Spain: evaluating the effects of macro policy using an econometric model.
Anderton, Bob
Introduction(1)
In recent years Spain has experienced rapid economic development
during a period of increasing European integration. Spanish policymakers
have enhanced their credibility by becoming a member of both the EC and
the ERM. A strong commitment to Spanish participation in a future
European Economic and Monetary Union confirms Spain's determination
to 'catch-up' and converge towards the model of the more
advanced economies of Europe. The National Institute's Global
Econometric Model (NIGEM) now contains a detailed econometric model of
Spain. This note begins with an overview of economic events and policy
in Spain over the last twenty years. This is followed by sections which
describe in more detail the reforms and economic outcomes regarding the
labour market, price and wage determination, the balance of payments and
the finances of the public sector. The econometric model is then
described and the effects of the structural reforms upon the individual
equations evaluated. The penultimate section uses the model to simulate
the effects of macroeconomic policies which the Spanish authorities have
either implemented or may be considering. This is followed by a
conclusion.
Overview
Table 1 shows that over the period of the two oil price shocks, from
the mid-1970s to the mid-1980s, Spain experienced sluggish growth.
During the 10 years between 1975 and 1984, real investment declined by
almost 2 1/2 per cent per year, employment fell by 15 per cent and real
consumption and GDP only grew by around 1 per cent per annum. As a
result, the unemployment rate increased from 3 per cent in 1974 to 22
per cent in 1985. At the end of 1982 the new government implemented
stronger monetary policy combined with rapid restructuring of the
industrial and financial sectors supplemented by policies aimed at wage
moderation. These policies improved profitability and restrained wages
with the result that interest rates fell slightly. These acts were
augmented by further supply-side legislation between 1984-86 which began
the process of dismantling financial and exchange controls combined with
labour market measures aimed at improving flexibility.(2) In particular,
temporary employment contracts were introduced along with rules allowing
easier termination of these contracts. EC membership in 1986 started the
process of tariff reduction and facilitated the introduction of VAT
which, along with a deceleration of public spending, helped to reduce
the government deficit. These policies attracted substantial foreign
investment as foreign multinational corporations began to perceive Spain
as both a high return investment opportunity and a gateway to the larger
EC market.
After EC membership Spain experienced rapid real GDP growth of above
4 per cent for the four years 1985-88. Although consumers'
expenditure expanded at an annual rate of more than 4 per cent over this
period, investment was also a major source of growth rising by almost 11
per cent in each year. Consumption was fuelled by strong growth in both
real incomes and wealth. Real incomes grew partly as a response to
robust employment while wealth benefitted from inflated asset prices
resulting from strong capital inflows. However, a significant proportion
of domestic demand was satisfied by imports which grew by around 14 per
cent over the same four years. This acceleration in imports was due to
both poor price competitiveness, arising from high relative inflation,
and strong demand. By 1990 Spain's current account deficit was
around 3 1/2 per cent of GDP. In terms of counterparts, this primarily
reflected a significant decline in the savings rate of households. This
was not offset by increased savings of the public sector which itself
was financially adversely affected by an unemployment rate above 15 per
cent throughout the second half of the mid-1980s. This caused a
savings/investment imbalance resulting in a current account deficit.
Spain's consumer price inflation has declined substantially from
an average of 16 per cent between 1975-84 to around 6 1/2 per cent in
1990. This reduction was achieved in a period of strong activity with
unemployment falling from a peak of around 21 per cent in 1986 to
approximately 16 per cent in 1990. The decline in price inflation has
largely followed the deceleration in wage inflation which, in turn, has
benefitted from the TABULAR DATA OMITTED vast expansion in temporary
employment in low paid service sector jobs, which has resulted in a
decline in average wages. Trade liberalisation has successfully
encouraged convergence of industrial price growth but price inflation in
services is not responding so well. Furthermore, a poor productivity
performance, in terms of growth in output per head, contributed to
robust growth in unit labour costs in the second half of the 1980s. This
is partly a consequence of employment growth being concentrated in the
service sector which is characterised by a relatively small rate of
labour augmenting technical progress.
Although Spain has made progress in implementing several economic
reforms, many structural deficiencies remain. Further reforms are
required to reduce imperfections in the labour market, to make the
service sector more competitive and to bring the public sector deficit
and debt ratios down to sustainable levels. If Spain is to become a
member of a future monetary union, or even maintain membership of the
ERM, reforms are necessary to enable further progress towards nominal
convergence.
