The impact of production factors and economic structures on economic development/Gamybos veiksniu ir ekonomikos strukturu itaka ekonominiam vystymuisi.
Tvaronaviciene, Manuela ; Lankauskiene, Toma
Introduction. Sustainable economic growth: emphasis on driving
Forces and a mode of economic growth
The scientists investigating economic growth devote close attention
to production factors affecting the development of national economies
(e.g. Bond et al. 2010; Sarkar 2007; Briec, Cavaignac 2007; Kosempel
2004) and focus on fluctuations in the sectors of economy (e.g.
Jaimovich 2011; Halkos, Tzeremes 2008; Tanuwidjaja, Thangavelu 2007;
Sonobe et al. 2004). An ongoing discussion generates how different
factors affect economic growth, sustainable development and
transformation of separate sectors of the taken economies (e.g. Karnitis
2011; Grybaite 2011; Staficzyk 2011; Korsakiene et al. 2011; Balkyte,
Tvaronaviciene 2011; Tvaronaviciene, Lankauskiene 2011; Tvaronaviciene
2012; Tvaronaviciene, Grybaite 2012; Kazmierczyk 2012). Since the
variety of approaches and theories coexist, have a look at the genesis
of the main theories to identify the interrelation of economic growth
(partly sustainable development), production factors and economic
structures. Economic growth is unanimously measured by percentage change
in GDP or GNI per capita from one year to another. Economic development
acquires an additional dimension specifically necessary to sustain the
standard of living through changing driving forces and a mode of
economic growth. To put in other words, economies raising their GDP or
GNI per capita through exploiting their national natural resources are
not considered as sustainably growing. Sustainable economic growth
nowadays is associated with an increase in living standards through
economic progress, the development of knowledge based and innovation
susceptible sectors, but not with exploiting nonrenewable natural
resources, which as a rule, are controlled by the limited groups of
societies. Hence, at present, economic growth is being analyzed in light
of aims for sustainable development, despite the goal of economic
development remains the enlargement of asset creation speed (Clark 1990)
and acceleration of competitive human well-being creation (e.g. Balkyte,
Tvaronaviciene 2010; Lankauskiene, Tvaronavicien? 2011). It can be
claimed that difference between economic growth and sustainable economic
development lies in an adopted approach--purely quantitative or
considering qualitative changes (e.g. Pisani, Jacobus 2006; Ciegis,
Ramanauskiene 2009; Ruchi 2009; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012).
1. Genesis of theories about economic growth
The concept of sustainable economic growth emerged much later in
comparison with the area of research on economic growth. One of the most
prominent classics of economic growth theory was Adam Smith whose famous
book An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations was
issued in 1776. He argued that the enlargement of production rather than
the trade sector would create greater wealth in the country. Market
forces, named "an invisible hand of the market", are better
regulators than the state (Willis 2005). Smith considered work
specialization as proxy for increasing productivity. Hence, according to
Smith, economic development can be related to the process of
specialization and diversification of the economic sector. Later, Allyn
Young (1928) wrote that "industrial differentiation was and
remained the type of a change characteristically associated with the
growth of production" (Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012).
Similarly, Landes (1969) claimed that the most evident effects brought
about by the Industrial Revolution were an increase in the variety of
products and occupations and gains in productivity (Jaimovich 2011).
Another classic was David Ricardo. He introduced the concept of a
"comparative advantage" of countries. According to his theory,
countries should concentrate on producing and then selling goods to have
advantage in producing their assets such as land, mineral resources,
labour, technical or scientific expertise. Ricardo suggested that in
comparison with producing everything such a way was more beneficial to
national economic growth (Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). In 1936,
the British economist John Maynard Keynes published the General Theory
of Employment, Interest and Money. The argument put forward by Keynes
was that the free market was not necessarily positive force as many who
followed Adam Smith believed. Keynes explained that real investment was
the key to growth, i.e. investment in new (rather than replacement)
infrastructure projects. He asserted that such kind of investment would
have a positive effect on job creation and further generation of wealth
(Willis 2005; Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012).
It can be noticed that the state plays an important role in
different approaches of economic growth. The state can even act as an
interventionist having a profound impact on further development. The
theory of Marxism provides the following stages of development: ancient
feudalism, capitalism and socialism (Willis 2005). Another distribution
of development theories is based on continental models (e.g. Lee 2006;
Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012).
The following groups of growth and development theories could be
suggested after a vast amount of a relevant analysis of scientific
literature considering post-1945 development theories: linear
stages-of-growth theories, the theories and patterns of structural
changes, the international dependence revolution, the neo-classical
free-market counterrevolution, the new growth theory, the unified growth
theory (Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). The
above presented groups theories will be characterized below in the paper
devoting more attention to the linear stages-of-growth and patterns of
structural changes. Reasons for the mode of focus will be explained
respectively.
2. Structural change in the theories of economic growth
One of the most known representatives of linear stages-of-growth
theories is W. Rostow stating that a country has to accumulate the
needed amount of savings in order for the country to take the stage of
take-off as the path from underdevelopment (traditional society) to
self-sustaining growth (Rostow 1960; Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene,
Tvaronaviciene 2012). The idea of the importance of economic sectors has
been incorporated into his model. Rostow provided a traditional society
(the one that has not reached the stage of self-sustaining development
or even take-off stage) based on agriculture (Todaro, Smith 2011;
Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). The take-off stage included the
features of technical innovation, changes in international economic
development, investments and savings accumulation, a substantial
manufacturing sector and appropriate institutional arrangements, e.g. a
banking system. The maturity phase has to contain the extended range of
technology and 10-20 percent savings of national income. The stage of
development--the age of mass consumption--provided widespread
consumption of durable goods and services and increased spending on
welfare services. It was supposed that all advanced countries had passed
the stage of "take-off into self-sustaining growth".
