. The theory and interpretation of the Panzar-Rosse H statistic
Equilibrium Test
E = 0 Equilibrium
E < 0 Disequilibrium
Competitive Conditions Test
H [less than or equal to] 0 Monopoly or conjectural variations short
run oligopoly
H = 1 Perfect competition or natural monopoly in
a perfectly contestable market or sales
maximizing firm subject to a break even
constraint
0< H <1 Monopolistic competition
Table 2. Equilibrium test results for Turkish
banks for 1998-2008
(Depended variable--lnROA)
Coefficients Turkey
ln[W.sub.L] 0.035 (0.081)
ln[W.sub.F] 0.136 (0.066)
ln[W.sub.K] 0.054 (0.041)
ln[Y.sub.1] 0.026 (0.017) **
ln[Y.sub.2] 0.071 (0.042)
ln[Y.sub.3] 0.011 (0.024)
[R.sub.2] 0.59
E-statistic -0.048 (0.08)
equilibrium E=0 Fail to Reject ***
Notes: *** and ** denotes that the values are significant
at 10% level and 5% level respectively
Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses
Table 3. Competitive conditions test results
for Turkish banks for 1998-2008
(Depended variable--lnTR)
Coefficients Turkey
ln[W.sub.L] 0.38 (0.085) ***
ln[W.sub.F] 0.331 (0.049) ***
ln[W.sub.K] 0.069 (0.017) **
ln[Y.sub.1] 0.044 (0.053)
ln[Y.sub.2] -0.009 (0.069)
ln[Y.sub.3] 0.018 (0.029)
[R.sub.2] 0.79
PR H-statistic 0.753 (0.098)
Monopoly H=0 Reject ***
Perft. Comp. H=1 Fail to Reject ***
Notes: ***and **denotes that the values are significant
at 10% level and 5% level respectively
Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses
Table 4. Description of variables which affect degree of competition
Variable Name Description
H-statistic Panzar and Rosse (1987) H-statistic calculated for
Turkey over the sample period 1998-2008.
Efficiency Ratio of non-interest expense to the sum of net
interest income and non-interest revenues. A
higher ratio indicates lower efficiency.
Profitability Return on assets (the ratio of net income to total
assets) and return on equity (the ratio of net
income to total equity).
Capitalization Ratio of equity to total assets.
Concentration A measure of the degree of concentration in the
banking industry, calculated as the fraction of
deposits held by the largest three commercial
banks in Turkey.
Foreign Ownership Fraction of the banking system's assets that is in
banks that are 50% or more foreign owned as of x
banks that are 50%
Source: Barth et al. (2007), Economist Intelligence Unit Country
Profiles and Turk-Ariss (2009).
Table 5. Regression results on the data
Variable Panel A: Yearly H-Statistic
Model-1 Model-2 Model-3
Efficiency -0.1886 -0.7659
(0.2871) ** (0.2304) **
Profitability 0.3123 0.2893
(0.2983) ** (0.0271) *
Capitalization 3.9283 2.8388
(1.2739) ** (1.1232) *
Concentration -0.1024 -0.1726
(0.2623) * (0.3401)
F. O. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Constant -0.2891 0.1193 0.6767
(0.5418) (0.4295) (0.6534)
Variable Panel B: Overall H-Statistic
Model-1 Model-2 Model-3
Efficiency -0.2656 -1.9673
(0.2159) ** (0.3573) *
Profitability 0.6527 0.5362
(0.4054) (0.0098) *
Capitalization 0.3218 -0.2783
(0.5451) * (0.8762)
Concentration -0.0889 0.6873
(0.4958) * (0.2157) *
F. O. n.a. n.a. n.a.
Constant 0.7749 0.0947 0.0215
(0.7863) (0.5874) (0.6019)
Notes: ***, ** and * denotes that the values are significant at 10%
level, 5% level and 1% respectively Robust standard errors are
reported in parentheses F.0.--Foreign Ownership