Full employment in a market economy.
Britton, Andrew
Introduction
The occasion for this conference is the 50th anniversary of the white
paper on Employment Policy, Cmnd. 6527, presented by the Minister of
Reconstruction to Parliament in May 1944. It is a short paper, just 31
pages long, and much of that length is devoted to the special
difficulties in the labour market that were expected during the
transition from war to peace. The detailed policy proposals set out in
the white paper were not implemented in quite the way that was foreseen.
Nevertheless this slim document did signal a new approach to economic
policy quite different to the approach of governments pre-war. The most
important sentence is the first: 'The Government accept as one of
their primary aims and responsibilities the maintenance of a high and
stable level of employment after the war'. The paper would have
been a landmark in the history of economic policy if it had said no more
than that.
To understand the significance of the commitment contained in the
white paper, we should turn to a very influential book, also published
in 1944: 'Full Employment in a Free Society' by William
Beveridge. There we can find the reason for the commitment being made
and also a fuller account of the methods by which it was hoped that full
employment would be maintained. That will be my starting point for an
overview of the successes and failures of economic policy, then and now.
Why was full employment adopted as an objective of policy? Why was it
achieved and maintained so successfully for more than twenty years after
the white paper was published? Why has it not been maintained since the
1970s? Should the commitment to full employment be reiterated today?
What does it mean in today's circumstances? And, since there is no
point in making commitments which cannot be fulfilled, what policy
actions should follow?
I have called my paper 'Full Employment in a Market
Economy' to emphasise the difference between the circumstances of
today and those in which Beveridge wrote fifty years ago. Whether we
welcome the fact or not, the organisation of economic life is very
different now from that of the post-war years. There is no question of
turning back the clock. If there is something in the commitment to full
employment which still seems right, even compelling, in 1994, then we
need to face some hard and difficult choices if we are to convince a
contemporary audience that this is more than a political slogan.
Post-war consensus
The long periods of high unemployment between the wars had been the
cause of poverty of a kind we no longer know in this country. The
unemployed and their families had experienced severe hardship, even
hunger. One of the main concerns of Beveridge and of the wartime
coalition government was that a social security system should be
established which would prevent this happening again. Such provision, it
was recognised, would be difficult to finance unless the level of
unemployment was kept low. But that was not the main reason for making
the commitment to full employment.
To quote Beveridge: 'Idleness is not the same as want, but a
separate evil, which men do not escape by having an income. They must
also have the chance of rendering useful service and of feeling that
they are doing so'. He also wrote 'A person who has difficulty
in buying the labour that he wants suffers inconvenience or reduction of
profits. A person who cannot sell his labour is in effect told that he
is of no use. The first difficulty causes annoyance or loss. The other
is a personal catastrophe'.
He gave three further reasons why full employment should be
maintained: to prevent the growth of restrictive practices; to make
structural change in the economy more acceptable; and to provide a
stimulus to technical progress and the more productive use of labour. No
doubt behind this lay also a profound unease as to the political
implications of high unemployment. On the title page of his book
Beveridge put the quotation 'misery generates hate'. That had
indeed been the experience of the inter-war years. The rise of the
dictatorships owed much to the perceived failure of liberal democracies
to provide prosperity and jobs. It had to be demonstrated that a free
society was capable of delivering full employment. The alternative to a
free society was to imitate either Nazi Germany or Soviet Russia. The
political consensus over economic policy after the war rested on the
belief that full employment was essential to the survival of the
freedoms that were believed to be fundamental by all the major political
parties, and which the war had been fought to preserve.
The importance of wartime experience should never be underestimated
as an explanation of post-war economic policies. In war, of course, full
employment had been achieved. Useful work was found for everyone as part
of a national effort, even those who had been thought unemployable turned out to be good soldiers or munitions workers after all. It could
all be put down to good planning and a general willingness to
co-operate. Workers and management found themselves, most of the time at
least, on the same side. Much of economic life was regulated in the
interests of the war effort, and despite some absurdities, regulation
seemed to work well. The stimulus for efficiency or initiative came
mainly from the need to serve a common purpose. Those who made profits
for themselves were regarded as selfish and antisocial. The sense of a
common purpose remained after the war was won and helped to support the
continued existence of regulations and restrictions on economic life
which might otherwise have been found to be intolerable.