Underdeveloped countries that were still in either the traditional
society or at the "preconditions" stage had only to follow a
certain set of rules of development to take off in their turn into
self-sustaining economic growth (Theobald 1961; Willis 2005; Todaro,
Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). The theory of stages
provided by Rostow is usually taken as "the pre-eminent theory of
development through the early 1960s" (Dietz 1983; Todaro, Smith
2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). One of the principal
strategies of development necessary for any take-off was the
mobilization of domestic and foreign savings in order to generate
sufficient investment to accelerate economic growth (Todaro, Smith 2011;
Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012).
Economic mechanism by which more investment leads to more growth
can be described in terms of the Harrod-Domar growth model, today often
referred to as the AK model based on a linear production function. The
main question elaborated by Harrod and Domar was about the circumstances
under which economy could be capable to achieve steady growth. The
authors viewed instability in economic growth as a result of failure to
equate a "warranted" and "natural" rate of growth.
The warranted rate of growth is dependent on the savings rate and given
capital requirement per unit of output. The natural rate is the maximum
long-run sustainable rate of growth (Ruttan 1988; Todaro, Smith 2011).
To grow, economies must save and invest a certain proportion of their
GDP. The more they can invest, the faster they can grow. However, the
actual rate they can grow for any saving and investment is the amount of
an additional output obtained from an additional unit of investment
(Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012).
The structural-change theory concentrates on the process through
which underdeveloped economies transform their domestic economic
structures from traditional subsistence agriculture to more modern, more
urbanized and more industrially diverse manufacturing and service
(Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). W. Arthur
Lewis, John Fei, Gustav Ranis (Choo 1971; Todaro, Smith 2011;
Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012) are the economists associated with
the elaboration of the structural-change theory.
According to, e.g. Lewis, the structure of economic sectors,
especially the development of manufacturing (in terms of employment) is
closely related to the process of economic growth (Lewis 1955; Todaro,
Smith 2011; Lankauskiene, Tvaronaviciene 2012). Other economies
attributed to the stream structural-change theory also claimed that
economies should shit their path from agriculture to manufacturing.
Like the earlier introduced Lewis model, the patterns of the
development analysis of structural change focus on the sequential
process through which the economic, industrial and institutional
structure of underdeveloped economy is transformed over time to permit
new industries to replace traditional agriculture as the engine of
economic growth. However, in contrast to the Lewis model and the view on
the original stages of development, increased savings and investment are
perceived by the patterns of development analysts as necessary but not
sufficient conditions for economic growth. In addition to the
accumulation of capital, both physical and human, a set of interrelated
changes in the economic structure of the country are required for the
transition from a traditional economic system to a modern one (Todaro,
Smith 2011). The major hypothesis of the structural change model is that
development is an identifiable process of growth and changes the main
features of which are similar in all countries. However, the model does
recognize that differences can arise among countries in the pace and
pattern of development, depending on their particular set of
circumstances. The factors, influencing the development process include
the endowment and size of national resources, governmental policies and
objectives, the availability of external capital and technology and the
international trade environment (Todaro, Smith 2011; Lankauskiene,
Tvaronaviciene 2012).
As mentioned above, the other theories of growth can be grouped
into the clusters of the international dependence revolution, the
neo-classical free-market counterrevolution, the new growth theory and
the unified growth theory. In the context of our paper, we only mention
the main representatives of those theories and then switch back towards
production factors and economic structures. Robert Solow, the Nobel
prize winner, is a famous theoretic of economic growth. Despite some
criticism (e.g. Prescott, 1988; the Solow's model have become a
classical example of economic growth. Solow focused on investigating the
impact of the patterns of capital, labour and technology on economic
development taking into account investment and capital depreciation
processes (Solow 1988). Later, the theory of endogenous growth appeared
(King, Rebelo 1993; Eltis 2000; This theory as well as the latest
unified growth theory (Galor 2010) in principle did not indicate new
driving forces of economic growth.
3. Sustainable economic growth through the lenses of economic
structures: interrelation of production factors and economic structures
After the overview of the main theories about economic development
we have came to the conclusion that despite the variety of economic
growth theories, rather limited scope of factors affecting the
development of economies are being distinguished. The theories differ in
conceptual approaches towards the processes of economic growth and the
role of certain factors. The list of factors, as mentioned above, is
comparatively limited. As economic growth is hardly possible without
parallel change in economic structures, we raise a hypothesis that
factors affecting economic growth first influence economic structures.
It is assumed that differently developed countries, experience different
effect caused by the impact of the same selected driving forces of
economic growth, which, in turn, differently restructure economic
structures.
