首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月03日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Coalition or decentralization: a game-theoretic analysis of a three-echelon supply chain network.
  • 作者:Mahdiraji, Hannan Amoozad ; Govindan, Kannan ; Zavadskas, Edmundas Kazimieras
  • 期刊名称:Journal of Business Economics and Management
  • 印刷版ISSN:1611-1699
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:June
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Vilnius Gediminas Technical University
  • 摘要:More than 50 years ago, Forrester (1958) introduced the elements of a theory that today is called supply chain management (SCM). The concept of the supply chain means that many experts believe that competition is transferred from companies to chains. SCM is extensive enough, and therefore large international corporations such as Cisco, Dell Computer, Gillette, Kodak, LEGO, Motorola, Sony, 3M, Xerox and Wal-Mart implemented it in the past decade. Moreover, international consultancy firms like IDM business Consulting Services, A.T. Kearney, Cap Gemini, etc. have adopted SCM as an important business area. Also, a large number of universities and business schools have included SCM courses in their curricula. Many scholars and experts gave different definitions for SCM that depend on their viewpoints and attitudes (Walker 2005). The role and importance of supply chain management have faced a number of challenges and problems. Although a comprehensive model dealing with the issues of the supply chain has not been explained, we have to indicate that questions such as reviewing the theoretical foundations of information systems, marketing, financial management, logistical and organizational relations have been considered by many researchers (Wang et al. 2007). There are many challenges that latent in the concept of the supply chain. The decisions made in SCM are mainly about the flows between chain stages. Therefore, many scholars express challenges and problems, and SCM have tried to answer them (Chandra, Kamrani 2004; Chopra, Miendel 2007; Simchi-Levi et al. 2004; Wisner et al. 2008). The objective of supply chain management is to improve various activities and components to increase the overall benefits of the supply chain system. Many decisions are made at a different level of the supply chain, which includes detailed and strategic decisions. Planning important decisions in a multi-echelon supply chain will affect all levels and the SC as a whole (Stadtler, Kilger 2007). If each level of the supply chain makes their inventory, the decision on pricing and advertising without considering other levels as well as the bullwhip effect will occur and the advantage of supply chain competiveness decrease (Lee et al. 1997). Between the components and different levels of the supply chain, in order to achieve the overall objectives, many contradictions may occur, including that these disorders, over time, may result in the decreased strength and competitiveness of the supply chain. Such conflicts, like marketing costs (advertising), pricing and inventory decisions can occur during the life cycle of the supply chain. For avoiding such loss in the SC, many coordination mechanisms have been introduced in recent researches. There are many possible interactive coordination mechanisms that can occur between different levels (Esmaeili et al. 2008). A large part of these mechanisms are based on a game theory approach. The game theory is concerned with the actions of decision makers who are conscious that their actions affect each other. The game theory approach is an appropriate tool for collaboration in the supply chain. Beside contradiction with decision variables, different levels of the supply chain may decide on acting independently or, in some cases, trying to integrate with some other levels for gaining more advantages. In this case, the main challenge is how to act in multi-echelon supply chains taking into account the levels involved. Making a choice independently or integrating with some or all levels will be a critical decision, and therefore affects the overall profit of the chain. This decision will have an influence on prices, inventory, lot sizes and costs which will finally change the overall profit of the supply chain. For solving this problem and finding a suitable answer, a three- echelon unlimited supply chain with S suppliers, M manufacturers and K retailers has been considered. In addition, decisions on pricing, inventory and advertising are included as three main decision variables in the proposed models. By using the definition of the Nash equilibrium for continuous problems, the best responses for each level of the supply chain in decentralization and integration situations are identified and used in a simulated supply chain. By comparing the obtained results, the best decisions are illustrated. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, supply chain management, the game theory and the Nash equilibrium are introduced and the classification of researches on similar topics is illustrated. Next, the assumptions and notations of our proposed models are presented and the payoff functions of each player in all situations (integration or decentralization) are designed. After, the best response of each player is calculated. Finally, by using the proposed models in the simulated SC, the results are compared and the final conclusion is proposed.
  • 关键词:Business logistics;Decision making;Decision-making;Logistics

Coalition or decentralization: a game-theoretic analysis of a three-echelon supply chain network.


Mahdiraji, Hannan Amoozad ; Govindan, Kannan ; Zavadskas, Edmundas Kazimieras 等


Introduction

More than 50 years ago, Forrester (1958) introduced the elements of a theory that today is called supply chain management (SCM). The concept of the supply chain means that many experts believe that competition is transferred from companies to chains. SCM is extensive enough, and therefore large international corporations such as Cisco, Dell Computer, Gillette, Kodak, LEGO, Motorola, Sony, 3M, Xerox and Wal-Mart implemented it in the past decade. Moreover, international consultancy firms like IDM business Consulting Services, A.T. Kearney, Cap Gemini, etc. have adopted SCM as an important business area. Also, a large number of universities and business schools have included SCM courses in their curricula. Many scholars and experts gave different definitions for SCM that depend on their viewpoints and attitudes (Walker 2005). The role and importance of supply chain management have faced a number of challenges and problems. Although a comprehensive model dealing with the issues of the supply chain has not been explained, we have to indicate that questions such as reviewing the theoretical foundations of information systems, marketing, financial management, logistical and organizational relations have been considered by many researchers (Wang et al. 2007). There are many challenges that latent in the concept of the supply chain. The decisions made in SCM are mainly about the flows between chain stages. Therefore, many scholars express challenges and problems, and SCM have tried to answer them (Chandra, Kamrani 2004; Chopra, Miendel 2007; Simchi-Levi et al. 2004; Wisner et al. 2008). The objective of supply chain management is to improve various activities and components to increase the overall benefits of the supply chain system. Many decisions are made at a different level of the supply chain, which includes detailed and strategic decisions. Planning important decisions in a multi-echelon supply chain will affect all levels and the SC as a whole (Stadtler, Kilger 2007). If each level of the supply chain makes their inventory, the decision on pricing and advertising without considering other levels as well as the bullwhip effect will occur and the advantage of supply chain competiveness decrease (Lee et al. 1997). Between the components and different levels of the supply chain, in order to achieve the overall objectives, many contradictions may occur, including that these disorders, over time, may result in the decreased strength and competitiveness of the supply chain. Such conflicts, like marketing costs (advertising), pricing and inventory decisions can occur during the life cycle of the supply chain. For avoiding such loss in the SC, many coordination mechanisms have been introduced in recent researches. There are many possible interactive coordination mechanisms that can occur between different levels (Esmaeili et al. 2008). A large part of these mechanisms are based on a game theory approach. The game theory is concerned with the actions of decision makers who are conscious that their actions affect each other. The game theory approach is an appropriate tool for collaboration in the supply chain. Beside contradiction with decision variables, different levels of the supply chain may decide on acting independently or, in some cases, trying to integrate with some other levels for gaining more advantages. In this case, the main challenge is how to act in multi-echelon supply chains taking into account the levels involved. Making a choice independently or integrating with some or all levels will be a critical decision, and therefore affects the overall profit of the chain. This decision will have an influence on prices, inventory, lot sizes and costs which will finally change the overall profit of the supply chain. For solving this problem and finding a suitable answer, a three- echelon unlimited supply chain with S suppliers, M manufacturers and K retailers has been considered. In addition, decisions on pricing, inventory and advertising are included as three main decision variables in the proposed models. By using the definition of the Nash equilibrium for continuous problems, the best responses for each level of the supply chain in decentralization and integration situations are identified and used in a simulated supply chain. By comparing the obtained results, the best decisions are illustrated. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, supply chain management, the game theory and the Nash equilibrium are introduced and the classification of researches on similar topics is illustrated. Next, the assumptions and notations of our proposed models are presented and the payoff functions of each player in all situations (integration or decentralization) are designed. After, the best response of each player is calculated. Finally, by using the proposed models in the simulated SC, the results are compared and the final conclusion is proposed.