Beveridge was well aware of the need for voluntary co-operation if
full employment was to be made compatible with economic freedom. He
wrote: 'The degree of liberty.. which can be left to agencies
independent of the State, without imperilling the policy of full
employment, depends on the responsibility and public spirit with which
those liberties are exercised. There is no reason to doubt that that
responsibility and public spirit will be forthcoming'.
But the main requirement for full employment, according to the white
paper or to Beveridge, was neither regulation nor public spirit; these
on their own would not be sufficient. What was essential, according to
the post-war intellectual consensus, was an adequate level of aggregate
demand. The diagnosis put forward by Maynard Keynes of the cause of
unemployment between the wars led to an obvious prescription. The second
paragraph of the white paper begins thus: 'A country will not
suffer from mass unemployment so long as the total demand for its goods
and services is maintained at a high level'. The implications of
this are set out later in the paper: 'The Government are prepared
to accept in future the responsibility for taking action at the earliest
possible stage to avert a threatened slump. This involves a new approach
and a new responsibility for the State'.
The new approach is well described by Beveridge as the creation of a
'seller's market' for labour. He defined full employment
as being a state in which there were 'more vacant jobs than
unemployed men'. Moreover these should be 'jobs at fair wages
of such a kind, and so located that the unemployed men can reasonably be
expected to take them'. It is important to recognise that this is
what full employment meant for Beveridge: not a state of balance or
equilibrium in the labour market, but rather a state of labour scarcity,
so that anyone who wanted work would not have to look for long to find
it. Of course he realised the danger of inflation in such a situation,
but he relied on the public spirit and responsibility of employers and
especially of trade unions to keep this tendency in check.
The main instruments for securing an adequate level of demand were
according to Beveridge to be extra public spending, both current and
capital, and the regulation of private investment by a National
Investment Board. He criticised the white paper as too timid, in its
reluctance to intervene in the private sector and for its continuing
concern with the scale of public sector debt. Very little was said
either by Beveridge or in the white paper about monetary policy. It was
widely believed at the time that the rate of interest had little effect
on saving or investment. Hence it was on fiscal policy that the
architects of full employment relied for the management of aggregate
demand.
Demand management was the main post-war policy innovation that
supported the commitment to full employment, but it was not the only
one. The white paper also discussed regional or local unemployment and
proposed to tackle it in three ways: by encouraging firms to locate in
'development areas'; by removing obstacles to labour mobility;
and by providing facilities for training.
Looking back 50 years later we cannot but admire the courage with
which the commitment to full employment was made. It was by no means
clear at the time that the objective could be achieved. Indeed, all
recent history suggested that it could not. In fact the white paper was
quite cautious in its wording, speaking of 'a high and stable level
of employment' rather than the more emotive words used by
Beveridge. And Beveridge himself thought that a reasonable target to aim
at would be 3 per cent unemployment, or 550 thousand. 'This margin
would consist of a shifting body of short-term unemployed who could be
maintained without hardship by unemployment insurance'. In fact
unemployment was below that level throughout the 1950s and for most of
the 1960s as well.
The years of full employment
In 1964, twenty years after the white paper was issued, the National
Institute published a historical study 'The Management of the
British Economy, 1945-60' by Christopher Dow. In his conclusions he
wrote: 'In terms of its fundamental aim--the desire so to manage
the economy as to prevent the heavy unemployment that accompanied the
pre-war trade cycle--modern economic policy has clearly been a success.