In order to verify the hypothesis, review the latest economic
literature listed in the database of the Web of Sciences. In this case,
we can find that a group of authors claims that an industrial structure
evolves with economic development. They provide evidence indicating that
since the reform and opening up of economy in 1978, China has undergone
rapid economic growth and dramatic industrial restructuring with the
proportion of primary, secondary and tertiary industry changed
respectively from 28%, 48% and 24% of GDP in 1978 to 11%, 49% and 40% in
2008. Using panel data collected from 31 provinces for the past three
decades, this paper has empirically examined the relationship between
economic growth and the industrial structure. Based on the results from
the unit root test, co-integration test and Granger causality test, the
article concludes that two variables are order-1 integrated, short-run
economic fluctuation causes the disproportion of the industrial
structure while long-run bidirectional causal relationship exists
between the disproportion of the industry structure and economic
aggregate fluctuation. This paper has also investigated the determinants
of Chinese industrial structure and found that influential factors
include per capita GDP, domestic consumption propensity, urban-rural
disparity, the scale of labour force and capital stock, property right
protection and administrative effectiveness (Dong et al. 2011).
Another paper proposes an economic model for analyzing dynamic
interaction among capital accumulation, the economic structure and
preference in a perfectly competitive economic system. The system
consists of three sectors: agriculture, industry and service. A typical
consumer's utility is dependent on the consumption of agricultural
and industrial goods, services, housing and wealth. The size of the
territory is given and public land ownership is assumed. The model
presented in this study is influenced by the structural approach
provided, for example, by Leontief, Srafa and Pasinetti. Traditional
models of neoclassical growth such as the Solow-Swan one-sector model,
the Uzawa two-sector model and Ricardian models of Samuelson and
Pasinetti, may be considered from a structural point of view as special
cases of the model discussed in this study (Zhang 1996).
With reference to co-integration tests, another paper estimates the
long-run relationship between real per capita GDP, per capita stock of
physical capital, measures of financial development and financial
structure (Luintel et al. 2008). The results are quite revealing. First,
for the majority of sample countries, financial structure appears
significant to explain economic growth (Luintel et al. 2008). The
relationship between financial structure and economic development can be
examined on the basis of the competing theories of financial structure
and include bank-based, market-based and financial services, the law and
finance. They are being briefly discussed in what follows (Luintel et
al. 2008). A large body of empirical literature has attempted to
evaluate this debate. Early studies focus on the UK and US as
market-based systems versus Japan and Germany as bank-based systems ().
They rigorously compare and contrast the country-specific financial
structure, that is, an assortment of financial markets, instruments and
intermediaries in operation, and conclude that financial structure is
important for economic growth. However, Goldsmith (1969), highlighting
their shortcomings, argues that these four industrialized countries have
resembling real per capita income levels and historically share similar
growth rates.
Consequently, it is hard to attribute their analogous growth rates
to the alternative forms of either the bank-based or market-based
financial system. Similarly, assert that although UK, US, Germany and
Japan did experience the periods of divergent growth rates, nonetheless,
"it is very difficult to draw broad conclusions about bank-based
and market-based financial systems from only four countries". They
argue that the empirical assessment of the role of financial structure
should be based on a broad dataset that encompasses wide-ranging
national experiences (Luintel et al. 2008). The bank-based theory
emphasizes a positive role of banks in development and growth and
stresses the shortcomings of market-based financial systems. The theory
claims that banks can finance development more effectively than markets
in developing economies, and, in the case of state-owned banks, market
failures can be overcome and the allocation of savings can be undertaken
strategically (Luintel et al. 2008). By contrast, the market-based
theory highlights the advantages of well-functioning markets in
promoting successful economic performance, and stresses the problems of
bank-based financial systems. Big, liquid and well-functioning markets
foster growth and profit incentives, enhance corporate governance and
facilitate risk management, diversification and customization of risk
management devices (Luintel et al. 2008). The third theory of
financial-services stresses the key financial services provided by
financial systems. Financial services are crucial to creating a new
firm, industrial expansion and economic growth. This theory is actually
consistent with both bank-based and market-based views. Although it
embraces both, it minimizes their importance in that the distinction
between bank-based and market-based financial systems matters less than
it was previously believed (Luintel et al. 2008). The standard
econometric specification of growth models in cross-country studies
regresses real per capita GDP growth on a number of growth determinants.
Our approach is time series. Given the non-stationarity of data, the
co-integrating (long-run) relationship between output, physical capital
stock, financial development and financial structure are estimated. Our
basic specification is (Luintel et al. 2008):
logt(Q/L) = a0 + a1logt(K/L) + a2logt(FS) + a3logt(FD) + e1, (1)
where, Q is output, L is labour, K is physical capital stock, FS
and FD are the measures of financial structure and financial development
respectively, e1 is the error term. In empirical estimations, we use
real per capita output (YP) and real per capita capital stock (KP),
since consistent time series on labour force do not exist for most of
our sample countries. A high value of FS means a system that is more of
a market-based variety while a lower FS means more of the bank-based
system (Luintel et al. 2008). Eq. (1) is an empirical model of our
benchmark. From a theoretical perspective, this can be viewed as a
generalized Cobb-Douglas production function where financial development
and financial structure account for total factor productivity (Luintel
et al. 2008). Our sample consists of low and middle income countries
representing different stages of development and economic structures.
They also share significantly different experience of growth. It is,
therefore interesting to formally test if it is valid to pool the
dataset of these countries. This is important not least because there is
a growing concern about the panel and cross-section tests, in that they
neglect cross-country heterogeneity (Luintel et al. 2008). We find
evidence of significant cross-country heterogeneity in the relationship
between financial development, financial structure and economic growth.