The labour market and price and wage determination
Spain is characterised by a relatively low rate of labour force
participation, particularly for females.(3) Furthermore, over the last
20 years most G7 countries have had rising participation rates but Spain
has remained fairly static. However, this was associated with a period
of economic stagnation in Spain (mid-1970s to mid-1980s) which possibly
resulted in 'discouraged worker' effects. The period of
stronger growth from 1986 has increased total participation slightly but
this masks strong differences between ages and genders. From 1986 adult
female participation rose strongly whereas adult male participation
remained static and male youth participation continued on a strong
downward trend. The latter is probably related to the particularly high
unemployment rates for this category, the type of employment growth over
this period and barriers to entry into permanent employment.
Spain is characterised by a labour market with a fairly strict
segmentation into permanent and temporary labour. Table 2 shows that a
high proportion of the rapid employment growth from 1986 onwards was
concentrated in the temporary sector. At the end of 1987 temporary
employment accounted for 17 per cent of total employment. By 1991 it had
risen to 32 per cent with most of the new temporary employment
concentrated in low paid jobs in the service sector. The Employment
Promotion Programmes (EPP) and other legislation easing the restrictions
on the adoption of temporary contracts began around 1984 and explains
the growth in temporary work. One component of the EPPs encouraged
employment of temporary workers via relatively lower employer social
security contributions and much lower termination payments for fixed
contract workers relative to permanent labour. In the case of permanent
worker dismissals the law provides for compensation, TABULAR DATA
OMITTED depending upon the size of firm, of between 20 and 45 days pay
for each year worked. This, in turn, encourages low turnover of
permanent employees with the result that redundancy payments average
around two years of salary. The EPPs allowed firms to avoid the higher
firing costs and rigid rules regarding permanent workers by introducing
fixed-term employment contracts of six months duration that could be
renewed for up to a period of three years.(4) The EPP therefore
satisfied a demand for flexible low-cost labour. Furthermore, the rise
in adult female labour participation showed that, combined with changing
attitudes towards working women, there was a sufficient supply of this
type of labour.
The Spanish economy seems to be characterised by both high wage
inflation and high unemployment. Table 3 shows unemployment by age,
gender and duration. It is clear that over 50 per cent of the unemployed
have been without jobs for more than a year which indicates a high
degree of unemployment persistence. Furthermore, prime age males, who
dominate employment in the permanent sector and would probably put the
most downward pressure on wage inflation, have a lower unemployment rate
compared to the other categories. In addition, strong growth regions
dominate wage bargaining and the resulting wage settlements are emulated
by low activity regions. As a consequence, wages do not seem to respond
strongly to local unemployment or productivity conditions hence the
dispersion of regional wage relativities is limited. Many of these
factors encourage a high degree of real wage rigidity and the economy
gets locked into a high inflation-high unemployment trajectory.(5)
The high unemployment rate may also be the result of a high
sustainable rate of unemployment. Labour market mismatch and a high
replacement ratio are often cited as the major structural impediments to
low unemployment. One reason for a skills mismatch is that temporary
workers eventually become unemployed as employers want to stop these
workers becoming permanent employees and avoid paying the higher fixed
costs. Consequently, training and skills acquired during temporary
employment are often wasted particularly given the high incidence of
long-term unemployment. Furthermore, difficulties in matching workers
and jobs are compounded by the official public employment offices
(INEM). INEM do not offer an efficient job placement service as their
work is dominated by the distribution of unemployment benefit to the
large numbers of unemployed. In addition, Bentolila and Blanchard (1990)
argue that improvements in unemployment benefit in Spain explain a
substantial fall in job search.(6) Unemployment benefit is approximately
80 per cent of the last wage for the first six months of unemployment
declining to 70 per cent for the next six months.
Table 3. Unemployment by age, gender and duration
1975 1980 1985 1991
Total unemployment 4.3 11.1 21.2 16.3
Males:
Adults 3.4 7.7 15.4 9.8
Youth 9.8 23.0 39.3 25.7
Females:
Adults 1.8 5.9 16.0 21.0
Youth 7.8 29.3 51.0 37.9
Long-term unemployment(a) - - 56.7 51.1
Notes:
Adults refers to those between the ages of 25-54.
Youths are 16-24 year olds.
(a) Those unemployed for 12 months and over as a percentage of
total unemployment.
Major attempts to decelerate wage inflation began in 1978 as both
labour organisations and the government agreed a formula for wage
indexation incorporating ex ante price expectations based on declining
inflation targets. But these agreements came to an end in 1987 as trade
unions felt that government inflation targets were far too ambitious.