1. Literature review

This section includes the basics and concepts of the game theory, different types of coordination contracts and reviews similar researches. As a definition, the supply chain consists of all parties involved, directly, or indirectly, in fulfilling a customer request (Chopra, Meindel 2007) and mentioning all activities performed until a raw material is delivered as the final good to a customer (Gumus, Guneri 2007). These activities and functions include new product development, marketing, operations, distributions, financing and customer services. A typical supply chain may involve a variety of stages such as customers, retailers, wholesalers, distributors, manufacturers and raw material suppliers (Chopra, Meindel 2007). Between the components and different levels of the supply chain, in order to achieve the overall objectives, many contradictions may occur, the contradictions that these disorders take place over time result in the decreased strength and competitiveness of the supply chain. One of the main tools for solving the problem in the before mentioned situation are the game theory approach. The essential elements of the game are players, actions, payoffs and information (Chen 2009). These are collectively known as the rules of the game, and the objective of the modeller is to describe the situation in terms of the rules of the game so as to explain what will happen in that situation. Trying to maximize their payoffs, the players will devise plans known as strategies that pick actions depending on the information that has arrived at each moment. The combination of strategies chosen by each player is known as equilibrium while given which modeller can see what actions come out of the conjunction of all players' plans, which tells him the outcome of the game.

While information transaction is not possible between different players (different layers of the SC), in such situations and by considering the Nash definition, each player will stimulate competitor believes or best responses, and, when these believes are correct, the Nash equilibrium will occur (Osborne 2004). In the given two-player game, the best responses are defined as (1):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (1)

where [B.sub.i] stands for the best response for player i, ([S.sub.i], [S.sub.-i])--for the strategy chosen by player i & -i, (i-i)--for two players of the game, ([S.sup.*.sub.i],[S.sup.*.sub.-1] for the best strategies for players, [U.sub.i] ([S.sub.i], [S.sub.-i])--for utility or payoff when players choose ([S.sub.i], [S.sub.-i]) as their final decisions. By considering the definition of the best response and continuous and discrete payoff functions, the Nash equilibrium is computable by the derivation of utility or the payoff function of each player regarding a specific decision variable. The Nash game, definition and equilibrium are used in famous situations such as the Bertrand duopoly model, Cornet model of duopoly, the final offer arbitration and the problem of commons (Gibbons 2002).

Game theoretic analysis for supply chain networks includes a wide range of research. Some scientists have focused on the use of the Nash equilibrium in supply chain coordination by applying a profit sharing contract (Feng et al. 2007; Jiazhen, Qin 2008; Feng 2008; Ying et al. 2007; Jaber et al. 2006; Bai, Wang 2008; Xu, Zhong 2011; Liu, Zhang 2006; Wang et al. 2009). The other contracts of supply chain coordination are presented in Table 1 (Govindan, Nicoleta 2011).

Besides using coordination contracts, Nash and Stackelberg games also can be used for coordinating the SC in complete situations with a determined demand function (Leng, Parlar 2010; Arda, Hennet 2005). Besides, Zandi et al. (2012) proposed a strategic theoretic approach of a cooperative game to market segmentation. For a symmetric supply chain, some researchers gave closed-form expressions of unique equilibrium (Adida, Demiguel 2011). In addition, equilibrium for the Shapley value and Eliasberg model for coordination and cooperation problems in the SC are performable (Zhao et al. 2010; Leng, Zhu 2009). In some cases, while incomplete information on decisions and payoffs dominate game conditions, Bayesian--Nash Games are used (Wang, Zhao 2009; Cachon, Lariviere 1999). Other optimization tools such as the queuing theory, a Markov chain, backward induction, stochastic programming and a genetic algorithm for solving coordination and cooperation problems in the supply chain, mostly in the situations of incomplete information games, are also performable (Cachon, Kok 2010; Hennet, Arda 2008; Stein, Ginevicius 2010; Kaviani et al. 2011; Gupta, Weerawat 2006).

Considering uncertainty in the game theory approach to solving different dilemmas is really noticeable, which eventuates to multi-criteria decision making (MCDM) or multi-objective decision making (MODM) usage in the game theory. Therefore, in 2005, Peldschus and Zavadskas proposed a Fuzzy matrix game by multi-criteria modelling of decision making in engineering projects (Peldschus, Zavadskas 2005). Three years later, a new logarithmic normalization method in the game theory was suggested (Zavadskas, Turskis 2008). Same time after, an overview of MCDM methods and its application to economics based on the game theory was figured by the same authors (Zavadskas, Turskis 2011). Recent findings have illustrated the application of the MODM and game theory approach where Peldschus and Zavadskas proposed an equilibrium approach to construction processes by multi-objective decision making for construction projects (Peldschus, Zavadskas 2012). As some of the aforementioned researches indicate, in practice, the application of the game theory in the fields of engineering and construction has further developed (Zavadskas et al. 2004; Peldschus 2008; Kaplinski, Tamosaitiene 2010; Peldschus et al. 2010).