The tests show that data on the countries displayed in our sample cannot
be pooled (Luintel et al. 2008). We also examine how the effects of
financial development and financial structure change when (i) countries
become economically more developed and get richer; (ii) the financial
structure of countries develops and converges to that of the US; (iii)
the level of the overall financial development of countries converges to
that of the US. The main policy message that emanates from our analyses
is that financial structure matters for economic growth (Luintel et al.
2008).
One more paper indicates that changes in social structures
occurring during the process of economic growth can be considered direct
consequences of this process, while other changes are caused by factors
such as technological progress affecting simultaneously social
structures and growth. The author focuses on that part of the circular
argument that goes from growth to social structures (Bourguignon 2005).
It does not consider the effect of social changes on growth. It is
attempted to isolate the pure "income effect" in the evolution
of social structures and to disentangle the effect of economic growth
from the effect of other factors in observed changes in social
structures (Bourguignon 2005). First, the nature of statistical
relationships existing between social indicators and development across
countries and/or across periods is being examined, further the
theoretical models of the effect of economic growth on social structures
with an emphasis on several dimensions of social differentiation and on
economic inequality is being scrutinized. Next, the author (Bourguignon
2005) focuses on empirical evidence for supporting this structural view
of the consequences of growth for social structures. The conclusion is
that emphasis has to be put on the importance of sector shits, the role
of the market in integrating economy and society and the social costs of
sector adjustment (Bourguignon 2005).
The following paper examines the economic implications of
demographic change in the Chinese context. The equation for growth is
being extended by the authors incorporating age structure dynamics and
applied to data for the period 1989-2004 at Chinese provincial-level. It
was found that changes in demographic structure, especially the
contribution of fertility decline to lower youth dependency, have helped
in fuelling economic growth in China since 1989. The effect of
demographic change on income growth operates mainly through its impact
on steady state income levels and the effect of age structure is more
pronounced in provinces that are more open to market forces. It was also
established significant feedback effect of economic growth on
demographic behaviour through the mechanisms of birth rates, marriage
age and life expectancy (Wei, Hao 2010). During recent years, there has
been an increasing awareness of the explanatory power of variables in
the population age structure concerning regression to economic growth. A
new cross-country regression model for the effects of changes in the age
structure on economic growth has been estimated. The new model has been
used and recent probabilistic demographic forecasts for India to derive
the uncertainty of rates for predicted economic growth caused by
uncertainty about demographic development (Prskawetz et al. 2007).
Even though the phenomenon of structural change is as old as the
very problems of economic development, up to now, the term
'economics of structural change' has been practically unknown.
The enormous heterogeneity of studies in this area, inherently related
to the complexity of the matter, does not lend itself easily to a
unified approach, and only recently there have been some attempts, e.g.
by Baranzini and Scazzieri in 1990 and Landesmann and Scazzieri in 1996
(Silva, Teixeira 2008) to organize the theoretical approach in a
systematic manner. Second, the terms 'structure' and
'structural change' are widely used in economic research under
very different meanings which, in many cases, have no connection with
'structural change analysis' (Silva, Teixeira 2008).
As shown in Fig. 1, during the last few decades, more precisely
from the late 1980s onwards, there has been a growing interest in
structural change analysis. The rising importance of this approach is
also related to the establishment, in 1990, of a new journal highly
dedicated to the topic--Structural Change and Economic Dynamics.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Publications on the economics of structural change were analyzed in
terms of eleven main topics selected on the basis of the undertaken
literature review. The selected topics cover (1) development, (2)
technical change and innovation, (3) convergence and growth, (4)
economic fluctuations, (5) international trade, (6) employment and
migrations, (7) industrial dynamics, (8) institutions and policies, (9)
regional and urban economics, (10) measurement and methods, (11)
environment and sustainability (Silva, Teixeira 2008).
The findings (Fig. 2) reveal that the marked rise in papers aimed
at discussing structural change analysis in the more recent period is
accompanied by a change in the main topics of the analysis explored.
Along with 'convergence and growth' that remains the most
relevant category throughout the period under study, but which has
recently lost ground, there is a notable increase in 'international
trade', 'technical change and innovation' and the topics
of analysis the importance of which has been continuously rising and is
particularly relevant in more recent years (Silva, Teixeira 2008).
The results of bibliometric research have helped in deriving a
picture of the overall evolution of structural change analysis from its
ancient roots (1700s-1890s) to the more recent period crossing the
chronological dimension and type of research proceeded (appreciative,
historical, empirical and formal). Based on the number of citations,
Fig. 3 reflects the most influential contributions in the field (e.g.,
Pasinetti, Leontief, Goodwin, Nelson, Freeman, Dosi, Schumpeter)
together with an indication of the main topics of analysis, more
significant research clusters (Marxian school, new school and
development, 'traverse', neo-schumpeterian and evolutionary,
environment) and links among (clusters of) researchers that are further
provided in the following sections. Another source presents, in
addition, an illustration of the strategy designed for organizing
relevant literature used in the present paper. Following a brief
characterization of the earlier foundations of structural change
analysis (Section 3), investigation (and discussion) into relatively
separate fields of pure theoretical and applied/ historical approaches
within the realm of structural change analysis is pursued (Sections 4
and 5). Then (Section 6), the analysis of a more recent period marked by
a strong rise of interest in the field and a change in the main topics
of research is performed (Silva, Teixeira 2008).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Both methodologies are congruent with relating the recent rise of
interest in structural change analysis with an attempt to develop an
alternative approach to the mainstream economic theory when analyzing
the relationship between technical change and economic growth. Not only
do technological issues gain increasing relevance during the period
under study, but also the most influential authors/ studies can be seen
as strong representatives of such a new perspective in the study of
technological change. Furthermore, our analysis shows that the 1990s
witnessed increasing relevance of formal work, which is in close
agreement with the attempt to consolidate this new approach as an
alternative to the rigorous modelling framework of neoclassical
economics. Evidence concerning more recent years does not confirm this
tendency, although it refers only to a half of the decade, which might
reflect the strong impetus towards empirically led work prompted by the
emergence of the New Economy and its impact on the overall workings of
the economic system (Silva, Teixeira 2008).