However, Table 4 shows that wage TABULAR DATA OMITTED inflation has
actually declined most rapidly since 1985. High unemployment explains
some of this fall but the major reason may be compositional. The rapid
movement towards temporary work, which has been primarily female and in
the low-paid service sector, has resulted in a downward movement in
nominal compensation per employee during the period of rapid growth
between 1986 and 1989. More recently earnings growth has remained fairly
buoyant even though unemployment is currently high and GDP growth is
declining. This may be partly explained by the fact that temporary
workers are usually the first to lose their jobs in a downturn thereby
changing the composition of employment back towards more highly paid
permanent workers.(7)
Unit labour costs throughout the whole economy did not show much
deceleration during the upturn in the second half of the 1980s as
productivity growth was not very impressive given the strength of output
growth. But Table 4 shows that manufacturing unit labour costs
decelerated more rapidly. In addition, price inflation followed wage
inflation in a downward direction. The GDP deflator declined from a
growth rate of almost 16 per cent between 1975-84 to around 7 per cent
in the second half of the decade. However, the exchange rate played a
considerable part in dampening price inflation as strong TABULAR DATA
OMITTED capital inflows put upward pressure on the exchange rate from
1985 onwards.
Table 5 shows Spain's comparative consumer price inflation
performance vis-a-vis fellow EMS members. It is apparent that in the
second half of the 1980s the total inflation differential has
substantially narrowed. However, manufactured goods inflation has
virtually converged to the EMS average. It is inflation in the service
sector which is preventing convergence of total inflation, but some
progress has been made in reducing distortions. Spain, in compliance
with EC directives, introduced a new competition law in 1989 which
forbids agreements which jeopardise competition. The resulting court
cases primarily concern the service sector (e.g. against unreasonable
commissions charged by banks, or repair tariffs and profit margins in
second hand vehicle sales and so on). The deregulation of the insurance
market in 1992 was partly in response to insurance premiums rising so
rapidly. Distortions in the property market have restricted the supply
of urban land which has also forced prices upwards. The inevitable
rental and home price inflation feeds into wage claims. Public sector
wage inflation has also frequently outstripped private sector pay
therefore encouraging higher wage claims in the latter sector.
However, the Spanish authorities have taken action on a macro scale
in an attempt to achieve lower inflation. ERM membership should help to
reduce inflationary TABULAR DATA OMITTED expectations and Spain's
commitment to EMU should encourage bargaining groups to realise that
nominal convergence is a necessity. Furthermore, Spain's plans to
implement legislation to create a Bundesbank-style independent central
bank should give greater priority to inflation reduction. EC membership
has exposed Spanish domestic producers to a greater degree of foreign
competition. The resulting downward pressure on both profit margins and
costs has encouraged inflation convergence, particularly in
manufacturing.
Balance of payments
Table 6 shows that Spain's current account deficit averaged
around 2.5 per cent of GDP between 1980-82 but then moved into a
similarly sized surplus over the next 5 years to 1987. This improvement
was largely attributable to the trade account which benefitted from
improvements in competitiveness resulting from a prolonged period of
exchange-rate depreciation and weak domestic demand. Chart 3 shows that
an 8 per cent depreciation of the peseta in December 1982 was followed
by further decline in the next year amounting to a 23 per cent
depreciation against the dollar and a nominal effective depreciation of
over 15 per cent. Total exports responded dramatically, rising in volume
terms by 17 per cent in 1984 whereas total import volumes remained flat
in the same year. Imports remained generally subdued from 1982-85 not
only due to domestic competitiveness gains but also because of subdued
domestic activity. Exports also seemed to benefit from weak internal
demand probably as a result of redirection of production from domestic
markets to overseas. The invisibles account, particularly tourism
receipts, also contributed to the improvement in the current account up
to 1987. In 1986 tourism brought in 12 billion dollars of foreign
exchange and comprised the largest component of the invisibles surplus.