This research mainly considers the use and application of the game theory, especially non-cooperative Nash games, in supply chain management. In Nash games, all levels of the SC or each player in the game act simultaneously with complete information about the game, players and equal power. Most of the games used in the SC are non-repetitive, with two or finally three levels and limited to one or finally two members at each level. Inventory, pricing and marketing policies are included in researches. Our paper reflects on inventory with shortage (backlog), incremental production, a nonlinear cost production function for the manufacturer, a nonlinear demand function, semi integrated (coalition) games and an unlimited supply chain, which differs this research from others.

2. Basic model

A three-echelon supply network made of K retailers, M manufacturers and S upstream suppliers where K [greater than or equal to] 1, M [greater than or equal to] 1, S [greater than or equal to] 1, (Fig. 1) has been considered. This network produces, distributes and sells multiple products to the end customers (i.e. consumers):

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

In this supply network, we assume that all agents are able to decide independently or, in some cases, integrate with the agents of other levels of the network. The network follows a make-to-order pull system in which orders first pass from retailers to manufacturers, and then from manufacturers to suppliers. We assume that all agents have complete information. In addition, shortages (and hence stock out) are allowed for manufacturers. The cost of shortages will be considered for the manufacturer during a shortage period, but no shortage is assumed for retailers and suppliers. Consumer demand for the product depends on both the retail price and marketing cost used for product advertisement. Following literature (Lee 1993, Esmaeili et al. 2008; Jia et al. 2013), we acknowledge a deterministic non-linear form of a consumer demand function as given by (2):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (2)

where [D.sub.n] presents demand for product [sub.n], [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] denotes the selling price of product n by retailer [sub.[gamma]], [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] points to marketing cost for product [sub.n, k a, b,], are all strictly positive constants to represent the corresponding coefficient in the demand function.

The total inventory cost of each manufacturer includes its shortage cost and inventory holding cost and it is computable by (3), in which [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] stands for holding cost estimated by the manufacturer, ([[gamma].sub.n] = 1 - [D.sub.n]/[PC.sub.n]) denotes production rate, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is production quantity, [B.sub.n] represents manufacturer's shortage, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is the cost of manufacturer's shortage, [PC.sub.n] is production capacity provided by the manufacturer (Jia et al. 2013):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (3)

Notice that the model presented in (3) follows literature (Oganezov 2006; Wang, Tang 2009; Chakrabortty et al. 2010; Chang 2008; Pentico et al. 2009; Jia et al. 2013).

As a remark, the final retail selling price and retail marketing cost, production quantity and shortage quantity, besides the mass production price for the manufacturer, and finally the raw material price for suppliers are the main decision variables of this research. The cost of unit production is nonlinear function [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] decreasing in demand and having coefficients u > 0, [gamma] > 0 (Bazaraa et al. 1993). Regarding this supply network, the scenario when each manufacturer supplies only a specific product to a specific retailer n = r = m is considered. However, upstream suppliers sell their raw materials to any manufacturer when needed. This matches the scenario in many industries such as fashion apparel in which many retailers (fashion retail brands) have designed garment factories (manufacturers) to produce solely for them while since there are relatively few upstream suppliers (for fabrics or components such as zippers) in the market, most manufacturers will source from the well-established ones (e.g. YKK is the zipper supplier to all kinds of manufacturers and all kinds of retail brands). Following the standard norm discussed in literature, we assume, throughout this paper, that each player at any level of the supply network is fully rational. To enhance the presentation, the notation employed in Table 2 of this paper is summarized.

3. Modelling/payoff functions

This section presents the analytical payoff function for each agent of the supply network. Two different approaches are considered. First, trio players, including suppliers, manufacturers and retailers, decide independently without any coordination approach. Second, two parts of the SC merge each other and act as one player to confront the demonstration of the third party. In both approaches, mathematical models are illustrated and the best responses of each player are calculated based on the Nash equilibrium.

3.1. The payoff function and model of the retailer

For retailer r, it confronts holding and setup costs as well as purchasing cost from getting supply from the manufacturer. In addition, any retailer should have a positive margin to participate in the supply network. The income of each retailer involves revenue achieved by selling the final goods to the final customer. Considering the details above, the payoff function of the retailer and a related optimization model are shown in (4) (Jaafarnejad et al. 2012; Jia et al. 2013):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (4)

where the first constraint implies that the final retail selling price is greater than the wholesale price paid to the manufacturer, and the second and third constraints guarantee that demand should not be negative or greater than production capacity. Decision variables associated with (4) in the supply network include [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

3.2. The payoff function and model of the manufacturer

Manufacturer n confronts holding, setup, ordering and shortage costs, purchasing cost and production cost. The manufacturer receives revenue with the wholesale price. The payoff function of manufacturers and model constraints are shown in (5) where the first constraint implies that the wholesale price offered by the manufacturer to the retailer is greater than that paid for raw materials and where the second and third constraints ensure that demand should not be negative or greater than the available production capacity (Jia et al. 2013).

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)

3.3. The payoff function and model of the supplier

A supplier has to bear holding, setup and purchasing costs. In return, every supplier will gain revenue by selling raw materials to manufacturers, and the total revenue depends on the amount of respective production used by the manufacturer. By considering the above indicated points, the payoff function of the supplier and its constraints are shown in (6), where the first constraint implies that the selling price of the raw material to the manufacturer should be greater than the procurement cost of acquiring the raw material by the supplier, and the second constraint guarantees that demand should not be negative (Jaafarnejad et al. 2012; Jia et al. 2013):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)

3.4. Channel integration

This section proposes that two levels of the SC make a joint venture to confront the leadership of the third party. We have considered two integration scenarios: manufacturer-retailer and supplier-manufacturer. In the first case, inventory/holding cost issues diminish to a single warehouse and the retailer does not have to enforce marketing effort any more. The second one brings similar benefits. Under each scenario, all parties involved simultaneously set their strategies.