Along with a relative deficit of formal work, our analysis also
reveals that most contributions put great emphasis on technology-driven
growth (although combined with factors such as institutional change and
industry dynamics), lacking an appropriate (micro-based) treatment of
the demand side. The development of a dynamic theory of demand and its
connections with the formal treatment of structural and technological
change seems, therefore, to constitute a highly promising avenue for
future research (Silva, Teixeira 2008).
German economy is export-oriented, and therefore Germany's
export is primarily based on manufacturing products. As the lion's
share of exports is concentrated in only four manufacturing sectors, we
have singled them out as the 'export core' and separated it
from the rest. Our conjecture was that total as well as sector output
and employment are differently affected by structural change in these
two manufacturing subsectors where a special interest in their impact on
business-related services has been taken (Franke, Kalmbach 2005). To
inquire about these questions, an input-output framework has been
employed by the authors. One advantage of this approach is that it
allowed them to evaluate the role of technological change, at least
insofar as it is represented by input-output coefficients. In addition,
the influence of increasing import penetration on intermediate demand
could be assessed. As a matter of fact, on the basis of the German
input-output tables for 1991-2000, both factors were shown to have
significant consequences for economic activity. Import penetration had
generally negative effects on output while the effects of technological
change were mostly positive with the notable exception of the subsector
'other manufacturing', for which it turned out to be negative
(Franke, Kalmbach 2005). Technological change had a particularly strong
positive impact on business-related services. In the decomposition of
the growth rates of the sector output, up to the one-third (for
business-related services in a narrow sense) or even almost one half
(for business-related services in a broader sense) of the growth of
these subsectors could be attributed to economy-wide changes in
technological input-output coefficients. This is even more astounding as
they grew more than twice as fast as the total economy. As the authors
have used commodity-by-commodity input-output tables, the explanation
given in literature that outsourcing took place cannot be examined. The
reason may therefore be found in an increasing necessity for the
production of goods themselves to make the use of new and specialized
services to preserve competitiveness. Closer investigation into this
issue is, however, beyond the scope of the present input-output tables
(Franke, Kalmbach 2005). In the second part of the paper, a series of
experiments has been conducted. In the main series, the authors focused
on hypothetical consequences when certain features of historical
structural changes between 1991 and 2000 were assumed to be limited to
one of the manufacturing subsectors while the rest of economic data
maintained its base-year values. Several scenarios of such isolated
structural change were considered. In the simplest, only the
technological coefficients of the chosen sector are permitted to change.
The other scenarios include changes in import and export shares and
(simple form of) induced investment. Solving respective models for the
initial and final years, differences in output and employment can, by
construction, be attributed to selected variables (Franke, Kalmbach
2005). For ISC both in the export core and other manufacturing even an
elementary technological scenario had a clearly positive effect on the
total output. If ISC in the export core additionally takes international
trade and induced investment into account, positive effects from the
shares of increasing export of this sector markedly dominate negative
effects from its increasing import shares. The output growth rates of
business-related services more than doubled. In contrast, the same
scenario for ISC in other manufacturing affects their output results
from the technological scenario only very moderately; nevertheless, this
outcome is still better than negative changes in most of other sectors
(Franke, Kalmbach 2005). To sum up, business-related services are
unambiguous winners from technological change in manufacturing
industries on the one hand and from the export strength of the parts of
German manufacturing on the other. Except perhaps for the sector which
ISC is assumed to affect directly, they profit the most (in terms of
growth rates). With respect to effects from other features of structural
change in the manufacturing sector, business-related services still tend
to have an advantage over the majority of other sectors. We emphasize
that manufacturing is still a decisive component of German economy.
However, it is not a homogeneous sector, but regarding relative weights
as well as structural change and its impact on other production sectors,
it is useful to distinguish the export core from other manufacturing.
Second, it is inappropriate to view the sector of services as a new
growth engine. Our analysis revealed that especially the subsector that
exhibited by far the highest growth over the 1990s, business-related
services, is closely linked to the manufacturing sector and owes a
significant portion of its positive performance to the structural change
that took place in this part of economy (Franke, Kalmbach 2005).
Figure 3, presented below, shows the prospect of benchmarking
industry: transition economies in 2000 and change from pre-transition.
Despite the indicated percentage share of employment in industry in most
of the countries, the figure shows that the share is assumed to increase
along with GDP growth in transition countries during the taken period in
the long perspective.