However, from 1987 onwards the current balance again began to
deteriorate, moving from a surplus of over 2 per cent of GDP in 1986 to
a 3 per cent deficit in 1992. This reflected several factors; a loss in
competitiveness resulting from a rise in the real exchange rate, strong
domestic demand and a dramatic reduction in import tariffs after joining
the EC in January 1986.(8) This rise in the real exchange rate primarily
reflected a nominal peseta appreciation resulting from the relaxation of
constraints governing Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) inflows. These
constraints were lifted in mid-1985 and TABULAR DATA OMITTED FDI inflows
were further encouraged by Spain's entry into the EC. However, a
large proportion of FDI were short-term in nature. Net long-term capital
inflows only began to grow strongly towards the end of the 1980s. This
has continued into the early-1990s perhaps encouraged by the prospect of
a more stable exchange rate after Spain joined the ERM in 1990.
The rapid growth of real GDP, averaging just under 5 per cent between
1985 and 1990, combined with the process of tariff reduction, provoked a
dramatic rise in imports. In particular, the strength of investment over
this period encouraged imports of capital goods to grow by an average of
more than 25 per cent per year in the years between 1987 and 1990.
Between 1986 and 1989 the volume of total imports grew by an annual
average of 19.5 per cent in comparison to just below 4 per cent for
total exports volume. In more recent years, as domestic demand has
decelerated, total export and import volumes have registered similar
growth rates of approximately 12 per cent and 10 per cent respectively
in 1991. Furthermore, exports of goods are now benefitting from previous
FDI inflows as 40 per cent of Spain's manufactured exports are now
produced by foreign MNCs. However, this may also help explain
Spain's deteriorating invisibles surplus as net factor income
payments to foreigners have increased which partly reflects repatriation of MNCs profits. But the upward trend in the net surplus on tourism has
also flattened out reflecting stability of receipts from foreign
tourists combined with rapid growth of tourism from Spain. This seems to
be a consequence of both the substantial appreciation of the peseta in
recent years and the relatively strong growth in Spain's service
sector inflation.
Public sector debt and deficit
Table 7 shows that the general government deficit on a national
accounts basis (excluding net lending) gradually deteriorated after 1975
but grew worse between 1980-85. The deficit rose from an average of just
over 1.8 per cent of GDP between 1977-79 to an average of almost 5 per
cent between 1980-85. Although this reflected a period of economic
stagnation, and hence slow revenue growth, the deterioration was also
due to rapid expansion of the public sector, improvements and extension
of coverage in social security benefits and subsidies to enterprises. By
1986 the deficit had reached almost 6 per cent of GDP. The accumulation
of deficits caused gross public sector debt to spiral from around 15 per
cent of GDP in 1977-79 to almost 48 per cent of GDP in 1986.
In the second half of the 1980s the government deficit began to
decline somewhat. Strong GDP growth increased tax revenues and
unemployment benefit payments decreased as employment growth started to
push unemployment downwards. Furthermore, the introduction of VAT in
1986, although adding about 2 percentage points to the consumer price
index, caused a sharp increase in government revenues. In addition
several measures were implemented to make tax evasion more difficult. By
1989 the deficit had declined to about 2.8 per cent of GDP and debt had
stabilised at roughly 43 per cent of GDP. Given the stage and strength
of the cycle, combined with the above improvements to the structural
deficit, one would have expected a more substantial recovery in the
government's finances. However, the opportunity to increase
spending on the infrastructure afforded by strong growth was given
greater priority and the policy of deficit reduction was diluted from
1988. The deceleration in GDP growth in 1990 and 1991 has put renewed
upward pressure on the deficit which is now close to 5 per cent of GDP
and the debt ratio is rapidly approaching 50 per cent.(9)
The options available for reduction and stabilisation of the deficit
are limited. Public expenditure may be difficult to reduce as it is
already small as a proportion of GDP by international standards.
However, budgetary decentralisation has allowed a large borrowing
requirement to develop among the regional authorities amounting to about
1 per cent of GDP. More effective control of regional public spending
may be able to decrease the deficit. Employers' social security
contributions are already high by European standards and it would not be
wise to increase them further particularly when unemployment is so high.
But further advances concerning the reduction of tax evasion are
possible. Tax evasion not only decreases tax revenue but reduces the
effectiveness of fiscal policy. Given that ERM membership requires
greater use of fiscal policy for demand management, because monetary
policy is primarily devoted to maintaining the exchange rate parity, the
elimination of tax fraud takes on a greater urgency.