3.4.1. Integration function (M-R Nash game) of the manufacturer--retailer

Our research is aimed at finding the best way of two-agent integration in the supply network to achieve the Nash equilibrium with the largest profit. As a remark, it is known that strategic partnership in a supply chain is most easily achievable and commonly seen in the case between two agents. Multi-agent integration (more than two) is relatively rare and usually done by involving a third part supply chain coordinator. In this paper, we confine ourselves to two-agent integration as commonly observed in the real world and assumed in the mainstream literature.

To achieve this goal, under our analysis, three options are possible for the three-echelon supply network: manufacturer- retailer integration (MR), supplier--manufacturer integration (SM) and supplier--retailer integration (SR). The purpose of this paper is to find the best integration mode among these three.

By vertically integrating manufacturers with retailers, the number of manufacturers is equal to the number of retailers, and the revenue of the MR pair will be the revenue generated by the retail selling price for the product sold. The incurred costs will include production costs, shortage costs, setup costs and holding costs. We have to notice that holding cost at this level includes one warehouse between manufacturers and retailers. In addition, marketing cost will not occur while manufacturers and retailers are bonded, because these two members are vertically integrated and simply controlled by one level in a centralized manner. A remark that marketing in our research is based on the costs the retailer spends to sell product n of the related manufacturer can be made. These costs, for example, include allocating a suitable stage in a retailer's shop for representing the product. However, when M and R integrate, this item will be eliminated because they act as one. Mathematically, if we make the integrated function of M and R, marketing cost write-off from the equation. By considering the above rules, the final payoff function of the MR Player is described as (7):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (7)

Decision variables for this function are [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and constraints insist that demand should not be negative. The objective function maximizes the manufacturer and retailer when both act as one player. In this case, the overall income from selling the final product to costumers should be maximized while production, holding, stock out and purchasing costs should be minimized. As they act as one player, only a single warehouse is considered and shared by both for the final products.

3.4.2. Integration function (S-M Nash game) of the supplier--manufacturer

While suppliers and manufacturers are integrating, their coalition will affect their costs and benefits. In this situation, the only income will supply from the mass price from manufacturers to retailers. On the other hand, the costs of a new integrated level will include production costs, shortage costs, setup costs and holding costs. By considering the above rules, the final payoff function for the MR Player is described as (8):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (8)

Decision variables for this function are [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and constraints insist that demand should not be negative. The objective function maximizes the manufacturer and supplier when both act as one player. In this case, the overall income from the selling product to retailers should be maximized while production, holding, stock out and purchasing costs should be minimized.

3.5. Best responses

Based on the Nash definition of equilibrium, the best responses of each player should be estimated by others. As the objective function of each player is a nonlinear mathematical model, the best responses of each player, due to its decision variable, are calculated by partial differentiation and the first derivative. By considering the best response definition, continuous and discrete payoff functions, Nash equilibrium N(G) is computable by the derivation of utility or the payoff function of each player [U.sub.i] ([S.sub.i], [S.sub.-i]) = f ([S.sub.i], [S.sub.-i]) regarding a specific decision variable. The best response for the discrete function is calculated by (9) and that for continuous payoff functions is illustrated in (10) (Rasmusen 2005):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (10)

3.5.1. Best responses for the decentralized game

Each player in three-level supply chains will make the best decision when playing a game in the SC, i.e. they move simultaneously and there is no Stackelberg leader. Make a remark that our research is based on non-cooperative game situations; thus, in the game theory, orders and demand follow the pull system, but pricing and other agreements may not. For example, in Stackelberg games, leadership could happen at any level of the SC, which contradicts the pull system. The game theory is a pre-action approach and leads the players to order a quantity which maximizes their and other levels. While SC information and the demand function are completely accessible, any level enables to model the SC profit function and make the best decision. By considering the reasonable behaviour of each player and the Nash best response principle, the best decisions on each player in the three-echelon SC will be concluded by the derivation of the payoff function to decision variables. The first order condition of each payoff function is used for the best response, and the second condition is applied for concavity analysis. By calculating the determinant of the Hessian matrix of each player and with regard to its decision variables, it has been concluded that all models are concave to their decision variables, and therefore optimal solutions to the proposed models are definable. Table 3 represents the best response of each player if the Nash principle is used by calculating the first order condition of the payoff functions of each player regarding their decision variables. The details of the results presented in the table are mentioned in Appendixes 1 to 3.

[TABLE 3 OMITTED]

3.5.2. Best MR responses

In this situation, two players or two levels of the supply chain are considered, i.e. suppliers and the MR level. Suppliers are similar to the decentralized model with the same best response. For a MR Player (it is assumed that MR becomes one unit), by a change in the payoff function, the best responses will vary as (17). We have to mention that integration affects the relation between manufacturers and retailers; hence, mass price from the manufacturer to the retailer as well as marketing cost will be eliminated from the final results: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (17)

3.5.3. Best SM responses

In this case, two players or two levels of the supply chain are taken into account, i.e. retailers and the SM level. Retailers are similar to the decentralized model with the same best response. For a SM Player, by a change in the payoff function, the best responses will vary as (18). We have to mention that integration affects the relation between manufacturers and suppliers, and therefore mass price from the supplier to the manufacturer will be eliminated from the final results. In all situations, the demand function and production rate equality always affect the obtained results:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (18)

4. Numerical example

With reference to the methodology of our research and to the evaluated results, the verification and validation of the investigated outputs have been analysed applying to a numerical example of a hypothetical supply chain. Due to a lack of numerical and historical information, the design of the experimental approach has been performed to produce suitable data. Each experiment has been assessed by the proposed models, and the total profit of the SC has bred out based on coalition or decentralization circumstances. Following sensitivity analysis, the overall SC profits of each method have been compared, and finally, an appropriate approach has been suggested. Through a numerical experiment, 17 design cases (through the performance of experiments) have been developed, and the total profit of the supply chain under each scenario has been evaluated. Statistical tests on the conducted 17 experiments have disclosed that the decentralized system performs significantly worse than the integration of the supplier with the manufacturer, whereas no significant difference in other combinations can be observed. Jia et al. (2013) used the same numerical example based on the Stackelberg game. They considered and compared three types of leadership and concluded that retailer leadership would beget the highest profit for the supply chain. Regarding the novelty of our research consisting of channel integration and the best responses of the proposed coalition, the above mentioned numerical example has been solved by our new non-cooperative game theory approach and coalition vs. decentralization. Conclusively, the profit achieved from the coalition was higher than employing decentralization and leadership methods.