Another contemporary paper has presented a framework for
benchmarking structural adjustment in transition economies. A simple
model we provide allows us examining both the causes of
over-industrialization in centrally planned economies and the pattern of
adjustment towards market-based equilibrium during transition. We
simulate two channels through which central planning may have led to
over-industrialization. These two channels are the preferences of
central planners for industrial goods over services and a technological
handicap that slowed down the rate of growth in industrial productivity.
The results of our simulations suggest that distortion in preferences
probably was a more important reason for over-industrialization than the
technological handicap (Raiser et al. 2004).
Turning to transition, the prediction of rapid deindustrialization
obtained from the analytical framework is strongly borne out by
evidence. Adjustment in the accession countries has by no means been
faster than in the CIS. One major difference in the pattern of
adjustment across the region has been changes in agricultural
employment. In the richest transition countries, agriculture has shed
employment during transition and is now generally smaller than would be
predicted by income levels. This might be explained by a relatively high
reservation wage among industrial workers due to the existence of a
social safety net and relatively high mobility out of temporary
unemployment. Thus, workers in advanced countries have preferred the
experience of a spell of unemployment to the return to "the
village". The opposite is true in most CIS countries where such a
safety net was not available and many people have been forced back into
subsistence farming (EBRD, 1997) (Raiser et al. 2004).
Empirical analysis suggests a number of implications for accession:
(1) Structural adjustment in industry is far from complete in all
accession candidates. Further downsizing in industry is to be expected
in the long run if these countries are to continue to move towards
adopting a market economy industrial structure. The pace of adjustment
in industry shows the signs of slowing in a number of countries,
however. (2) In agriculture, wealthier and more rapidly reforming
accession candidates have continued to reduce the shares of their labour
forces in agriculture, and are now actually quite close to what is seen
in many EU member states. Agriculture has been a particular problem for
EU policy making for many years, and this finding suggests that in the
long run the impact of accession countries on this problem may not be as
great as might have been feared. (3) A number of accession candidates
have shares of employment in non-market-oriented services that are
significantly greater than would be expected in market economies of
similar incomes with potentially significant implications for the public
finances of these countries (Raiser et al. 2004). Turning to the issue
of economic development patterns more generally, the paper raises an
interesting hypothesis that the patterns of industrialization may change
systematically depending on the date of take-off and the distance to the
technological leader in the world. While direct empirical tests of this
prediction may be difficult, it would seem worthwhile to conduct further
research into the matter and draw implications for development
strategies. Thus, as industrialization is no longer available as a major
outlet for surplus rural labour, the focus of policies might shift
towards creating conditions for employment in services (Raiser et al.
2004). The analysis presented in this paper remains incomplete in
several important respects. The model is very simple and suffers from
restrictive assumptions. As a heuristic device, it is nevertheless quite
powerful. More sophisticated theoretical research has begun, however, to
integrate economic growth and structural change into a unified
analytical framework Empirically, the derived benchmarks fail to control
the effects of economic specialisation in the global market and the
availability of natural resources, which may have an important bearing
on the allocation of employment. Measures for natural capital across the
world have recently been calculated by the World Bank and could be
integrated into analysis in future research (for the first attempt see
Finally, a closer examination of variations in the patterns of
adjustment across transition economies would seem promising regarding
dynamic implications of largescale labour reallocation from industry
back to agriculture in the CIS in particular (Raiser et al. 2004).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
One more paper indicates that Turkish exports are subject to
structural changes as Turkey integrates into global production networks.
Integration, which leads vertical specialization in production and
changes in the commodity composition of Turkish exports in favour of
non-traditional commodities, paces up during the periods of an economic
reform. As the export shares of non-traditional commodities, which have
higher import and income sensitivity but lower real exchange rate
elasticity, increases, the coefficients of the aggregate export function
change accordingly. Nevertheless, high import and income elasticity of
exports imply that the global growth pattern plays a significant role in
determining exports of Turkey (Saygili, H., Saygili, M. 2011).
4. Concluding remarks
The following observations could be noticed while scrutinizing
economic growth and development theories. The analysis of the theories
noticeably conveys the profound basement targeted for country
development through production factors and structural change.
The process of sectoral diversification and increasing
specialization within economy could be found in an idea that dates back
to the oldest development theorists. Structural change models and their
representatives provide profound ideas that structural changes are
needed for the country targeted to reach self-sustained development.
According to those theories, development could be reached only by
transferring a traditional agriculture sector to the manufacturing
sector and then to the diversified sector of services. Another
implication considers common structural change patterns of development
showing that each country has to overcome in order to reach sustainable
development.
To conclude, even though development and economic growth theories
may seem contradictory, each of them put emphasis on specific driving
forces or factors of economic development. Nevertheless, the factors of
production are limited.
The research paper has raised and verified a hypothesis that
factors affecting economic growth at the same time affect economic
structures. We claim that differently developed countries experience
different effect caused by the impact of similarly selected driving
forces of economic growth, which, in turn, differently restructure
rather widely discussed economic structures the treatment of which, as a
respective composition of industrial sectors, seems to us the most
productive from the research point of view, since containing limitations
revealed above.
The research was partly financed by The Research Council of
Lithuania (IEP-01/2012)
doi: 10.3846/btp.2013.01
References
Adam Smith. 1776. An inquiry to the wealth of nations. Scotland: W.