An econometric model of Spain
This section begins by describing the key equations and long-run
parameters of our estimated econometric model. The equations are then
used to evaluate whether the structural changes and reforms discussed
above have had any discernible influence upon the Spanish economy.(10)
Econometric model
Wages. The compensation equation is based upon the bargaining
framework popularised by Layard, Nickell and Jackman (1991).(11) The
equation assumes that wages grow in line with labour productivity and
producer prices in the long run. Wages are also negatively related to
unemployment as the latter is used as a proxy for bargaining power. Tax
wedge effects are only present in the short-run dynamics. The equation
is estimated by instrumental variables as it is forward-looking in
prices. The actual out-turn of inflation one period ahead is used as the
proxy for expected inflation. The dynamic forward term has a coefficient
fairly close to unity which is consistent with the move to ex ante price
expectations indexation from 1978 onwards.
Prices. The wholesale and consumer price equations are a weighted sum
of unit labour costs and import prices plus pressure of demand terms
proxied by capacity utilisation. The latter have positive signs which
indicate a procyclical mark-up. The greater exposure to foreign
competition of the wholesale sector relative to the service sector is
indicated by the relative sizes of the capacity utilisation parameters.
The larger parameter in the consumer price equation (which includes
services) indicates that the excess rent generated in the service sector
allows a substantial variation in the mark-up over the cycle. Another
difference between the sectors is that wholesale prices have a
relatively higher weight for import prices. This reflects the high
proportion of imports of semi-manufactured goods, the large volume of
capital goods imports and the increased 'openness' of the
tradeable goods sector in recent years.
Trade. Exports of goods are assumed to grow in line with demand
(which is proxied by imports of goods of other countries weighted by
their importance in Spanish export markets). The exports equation also
includes a relative price elasticity of around unity and a time trend
which indicates that, other things being equal, Spain's exports
grow by 2 per cent per annum.(12) The import volumes equation has a
large demand elasticity of just over 1.5. But this is not unusual when
demand is represented by total final expenditure as NIGEM has similar
marginal import propensites for the US and UK. The price competitiveness
elasticity for imports is again relatively large at 0.7.
The export price of manufactures equation indicates that Spain's
trade prices are equally influenced by domestic and competitors'
prices. The weight allocated to foreign prices is large compared to some
countries on NIGEM (e.g. USA, Germany and France) but this is to be
expected given that Spain is a smaller country than most of the G7
members.
Consumption and investment. Real consumers' expenditure is
assumed to grow in line with real personal disposable income and is
negatively related to short-term interest rates (proxying consumer
credit effects). However, Spanish consumption seems to be relatively
more interest sensitive than other countries on NIGEM. Total real
investment is assumed to grow in line with real GDP and also has a
negative elasticity with respect to long-term interest rates. An
intercept shift dummy variable with a value of 1 from 1986 onwards is
required to capture the strong investment growth after EC entry. The
semi-elasticity of long rates seems small compared to other investment
equations on NIGEM and seems to reflect two factors. First, interest
rate increases in the second half of the 1980s did not subdue investment
as much as one would expect due to the greater opportunities for
investors from EC entry. Second, housing investment is less responsive
to interest rates in Spain because regulations severely restrict urban
land use and housing construction.
The model and structural reforms
There are several aspects of the above model which reflect the
structural changes described earlier:
First, the compensation specification displays instability over the
post-1984 period. This seems to be associated with the introduction of
flexible labour contracts. We find that the dynamic forecast of a wage
equation estimated using data until the end of 1984 overpredicts the
growth of earnings in the second half of the 1980s. This is consistent
with the fact that the growth in temporary labour was associated with
lower employers' social security contributions and low-paid
employment in the service sector. Therefore, the instability is probably
capturing the change in the composition of employment over this period.
Consequently, we performed stability tests by re-estimating the wage
equation over the whole sample period with the addition of intercept,
time-trend and slope dummy variables for the period after the supposed
change in structure. We found that the intercept and time-trend dummies
were significant with positive and negative parameters respectively. We
interpret this result in a similar fashion to Dolado and Bentolila
(1993). The positive dummy indicates that the legislation which eased
firing restrictions for temporary workers increased the relative job
security of permanent workers. Hence the legislation reduced the threat
of unemployment for this category of workers and put upward pressure on
wages. The negative time trend may be explained by the growth in
low-paid temporary employment which gradually decreased the average wage
as the composition of employment shifted away from permanent workers.
Therefore, in our simulations we use the wage equation incorporating the
dummies.(13)
Second, the investment equation contains a positive intercept dummy
variable to capture the rapid rise in capital expenditure in the second
half of the last decade. This represents several factors which cannot be
captured by the equation. Ceteris paribus, flexible labour contracts
allowed labour demand to become more cyclically responsive and improved
both current and future profitability. In addition, the relaxation of
capital controls, EC membership and the prospect of a Single European
Market encouraged foreign and domestic investment in Spain. Furthermore,
financial deregulation allowed easier financing of investment by
allowing firms greater access to the stock market.