4.1. Definition of the problem

Considering the above mentioned models for sensitivity analysis and leadership selection, the three-echelon supply chain, including 2 suppliers, 2 manufacturers and 2 retailers has been designed. Table 4 indicates the numerical amounts of parameters proposed in the supply chain.

For sensitivity analysis, five constants, including a, b, g, k, u, have been chosen. The lower and upper bounds of these five elements are shown in Table 5.

While using design of experiment (DOE) and 2k-p experiments, and including one central point in each block, 17 different tests have been designed employing MINITAB 16.5 software (see Table 6).

4.2. Results

All experiments designed in Table 5 are performed for the decentralization game, MR game and SM game. For the decentralized game, the models have been coded, debugged and solved by LINGO 11. On the other hand, for MR and SM games, multi nonlinear equations have been solved using the Levenberg--Marquardt algorithm through fsolve application in MATLAB software. The calculated overall profit of the supply chain taking into account different types of problems is displayed in Table 7.

By taking a two-paired test, the results of the three types of decision making used in the supply chain have been compared. The findings obtained employing MINITAB 16.5 software is presented in Table 8. It is obvious that coalition, integration and semi centralization bring better results and profit to the SC.

The main effects of each situation considering five critical elements are calculated using MINITAB 16.5 software and shown in the figures of Table 9. In all models, Gama has the least noticeable effect, whereas K, Alpha and Beta have the strongest one, which means that changes in unit production cost will impact SC profit less than demand oscillation. K and Beta directly affect the overall profit of the SC in all three situations, and Alpha makes an impact inversely on decentralized and SM games. In the MR semi-integrated game, U parameter has direct effects on the overall profit of the SC. Thus, it can be concluded that higher marketing cost increases SC profit as a lower retailer price do for decentralized and SM games. Also, Beta parameter does not exist in the MR game, and therefore marketing cost is not included. As Beta parameter does not exist in the MR game, marketing cost is not included. We also conclude that changes in unit production cost will impact SC profit less than demand oscillation. In addition, higher marketing cost increases SC profit as a lower retailer price does for decentralized and SM games.

Conclusions

The conducted research has demonstrated coordination in multi-echelon supply chains in which the non-cooperative game theory approach is used as a suitable tool for coordinating pricing, inventory and marketing expenditure policies in the unlimited three-level supply chain, since a different level acts independently (decentralization) or, in some cases, integrates with other levels (coalition). For this matter, first of all, the objective function of each player and constraints has been modelled. Next, the best response of each player has been obtained based on the definition of the Nash equilibrium. Finally, two scenarios of decentralization and coalition have been modelled and analysed conducting an experiment. Among this, the concavities of the proposed models have been obtained and sensitivity analyses for different situation have been illustrated. A remark that a nonlinear demand and production cost function, besides unlimited levels and stock out situation taking into account the inventory system of the manufacturer, has been considered. Through the numerical experiment, 17 design cases (performed experiments) have been developed and the total profit of the supply chain under each scenario has been evaluated. According to statistical tests on the above introduced 17 experiments, the authors have found that the decentralized system performs significantly worse than the integration of the supplier with the manufacturer, whereas no significant difference can be observed for other combinations. To sum up, coalition and semi integration circumstances are more effective and beget higher profit for the total supply chain. In addition, based on the considered SC, coalition between manufacturers with suppliers is more effective than that between retailers and manufacturers.

The above discussed situation and assumptions made in this paper are the keys for future researches. Taking into account more levels in the supply chain through distribution centres, warehouses or final stores will lead researchers to a comprehensive model for coordinating the supply chain in the future. For more accuracy and to provide the proposed models performable in reality and industrial situations, the case studies based on industrial information from the existing supply chains should be gathered and examined. In conclusion, as the competency of information and complete information shared at different levels of the supply chain under real circumstances seem to be impossible, using incomplete or imperfect game theory approaches such as the signalling game or Nash Bayesian game will solve this problem and reach more realistic options in the future.

doi:10.3846/16111699.2014.926289

Caption: Fig. 1. The three-echelon supply network

Appendixes

Appendix 1. Best retailer responses

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Appendix 2. Best manufacturer responses

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

Appendix 3. Best supplier responses

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

References

Adida, E.; Demiguel, V. 2011. Supply chain competition with multiple manufacturers and retailers, Operations Research 59(1): 156-172. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/opre.1100.0863

Arda, Y.; Hennet, J. C. 2005. Supply chain coordination through contract negotiation, in Conference on Decision and Control, 12-15 October, 2005, Seville, Spain, 4658-4684.

Bai, S.; Wang, D. 2008. Research on inventory game of supply chain based on credit coordination mechanism, in IEEE International Conference on Service Operations and Logistics, and Informatics, 12-15 October, 2008, Beijing, China, 3037-3042.

Bazaraa, M. S.; Sherali, H. D.; Shetty, C. M. 1993. Nonlinear programming: theory and algorithms. New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons.

Cachon, G. P.; Kok, G. A. 2010. Competing manufacturers in a retail supply chain: on contractual form and coordination, Management Science 56(3): 571-589. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1090.1122

Cachon, G. P.; Lariviere, M. A. 1999. Capacity choice and allocation: strategic behavior and supply chain performance, Management Science 45(8): 1091-1108. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.45.8.1091

Chakrabortty, S.; Pal, M.; Nayak, P. K. 2010. Solution of interval-valued manufacturing inventory models with shortage, International Journal of Engineering and Applied Sciences 4(2): 357-365.

Chandra, C.; Kamrani, A. K. 2004. Mass customization: a supply chain approach. New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-9015-0

Chang, H. C. 2008. A note on the EPQ model with shortages and variable lead time, Information and Management Sciences 15(1): 61-67.

Chen, S. S. 2009. Comparing Cournat output and Bertrand price doupoly game. Taiwan: Dahan Institute of Technology.

Chopra, S.; Meindel, P. 2007. Supply chain management. New York: Prenticehall.