Strahan and T. Cadell, London.
Balkyte, A.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2010. Perception of competitiveness
in the context of sustainable development: facets of "Sustainable
competitiveness", Journal of Business Economics and Management
11(2): 341-365.
Balkyte, A.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2011. The role of migration for
Sustainable developing economy: Lithuania in the EU context, Journal of
Security and Sustainability 1(2): 133-145.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/jbem.2010.17
Bond, S.; Leblebiciog, A.; Schiantarelli, F. 2010. Capital
accumulation and growth: a new look at the empirical evidence, Journal
of Applied Econometrics 25: 1073-1099.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jae.1163
Bourguignon, F. 2005. The effect of economic growth on social
structures, in Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf (Editors). Handbook
of Economic Growth. Chapter 27, Volume (B): 1701-1747. ISSN 1574-0684,
ISBN 9780444520432, 10.1016/S1574-06 84(05)01027-0.
(http://www.sciencedirect. com/science/article/pii/S15740 6 8 405
010270)
Briec, W.; Cavaignac, L. 2009. An extension of the multi-output
state-contingent production model, Economic Theory 39: 43-64.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00199-007-0308-6
Choo, H. J. 1971. On the empirical relevancy of the Ranis-Fei model
of economic development: comment, American Economic Review 61(4):
695-703.
Clark, J. R. 1990. Macroeconomics for Managers. Boston: Allyn and
Bacon, INC.
Ciegis, R.; Ramanauskiene, J. 2009. Sustainable development and its
assessment, Applied Economics: Systematic Research 3(2): 143-153.
Dietz, J. 1983. Theories of development, Journal of Economic Issues
(Association for Evolutionary Economics) 17(4): 1160-1162.
Dong, X.; Song, S.; Zhu, H. 2011. Industrial structure and economic
fluctuation--Evidence from China, The Social Science Journal 48(3):
468-477. ISSN 0362-3319, 10.1016/j. soscij.2011.05.002.
(http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/ article/pii/S0362331911000802)
Eltis, W. 2000. The classical theory of economic growth. Macmillan,
Basingstoke. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/9780230598201
Franke, R.; Kalmbach, P. 2005. Structural change in the
manufacturing sector and its impact on business-related services: an
input-output study for Germany, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics
16(4): 467-488. ISSN 0954-349X, 10.1016/j.strueco.2004.09.001.
(http://www.sciencedirect. com/science/article/pii/S0954349X04000670)
Galor, O. 2010. The 2008 Lawrence R. Klein lecture-comparative
economic development: insights from unified growth theory, International
Economic Review 51(1): 1-41.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2354.2009.00569.x
Grybaite, V. 2011. Towards measurement of sustainable development:
systems of indicators, Journal of Security and Sustainability Issues
1(1): 17-24.
Halkos, G.; Tzeremes, N. 2008. Trade efficiency and economic
development: evidence from a cross country comparison, Applied Economics
40: 2749-2764. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840600970302
Jaimovich, E. 2011. Sectoral differentiation, allocation of talent,
and financial development, Journal of Development Economics 96: 47-60.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.07.005
Karnitis, E. 2011. Strategy and efficient mechanisms to improve
security and sustainability of the natural gas supply in Baltic States,
Journal of Security and Sustainability Issues 1(1): 3-15.
Kazmierczyk, J. 2012. Information technology systems and their
impact on the employment level in the polish banking sector, Journal of
Security and Sustainability Issues 1(3): 187-195.
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money. United Kingdom: Palgrave Macmillan.
King, R. G.; Rebelo, S. T. 1993. Transitional dynamics and economic
growth in the neoclassical model, American Economic Review 83(4).
Korsakiene, R.; Breivyte, I.; Wamboye, E. 2011. Sustainable
development and Human Development Index, Journal of Security and
Sustainability Issues 1(2): 103-112.
Kosempel, S. 2004. A theory of development and long run growth,
Journal of Development Economics 75: 201-220.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2003.08.004
Landes, D. 1969. The Unbound Prometheus. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge.
Lankauskiene, T.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2011. Interrelation of
countries' developmental level and foreign direct investments
performance, Journal of Business Economics and Management 12(3):
546-565.
Lankauskiene, T.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2012. Production factors and
structural changes in economy sectors: genesis of theoretical
approaches, in Conference proceedings "Contemporary Issues in
Business, Management and Education'2012", Vilnius, Lithuania.
ISSN 2029-7963/ISBN 978-609-457-323-1
http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/16111699.2011.599412
Larrain, J. 1989. Theories of development: capitalism, colonialism
and dependency. Cambridge Polity press.
Lee, D. 2006. The Korean Economy in Transition: in Search for a New
Model, Global Economic Review 35(2): 207-230.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/12265080600715475
Lewis, W. A. 1955. The theory of economic growth. Homewood, Ill.:
Richard D. Irwin.
Luintel, K. B.; Khan, M.; Arestis, P.; Theodoridis, K. 2008.
Financial structure and economic growth, Journal of Development
Economics 86(1): 181-200. ISSN 0304-3878, 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.11.006.