Third, the removal of trade protection, combined with membership of
the EMS, created pressure for Spain's tradeable goods sector prices
to converge to those of her competitors. Chart 5 shows a 'rolling
window' regression of the export price equation and it is clear
that the weight given to competitor's prices, relative to domestic
prices, is greater after the trade liberalisation associated with EC
membership. However, the process seems to have stabilised in recent
years and our equation should be adequate for simulation purposes.(14)
Model simulations
We conducted three simulations using our model of Spain. First, we
reduce short-term interest rates temporarily by 1 percentage point to
get some idea of the inflationary consequences of a loosening of
monetary policy. The latter may occur because continued Spanish
membership of the ERM implies a tendency towards lower interest rates.
Conversely, reversing the signs of the simulation results gives us some
idea of the effects of tighter monetary policy in the 1980s. Second, we
simulate the effects of a permanent reduction in government expenditure
equivalent to 1 per cent of GDP. This allows us to compare the effects
of monetary policy and fiscal policy. This is an important issue as
fiscal policy may have to play a vital role in dampening demand if ERM
membership restricts monetary policy to the exchange rate target.(15) In
addition, Spain's public sector deficit needs to be reduced to
satisfy the Maastricht criteria. If this is to be achieved by spending
cuts then we can gain a rough idea of the effects upon GDP. Third, we
can examine the effects of a 10 per cent devaluation of the peseta
against the dollar (which also represents a 10 per cent depreciation
against the D-Mark). This will give us a valuable insight into the
effects of the recent devaluations of the peseta within the ERM.
In the following simulations nominal exchange rates and interest
rates are exogenous. However, economic interactions between Spain and
the rest of the world are fully captured as the whole of NIGEM is
simulated. It is assumed that shocks are unexpected and therefore do not
influence forward-looking variables, such as wages, before the event
occurs. The final simulation is followed by a brief comparison of the
results with other countries.
A temporary 1 percentage point reduction in short-term interest rates
Short-term interest rates are reduced temporarily by 1 percentage
point for two years and then gradually return to base over the following
year. The temporary nature of the reduction means that long-term rates,
which represent the key borrowing rate for investment, decline
temporarily by a much smaller amount. Chart 6 shows that the increase in
the level of GDP peaks at roughly 0.4 per cent after about three years
and then declines back to base when the monetary loosening is reversed.
Chart 7 shows that an increase in total investment accounts for a large
part of the rise in GDP. The increase in investment peaks at about 2 per
cent after three years and then returns to base. However, the increase
in consumers' expenditure is only slightly above 1/2 per cent
before returning to base. Chart 6 indicates that the extra activity
causes the consumer price level to rise by about 1 per cent after five
years. Consequently the percentage effects upon the price level of an
interest-rate reduction are greater than those for real GDP.
Furthermore, the degree of nominal inertia is evident from Chart 6 as
prices continue to rise for two years after the rise in output has
peaked. The extra activity from the temporary reduction in interest
rates also permanently reduces the government debt/GDP ratio by about
half a percentage point.
A permanent reduction in government expenditure equivalent to 1 per
cent of GDP
Chart 8 shows that the reduction in government expenditure initially
decreases real GDP by 1 per cent in the first year. But this effect
rapidly declines to around 0.6 per cent by the start of the second year
and almost disappears after about seven years. Chart 9 shows that the
decline in the price level peaks at about 2.5 per cent after about six
years. These price effects reduce the short-term government expenditure
multiplier by improving competitiveness and reducing the fall in real
personal disposable income. Hence consumption does not fall as much as
real GDP and exports and imports begin to make a positive contribution
to GDP. If we compare the results to the simulation above we can see
that a substantial reduction in government expenditure is required to
offset the inflationary effects of a temporary cut in interest rates.
However, the reduction in the government debt/GDP ratio is of the order
of 5 percentage points when spending is reduced. Therefore, the
combination of falling interest rates offset by reduced fiscal
expenditure would help Spain satisfy the Maastricht criteria concerning
government debt and deficits.
A 10 per cent devaluation of the peseta
Chart 10 shows that the devaluation eventually feeds through to the
price level resulting in a return to the original real exchange rate.
However, it takes some time for this to happen--about 4 years for about
two thirds of the increase in the price level to occur--and in the short
term there are gains to output resulting from temporary gains in
competitiveness. Chart 12 shows the effects upon total export volumes.