Esmaeili, M.; Aryanejad, M.; Zeephongsekul, P. 2008. A game theory approach in seller-buyer supply chain, European Journal Of Operation Research 195(2): 442-448. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/-j.ejor.2008.02.026

Feng, S. X. 2008. Coordination of pricing decisions in multiple product supply chains, in 4th International Conference on Wireless Communications, Networking and Mobile Computing, 12-14 October, 2008, Dalian, China, 16-22.

Feng, J. S.; Jia, L. M.; Jiao, H. L. 2007. The three stage supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts, in IEEE International Conference on Grey Systems and Intelligent Services, 18-20 November, 2007, Nanjing, China, 1216-1220. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/GSIS.2007.4443466

Forrester, J. W. 1958. Industrial dynamics--a major breakthrough for decision makers, Harvard Business Review 36(4): 37-66.

Gibbons, R. 2002. A primer in game theory. Essex: Pearson Education Limited.

Govindan, K.; Nicoleta, M. 2011. Overview and classification of coordination contracts within forward and reverse supply chains, Discussion Papers on Business and Economics 7: 5-32.

Gumus, T. A.; Guneri, F. A. 2007. Multi-echelon inventory management in supply chains with uncertain demand and lead times: literature review from an operational research perspective, in Proceedings of the Institution of Mechanical Engineers, Part B: Journal of Engineering Manufacture 221(10): 1553-1570. http://dx.doi.org/10.1243/09544054JEM889

Gupta, D.; Weerawat, W. 2006. Supplier manufacturer coordination in capacitated two stage supply chains, Elsevier: European Journal of Operational Research 175(1): 67-89. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2005.04.021

Hennet, J. C.; Arda, Y. 2008. Supply chain coordination: a game theory approach, Engineering Applications of Artificial Intelligence 21(3): 399-405. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.engappai.2007.10.003

Jaber, M. Y.; Osman, I. H.; Guiffrida, A. L. 2006. Coordinating a three level supply chain with price discounts, price dependent demand, and profit sharing, International Journal of Integrated Supply Chain 2(1): 28-49. http://dx.doi.org/10.1504/IJISM.2006.008337

Jaafarnejad, A.; Amoozad Mahdiraji, H.; Mohaghar, A.; Modarresyazdi, M. 2012. Retailers leadership mathematical modeling in unlimited three echelon supply chain: noncooperative game theory approach, Archives Des Science 65(6): 81-90.

Jia, P.; Amoozad Mahdiraji, H.; Govindan, K.; Meidute, I. 2013. Leadership selection in an unlimited three-echelon supply chain, Journal of Business Economics and Management 14(3): 616-637. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/16111699.2012.761648

Jiazhen, H.; Qin, L. 2008. Revenue coordination contract based on Stackelberg game in upsteam supply chain, in 4th International Conference on Wireless Communications, Networking and Mobile Computing, 12-14 October, 2008, Dalian, China, 1-5.

Kaplinski, O.; Tamosaitiene, J. 2010. Game theory applications in construction engineering and management, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 16(2): 348-363. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/tede.2010.22

Kaviani, M. R.; Chaharsooghi, K.; Naimi Saidgh, A. 2011. Stackelberg game theory approach for manufacturer--retailer supply chain coordination using imperialist competitive algorithm, in 2nd International Conference on Logistics & Supply Chain Conference, 22-23 November, 2011, Tehran, Iran, 130-145.

Lee, J. W. 1993. Determining order quantity and selling price by geomettric programming: optimal solution, bounds, and sensitivity, Decesion Science 24(1): 76-87. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5915.1993.tb00463.x

Lee, H. L.; Padmanabhan, V.; Seungjin, W. 1997. The bullwhip effect in supply chains, Sloan Management Review Spring: 93-102.

Leng, M. M.; Parlar, M. 2010. Game theoretic analysis of decentralized assembly supply chains: non cooperative equilibria vs. coordination with cost sharing contracts, European Journal of Operational Research 204(1): 96-104. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2009.10.011

Leng, M. M.; Zhu, A. 2009. Side payments contracts in two person nonzero sum supply chain games: review, discussion and applications, European Journal of Operational Research 196(2): 600-618. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.03.029

Liu, Y.; Zhang, H. 2006. Supply chain coordination with contracts for online game industry, in IEEE International Conference on Innovation and Technology, June, 2006, Singapore, China, 867-871.

Oganezov, K. N. 2006. Inventory models for production systems with constant linear demand, time value of money and perishable or nonperiashable items. Virginia: West Virginia University.

Osborne, M. J. 2004. An introduction to game theory. Newyork: Oxford University Press.

Peldschus, F. 2008. Experience of the game theory application in construction management, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4): 531-545.

Peldschus, F.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2005. Fuzzy matrix games multi-criteria model for decisionmaking in engineering, Informatica 16(1): 107-120. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.531-545

Peldschus, F.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2012. Equilibrium approaches for construction processes- multi-objective decision making for construction projects, Bauingenieur 87(5): 210-215.

Peldschus, F.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Turskis, Z.; Tamosaitiene, J. 2010. Sustainable assessment of construction site by applying game theory, Inzinerine Ekonomika--Engineering Economics 21(3): 223-236.

Pentico, D. W.; Drake, M. J.; Toews, C. 2009. The deterministic EPQ with partial backordering: a new approach, Omega 37(3): 624-636. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2008.03.002

Rasmusen, E.; Blackwell, B. 2005. Games and information; an introduction to game theory. 4th ed. Indiana: Indiana University Press.

Simchi-Levi, D.; Kaminsky, P.; Simchi-Levi, E. 2004. Managing the supply chain: the definitive guide for the business professional. New York: Mc-Graw Hill.

Stadtler, H.; Kilger, C. 2007. Supply chain management and advanced planning: concepts, models, software, and Case Studies. New York: Springer.

Stein, H. D.; Ginevicius, R. 2010. New co-opettion approach for supply chain applications and the implementation a new allocation rule, in 6th International Conference Business and Management, 13-14 May, 2010, Vilnius, Lithuania, 147-152. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/jbem.2010.21

Walker, W. 2005. Supply chain architecture: a blueprint for networking the flow of material, Information and Cash. Florida: CRC Press.

Wang, W. Y.; Michael, H. S.; Patrick, Y. 2007. Supply chain management: issues in the new era of collaboration and competition. Pensylvania: Idea Group Publishing.