(http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/ article/pii/S0304387807001009)
Pisani, D.; Jacobus, A. 2006. Sustainable development--historical
roots of the concept, Environmental Sciences 3(2): 83-96.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15693430600688831
Prescott, E. C. 1988. Robert M. Solow's neoclassical growth
model: an influential contribution to economics, Scandinavian Journal of
Economics 90(1): 7-12. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3440145
Prskawetz, A.; Kogel, T.; Sanderson, W. C.; Scherbov, S. 2007. The
effects of age structure on economic growth: An application of
probabilistic forecasting to India, International Journal of Forecasting
23(4): 587-602. ISSN 0169-2070. 10.1016/j.ijforecast.2007.08.001
(http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/ article/pii/S0169207007000970)
Raiser, M.; Schafer, M.; Schuchhardt, J. 2004. Benchmarking
structural change in transition, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics
15(1): 47-81. ISSN 0954-349X. 10.1016/
S0954-349X(03)00027-4.(http://www.sciencedirect.com/
science/article/pii/S0954349X03000274)
Rostow, W. 1960. The stages of economic growth: a non communist
manifesto. London: Cambridge University Press.
Ruchi, M. 2009. Sustainable development--how far is it sustainable?
Proceedings of World Academy of Science, Engineering & Technology
(51): 754-757.
Ruttan, V. W. 1988. The new growth theory and development
economics: a survey, Journal of Development Studies 35(2): 1-26.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220389808422562
Sarkar, D. 2007. The role of human capital in economic growth
revisited, Applied Economics Letters 14: 419-423.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504850500447323
Saygili, H.; Saygili, M. 2011. Structural changes in exports of an
emerging economy: Case of Turkey, Structural Change and Economic
Dynamics 22(4): 342-360. ISSN 0954-349X. 10.1016/j.strueco.2011.08.001.
(http://www.sciencedirect. com/science/article/pii/S0954349X11000543)
Silva, E. S; Teixeira, A. A. C. 2008. Surveying structural change:
Seminal contributions and a bibliometric account, Structural Change and
Economic Dynamics 19(4): 273-300. ISSN 0954-349X,
10.1016/j.strueco.2008.02.001.(http://www.
sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0954349X08000192)
Solow, R. M. 1988. Growth theory and after, American Economic
Review 78(3): 307-317.
Sonobe, T.; Hu, D.; Otsuka, K. 2004. From inferior to superior
products: an inquiry into the Wenzhou model of industrial development in
China, Journal of Comparative Economics 32: 542-563.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2004.05.001
Stanczyk, J. 2011. European security and sustainability issues in
the context of current international environment, Journal of Security
and Sustainability Issues 1(2): 81-90.
Tanuwidjaja, E.; Thangavelu, S. 2007. Structural change and
productivity growth in the Japanese manufacturing industry, Global
Economic Review 36(4): 385-405.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/12265080701694603
Theobald, R. 1961. Reviews. Toward a practical theory of economic
growth, American Journal of Economics & Sociology 20(3): 327-331.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1536-7150.1961.tb00590.x
Todaro, M. P.; Smith, S. C. 2011. Economic development, eleventh
edition. Pearson Education limited: England. 865 p.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Lankauskiene, T. 2011. Peculiarities of FDI
performance in developed, developing and underdeveloped countries,
Business: Theory and Practice 12(1): 50-62.
Tvaronaviciene, M. 2012. Contemporary perceptions of energy
security: policy implications, Journal of Security and Sustainability
Issues 1(4): 235-247.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Grybaite, V. 2012. Sustainable development and
performance of institutions: approaches towards measurement, Journal of
Security and Sustainability Issues 1(3): 167-175.
Tvaronaviciene, M.; Lankauskiene, T. 2011. Plausible foreign direct
investment' impact on sustainable development indicators of
differently developed countries, Journal of Security and Sustainability
Issues 1(1): 25-36.
Wei, Z.; Hao, R. 2010. Demographic structure and economic growth:
Evidence from China, Journal of Comparative Economics 38(4, December):
472-491. ISSN 0147-5967, 10.1016/j. jce.2010.08.002.
(http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/ article/pii/S014759671000065X)
Willis, K. 2005. Theories and practices of development. Routledge,
Taylor & Francis group: London and New York.
Young, A., 1928. Increasing returns and economic progress, The
Economic Journal 38: 527-542. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2224097
Zhang, W.-B. 1996. Preference, structure and economic growth,
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 7(2): 207-221. ISSN 0954-349X,
10.1016/0954-349X(95)00024H.
(http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/ pii/0954349X9500024H)
Manuela Tvaronaviciene (1), Toma Lankauskiene (2)
Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223
Vilnius, Lithuania
E-mail: (1)
[email protected]; (2)
[email protected]
(corresponding author)
Received 19 November 2012; accepted 10 January 2013
Manuela Tvaronaviciene (1), Toma Lankauskiene (2)
Vilniaus Gedimino technikos universitetas, Sauletekio al. 11,
LT-10223 Vilnius, Lietuva
El. pastas: (1)
[email protected]; (2)
[email protected]
Iteikta 2012-11-19; priimta 2013-01-10
Manuela TVARONAVICIENE. Prof. at the Department of Economics and
Management of Enterprises, the Faculty of Business Management, Vilnius
Gediminas Technical University. Research interests: economic growth,
investment, innovations, economic sector development.
Toma LANKAUSKIENE. Phd student at the Department of Economics and
Management of Enterprises, the Faculty of Business Management, Vilnius
Gediminas Technical University. Research interests: economic growth,
development economics, sustainable development.