As mentioned above, Spanish export volumes are quite price sensitive
with a competitiveness elasticity of around unity. However, export
volumes only register a maximum increase of 6 per cent in response to a
10 per cent devaluation as domestic prices rapidly respond to the rise
in import prices. Eventually exports returns to base as the depreciation
of the real exchange rate is eroded by domestic inflation.
Comparing simulation results with other countries
The output effects of a simulation of a 10 per cent devaluation are
reported for the European economies in Anderton et al. (1992). Even
though the simulations in the latter paper also include an interest rate
cut the effects on output for Spain are somewhat larger relative to the
UK, Italy and France. This is primarily due to the large price
competitiveness elasticities embodied in the Spanish trade equations,
particularly for exports. As a consequence of the higher activity, it
seems that the price level for Spain remains higher, and for a longer
period of time, relative to other European economies after a
devaluation.(16)
The effects upon real GDP of a temporary 1 per cent cut in short-term
interest rates is similar to that reported for the USA in the November
1992 Review. However, the US reaction to a monetary loosening tends to
favour the supply-side (investment) more than the demand-side
(consumption) relative to the Spanish response.
Table 6 of Barrell et al. (1993) shows that the fiscal multipliers
for the major European economies are very similar to those reported for
Spain in this paper. It seems that a fiscal shock equivalent to 1 per
cent of GDP changes output by around a half to three quarters of a per
cent for the first few years before declining to zero in the long run.
Conclusion
We have described recent economic events and policy in Spain and
highlighted some of the problems facing the Spanish authorities. Our
econometric model seems to capture several of the changes experienced by
the Spanish economy over the last decade and consequently may be a
useful tool for policy analysis. Simulations using the model were
conducted with specific macroeconomic problems in mind. We found that
monetary policy seems to have strong effects on output relative to
fiscal policy. Spain's membership of the ERM and commitment to EMU
implies interest rate convergence with the other participants. This
suggests a substantial loosening of Spanish monetary policy which may
have inflationary effects. The extent to which fiscal policy would have
to be tightened to offset these effects would be rather severe. However,
Spain's positive inflation diffential vis-a-vis the other ERM
members will depress demand in a semi-fixed exchange rate regime given
the magnitude of the competitiveness elasticities. Hence any required
fiscal tightening will not be so harsh. Furthermore, the competitiveness
elasticities of our model suggest that the recent devaluations of the
peseta will mitigate the severity of the current Spanish recession.
NOTES
(1) This note is an abbreviated version of Anderton (1993). The
latter contains full details of the econometric model used here.
(2) Larre and Torres (1992) provide a summary of structural problems
and reforms relating to Spanish labour markets and wage and price
determination. For a summary of financial liberalisation and the effects
upon the Spanish economy see Galy et al (1993).
(3) In 1990 the male and female participation rates for Spain were 79
per cent and 42 per cent respectively. Whereas in the UK, for example,
the figures are 89 per cent and 68 per cent.
(4) For a more thorough summary see OECD Economic Survey of Spain
(1992) and Emerson (1988) which compare redundancy regulations between
Spain and other countries. Bentolila and Saint-Paul (1992) compare the
regulations governing temporary contracts in Spain with other countries.
(5) However, Bentolila and Saint-Paul (1992) argue that the
EPP's introduced much greater labour flexibility by decreasing
firing costs. Hence the magnitude of the response of employment to
cyclical fluctuations may have increased since 1986.
(6) See Chan-Lee et al (1987) for an international comparison of
replacement ratios.
(7) Although compositional changes in employment may have decreased
average wages the effects upon wage setting of flexible labour contracts
may be far more complex. For example, Dolado and Bentolila (1993) claim
that the threat of unemployment to permanent workers is lower if they
are protected by a buffer of temporary workers with lower firing costs.
Hence this will raise the wage demands of permanent workers. They
calculate that a percentage point increase in the proportion of
temporary employment raises the growth rate of permanent workers wages
by 1/3 of a percentage point.
(8) Larre and Torres (1991) point out that half the difference
between Spanish tariffs and the common external tariff was wiped out in
three years and virtually all quotas abolished.
(9) Cointegration tests reported in Caporale (1993) show that
Spain's government debt to GDP ratio is not sustainable in the long
run.