Wang, L.; Sun, X.; Dang, F. 2009. Dynamic cooperation mechanism in supply chain for perishable agricultural products under one to multi, Advances in Neural Networks: Lecture Noes in Computer Science 5553: 1212-1221. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11424-009-9166-6

Wang, X.; Tang, W. 2009. Fuzzy EPQ inventory models with backorder, Journal of System and Science Complexity 22(2): 313-323.

Wang, S.; Zhao, L. 2009. Helper mode analysis in a supply chain: based on supermodular game theory, International Conference on Management and Service Science, 20-22 September, 2009, Wuhan, China, 978-983.

Wisner, J.; Tan, K.; Leong, G. 2008. Principles of supply chain management: a balanced approach. Ohio: South-Western Cengage Learning.

Xu, Y.; Zhong, H. 2011. Benefit mechanism designing: for coordinating three stages supply chain, in International Conference on Management Science and Industrial Engineering, 811 January, 2011, Harbin, China, 966-969.

Ying, H. L.; Qi, C. Y.; Sheng, J. Z. 2007. Research on the coordination mechanism model of the three level supply chain, in International Conference on management Science and Engineering, 20-22 August, 2007, Harbin, China, 20-25.

Zandi, F.; Tavana, M.; O'Connor, A. 2012. A strategic cooperative game-theoretic model for market segmentation with application to banking in emerging economies, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 18(3): 389-423. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/20294913.2012.688072

Zavadskas , E. K.; Peldschus, F.; Ustinovicius, L. 2004. Game theory in building technology and management. Vilnius: Technika.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Turskis, Z. 2008. A new logarithmic normalization method in game theory, Informatica 19(2): 303-314.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Turskis, Z. 2011. Multiple criteria decision making (MCDM) methods in economics: an overview, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 17(2): 397-427. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/20294913.2011.593291

Received 08 August 2013; accepted 16 May 2014

Hannan Amoozad Mahdiraji (1), Kannan Govindan (2), Edmundas Kazimieras Zavadskas (3), Seyed Hossein Razavi Hajiagha (4)

(1) Department of Management, Kashan Branch, Islamic Azad University, Kashan, Iran

(2) Department of Business and Economics, University of Southern Denmark, Odense, Denmark

(3) Faculty of Civil Engineering, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223Vilnius, Lithuania

(4) Department of Management, Kashan Branch, Islamic Azad University, Kashan, Iran

E-mails: (1) [email protected]; (2) [email protected];

(3) [email protected] (corresponding author) (4) [email protected]

Zhao, Y; Wang, S.; Cheng, T. E.; Yang, X.; Huang, Z. 2010. Coordination of supply chains by option contracts: a cooperative game theory approach, European Journal of Operational Research 207(2): 668-675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2010.05.017

Hannan AMOOZAD MAHDIRAJI. PhD in operation and manufacturing management from the University of Teheran, BA in industrial engineering. Assistant Professor of Kashan branch, Islamic Azad University and the Chief of Planning and Systems Department of Iran Mercantile Exchange. Has published nearly 15 papers on supply chains and MCDM models in international journals and conferences.

Kannan GOVINDAN is currently an Associate Professor of operations and supply chain management at the Department of Business and Economics, University of Southern Denmark, Odense M, Denmark. Has published more than 65 papers in the refereed international journals and more than 70 papers in conferences. Was awarded a gold medal for the best PhD thesis. Research interests: logistics, supply chain management, green and sustainable supply chain management, reverse logistics and maritime logistics.

Edmundas Kazimieras ZAVADSKAS. PhD, DSc, h.c.multi. Prof., the Head of the Department of Construction Technology and Management at Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Lithuania. Senior Research Fellow at the Research Institute of Smart Building Technologies. PhD in Building Structures (1973). Dr Sc in Building Technology and Management (1987). A member of Lithuanian and several foreign Academies of Sciences. Doctore Honoris Causa from Poznan, Saint Petersburg and Kiev universities. Honorary International Chair Professor of the National Taipei University of Technology. A member of international organizations; a member of steering and programme committees at many international conferences; a member of the editorial boards of several research journals; the author and co-author of more than 400 papers and a number of monographs in Lithuanian, English, German and Russian. The editor-in-chief of journals Technological and Economic Development of Economy and Journal of Civil Engineering and Management. Research interests: building technology and management, decision-making theory, automation in design and decision support systems.

Seyed Hossein RAZAVI HAJIAGHA. Assistant Professor at the Department of Systemic and Productivity Studies, Institute for Trade Studies and Research, Teheran, Iran. PhD in Production and Operation Management (2012). The author and co-author of about 20 scientific papers. Research interests: multiple criteria analysis, decision-making theories, data envelopment analysis and mathematical modelling of industrial problems.
Table 1. Coordination contracts

Contract                              Description

Wholesale         The buyer pays a fixed and quantity-independent
                  price of each purchased unit for the seller

Discount          Quantity-dependent unit prices

Buyback           The seller promises to compensate the buyer for
                  unsold quantities

Revenue sharing   The downstream agent commits to return a pre
                  negotiated portion of its realized profits to the
                  upstream agent

Rebate            The upstream agent rewards the downstream agent for
                  every sold unit

Side payment      Lump-sum monetary transfers among the contracting
                  agents that are independent of the amount of trade
                  and used as compensation and incentive alignment
                  mechanisms

Flexible          In contrast with a rebate contract

Push & pull       By increasing the amount of selling or buying, the
                  upstream agent proposes a lower price

Table 2. The notation of decision variables and parameters

Description                    Note              Description

Product n and ordering cost    [MATHEMATICAL     Retailer's margin
  of supplier s                EXPRESSION NOT
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN
                               ASCII]
Manufacturer's margin          [G.sub.n]         Selling price of
                                                   product n to
                                                   retailer r
Manufacturer's total revenue   [TR.sub.n]        Retailer's setup
                                                   cost

Total manufacturing cost       [TC.sub.n]        Retailer's
                                                 holding cost
                                                 coefficient
Supplier's margin              [G.sub.S]         Retailer's total
                                                 revenue
Supplier's total revenue       [TR.sub.S]        Retailer's total
                                                 cost
Supplier's total cost          [TC.sub.S]        Retailer's total
                                                 payoff
Supplier's unit cost of a      [G.sub.S]         Coefficient of a
  raw material                                   raw material in
                                                 product n