(10) This section is an abbreviated description of the model and only
highlights some of the major equations. The full model contains many
other equations and identities including complete models of the public
sector, balance of payments and national income determination. See
Anderton (1993) for full details or the NIGEM Model Manual (NIESR (1993)).
(11) A detailed explanation of this specification and application to
Spain and other European countries is contained in Anderton and Barrell
(1993).
(12) The export price elasticity is fairly high relative to other
countries in NIGEM. However, other studies have estimated high
elasticities for Spain. For example, Martin and Moreno (1991) estimate
equations for Spain's industrial exports to the EEC disaggregated by commodity. They find export price elasticities as high as 3 for
sectors such as textiles, leather and clothing.
(13) It is possible that this latter effect may be cyclical as
temporary workers will probably account for most of the job losses in a
downturn given that firing costs are much lower for fixed contract
workers relative to those on permanent contracts. However, our wage
equation stability tests did not indicate cyclical effects as the dummy
variable for unemployment was not significant. In contrast, Bentolila
and St. Paul (1992) estimate a model which contains significant cyclical
effects.
(14) For a thorough analysis of the effects of EC membership and the
European Single Market Act upon Spanish trade see Vinals et al (1990).
(15) See European Economy--One Market, One Money for a description of
the possible requirements of fiscal policy within a monetary union.
(16) The effects of a devaluation for the major European economies
are also analysed in Box 2 of the World Economy Chapter in the May 1992
National Institute Economic Review.
REFERENCES
Anderton, R., Barrell, R., in't Veld, J.W. and Pittas, N.
(1992), 'Forward-looking wages and nominal inertia in the
ERM', National Institute Economic Review, no. 141, August.
Anderton, R. (1993), 'Spain: evaluating the effects of policy
using an Econometric Model', National Institute Discussion Paper
(forthcoming).
Anderton, R. and Barrell, R. (1993), 'The ERM and structural
change in European labour markets: a study of 10 countries',
National Institute Discussion Paper no. 40.
Barrell, R., Sefton, J. and in't Veld, J.W. (1993),
'Interest rates, exchange rates and fiscal policy in Europe: the
implications of Maastricht', National Institute Discussion Paper
no. 44.
Bentolila, S. and Blanchard, O. (1990), 'Spanish
unemployment', Economic Policy, 10, pp. 233-281.
Bentolila, S. and Saint-Paul, G. (1992), 'The macroeconomic
impact of flexible labour contracts: an application to Spain',
Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper no. 596.
Caporale, G. (1993), 'Some stochastic implications of the
government budget constraint: an empirical analysis', paper
presented at the Applied Economics Association Conference on Budgetary
Policy Modelling, April 1993.
Chan-Lee, J., Coe, D. and Prywes, M. (1987), 'Microeconomic
changes and macroeconomic wage disinflation in the 1980s', OECD
Economic Studies, no. 8, Spring, pp. 121-57.
Commission of the European Communities (1990), 'One market, one
money: an evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an
economic and monetary union', European Economy, no. 44, October.
Dolado, J. and Bentolila, S. (1993), 'Who are the insiders? Wage
setting in Spanish manufacturing firms', CEPR Discussion Paper no.
754.
Emerson, M. (1988), 'Regulation or deregulation of the labour
market: policy regimes for the recruitment and dismissal of employees in
the industrialised', European Economic Review, no. 32, pp. 775-817.
Galy, M., Pastor, G. and Pujol, T. (1993), 'Spain: Converging
with the European Community', IMF Occasional Paper no. 101.
Larre, B. and Torres, R. (1991), 'Is convergence a spontaneous
process? The experience of Spain, Portugal and Greece', OECD
Economic Studies, no. 16, Spring.
Larre, B. and Torres, R. (1992), 'Real and nominal convergence
in the EMS: the case of Spain, Portugal and Greece', in Economic
Convergence and Monetary Union in Europe, edited by R. Barrell, Sage
publications.
Layard, R., Nickell, S. and Jackman, R. (1991), Unemployment:
Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market, Oxford University
Press.
Martin, C. and Moreno, L. (1991), 'Spain's industrial
exports to the EEC: a panel data approach', CEPR Discussion Paper
no. 521.
NIESR (1993), NIGEM Model Manual, November.
OECD (1989), 'Economies in transition; structural adjustment in
OECD countries'.
OECD (1992), Economic Survey of Spain 1992.
OECD (1993), Economic Survey of Spain 1993.
Vinals, J. et al (1990), 'Spain and the 'EEC cum 1992'
shock', CEPR Discussion Paper no. 388.