Supplier's holding cost        [MATHEMATICAL     Price of a raw
  coefficient                  EXPRESSION NOT    material from s
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN   of product n
                               ASCII]
Supplier's ordering cost       [MATHEMATICAL     Variable
                               EXPRESSION NOT    manufacturing
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN   cost
                               ASCII]
Integrated payoff function of the manufacturer and retailer

Integrated payoff function of the manufacturer and supplier

Description                    Note

Product n and ordering cost    [G.sub.r]
  of supplier s

Manufacturer's margin          [P.sub.n]

Manufacturer's total revenue   [MATHEMATICAL
                               EXPRESSION NOT
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN
                               ASCII]
Total manufacturing cost       [k'.sub.n]

Supplier's margin              [TR.sub.r]

Supplier's total revenue       [TC.sub.r]

Supplier's total cost          [Z.sub.r]

Supplier's unit cost of a      [MATHEMATICAL
  raw material                 EXPRESSION NOT
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN
                               ASCII]
Supplier's holding cost        [MATHEMATICAL
  coefficient                  EXPRESSION NOT
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN
                               ASCII]
Supplier's ordering cost       [MATHEMATICAL
                               EXPRESSION NOT
                               REPRODUCIBLE IN
                               ASCII]
Integrated payoff function     [Z.sub.MR]
  of the manufacturer and
  retailer
Integrated payoff function     [Z.sub.SM]
  of the manufacturer and
  supplier

Table 4. Initial data on the numerical example

Amount   Par                Amount   Par

2        M                  2        R

4        [MATHEMATICAL      2        S
         EXPRESSION NOT
         REPRODUCIBLE
         IN ASCII]

0.15     [k'.sub.1]         5        [MATHEMATICAL
                                     EXPRESSION NOT
                                     REPRODUCIBLE
                                     IN ASCII] (2)

1.1      [[phi]'.sub.1]     0.2      [k'.sub.2]

3        [k.sub.sn] (11)    1.15     [[phi]'.sub.2]

3        [k.sub.sn] (21)    4        [k.sub.sn] (12)

6        [Co.sub.sn] (11)   3        [k.sub.sn] (22)

4        [Co.sub.sn] (21)   5        [Co.sub.sn] (12)

1        [C.sub.B] (1) =    6        [Co.sub.sn] (22)

         [C.sub.B] (2)

25       [MATHEMATICAL      0.5      [MATHEMATICAL
         EXPRESSION NOT              EXPRESSION NOT
         REPRODUCIBLE                REPRODUCIBLE
         IN ASCII] (1)               IN ASCII]

0.15     [MATHEMATICAL      24       [MATHEMATICAL
         EXPRESSION NOT              EXPRESSION NOT
         REPRODUCIBLE                REPRODUCIBLE
         IN ASCII] (1)               IN ASCII] (2)

2        [MATHEMATICAL      0.2      [MATHEMATICAL
         EXPRESSION NOT              EXPRESSION NOT
         REPRODUCIBLE                REPRODUCIBLE
         IN ASCII] (1)               IN ASCII] (2)

15       PC (1) = PC (2)    1.5      [MATHEMATICAL
                                     EXPRESSION NOT
                                     REPRODUCIBLE
                                     IN ASCII] (2)

8        [MATHEMATICAL      7        [MATHEMATICAL
         EXPRESSION NOT              EXPRESSION NOT
         REPRODUCIBLE                REPRODUCIBLE
         IN ASCII] (2)               IN ASCII] (1)

1.1      [[phi].sub.2]      1.15     [[phi].sub.1]

Table 5. Key parameters for sensitivity analysis

Max    Min    Par

1.25   1.2    [alpha]
0.15   0.05   [beta]
0.1    0.01   [gamma]
4000   3000   k
 4      2     u

Table 6. Design of experiment

[beta]   [alpha]   k      u   [gamma]   Design

0.15       1.2     4000   4    0.01       1
0.05       1.2     3000   2     0.1       2
0.05       1.2     3000   4    0.01       3
0.05      1.25     3000   4     0.1       4
0.15      1.25     4000   4     0.1       5
0.15       1.2     3000   4     0.1       6
0.1       1.225    3500   3    0.055      7
0.15      1.25     3000   4    0.01       8
0.15      1.25     3000   2     0.1       9
0.15       1.2     3000   2    0.01       10
0.05      1.25     3000   2    0.01       11
0.05       1.2     4000   4     0.1       12
0.05       1.2     4000   2    0.01       13
0.15       1.2     4000   2     0.1       14
0.15      1.25     4000   2    0.01       15
0.05      1.25     4000   4    0.01       16
0.05      1.25     4000   2     0.1       17

Table 7. The overall profit of the supply chain

Design   Decentralized   MR game   SM game

1            2288         1918      3406
2            1593         1939      1775
3            1552         1929      1737
4            1067         1849      1315
5            2442         1969      2407
6            2552         1866      2535
7            1995         1980      2073
8            1800         2462      1869
9            1819         1501      1839
10           2572         1493      2552
11           1088         1892      1320
12           2135         1451      2345
13           2168         1467      2380
14           2438         2503      3421
15           2498         1900      2474
16           1500         2441      1764
17           1507         2492      1794

Table 8. Comparison results from three coalition and
independent games

P-Value   T-Value   St Dev   Mean     Experiments

0.193     1.36      608      2177     17
                    355      1944     17
                    705      232      17

0.988     -0.01     498      1942     17
                    355      1944     17
                    672      -2       17

0.009     -2.96     498      1942     17
                    608      2177     17
                    327.4    -234.9   17

Table 9. The analysis of three proposed models for SC behaviour

        Decentralized Game     MR Game

P       Effect   Coefficient   Effect   Coefficient

Gama    10.7     5.4           8.4      4.2
U       -43.1    -21.6         87.2     43.6
K       366.8    183.4         151.3    71.6
Alpha   -447.1   -223.1        242.6    121.3
Beta    724.9    362.4           *           *

        SM Game

P       Effect   Coefficient

Gama    -8.6     -4.3
U       -21.9    -10.9
K       631.2    315.2
Alpha   -671.2   -375.3
Beta    759.3    379.4

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有