For some years after the war, high employment required no specific
intervention: wartime arrears of demand were more than enough to ensure
full employment. In the decade of the fifties, however, there probably
would have been more unemployment if the government had not intervened
to increase demand when unemployment showed signs of increasing: and,
perhaps equally important, if the world of business had not acquired
some confidence that governments could and would so intervene when
necessary'. He then goes on to point out other economic problems,
such as slow but persistent inflation, frequent balance-of-payments
weakness, and growth rather slower than in many other countries. But he
adds: 'Failure in these respects has been relative failure
only'. At that stage the main emphasis was, quite rightly, on what
went right, and not on the early signs of what would later go sadly
wrong.
We cannot be certain even now why it was that demand remained so
strong for so many years after the war. It was not because the
government, following the teachings of Keynes and Beveridge, borrowed
heavily to finance extra spending. They did not need to, because private
expenditure was buoyant most of the time. Initially private-sector
demand may have been strengthened by the low level of interest rates and
by the devaluation of sterling in 1949. But this is not enough to
explain the continuing buoyancy of expenditure well into the 1960s, by
which time the authorities were more inclined to rein it back than to
urge it forward.
We are concerned here with a phenomenon which affected most advanced
industrial countries, not just the United Kingdom. Initially it may be
attributed to making good the damage done by the war to building and
equipment both in the public and private sectors. The Cold War and the
Korean War stimulated military spending. Consumers for many years were
running down the savings accumulated during the years of rationing, then
borrowing to acquire new durable goods as they became available. The
expansion of international trade was catching up with opportunities
lost, not only in wartime but also as a result of trade restrictions in
the 1930s.
The point I would wish to stress however is that demand and supply
were not matched exactly together by some extraordinary skill on the
part of policy-makers, nor indeed by any flexibility in the workings of
the market mechanism. What seems to have characterised the period rather
was a condition of persistently high, and at times excess, demand. We
did have, as Beveridge intended, a 'seller's market' for
labour.
It becomes important therefore to ask what were the restraints which
prevented wages and prices rising to remove the excess demand, as would
be expected in a market economy. Part of the answer may be with the size
of the public sector, as well as the continued regulation of credit,
foreign exchange, and investment. But I am also prepared to recognise
the importance of what Beveridge called 'responsibility and public
spirit' as a restraint on inflationary pressure. There was a very
general agreement on the priority to be given to full employment, and
memories of the inter-war years were still fresh. In national wage
bargaining there was some recognition of the potential conflict between
the national aims of full employment and price stability. Perhaps the
trade unions did not at first realise the strength of their bargaining
position in a 'seller's market' for labour, or they chose
not to use that strength. Either way, they were contributing to the
persistence of what now appears to us as a golden age. By the mid-1960s
it was already becoming clear that the problems with inflation, the
balance-of-payments and international competitiveness were getting
progressively more serious. Since the early-1970s the commitment to
'a high and stable level of employment', although never
formally abandoned, has never actually been fulfilled.
What went wrong?
I hardly need to rehearse again the history of unemployment in this
country since 1970. The trend has been strongly upward, at least until
the mid-1980s. The fluctuations from year to year have also become much
more severe. For much of the time inflation has been very high and very
variable, although it is low and stable now. The experience of other
countries has been varied, but also generally unhappy. In most European
countries the trend of unemployment has been strongly upward; in the
United States the level has generally been high although the increase is
not so marked. There is no consensus amongst economists about the
explanation of these developments; on the contrary the period has been
one of confusion, controversy and disarray.
It is helpful to distinguish between cyclical and structural
unemployment. There is plenty of evidence that the pressure of demand
rises and falls from year to year and that unemployment moves in
sympathy with that cycle. For example, unemployment fell sharply
following the boom in the late-1980s, rose again during the recession of
the early-1990s, and is now falling again. This cyclical movement does
seem to be related to the adequacy of demand in the economy as a whole,
in much the way that Keynes described. However, this cyclical movement,
troublesome though it may be, is not the main issue. The main issue is
the high level around which this fluctuation occurs, and the dramatic
increase in the average level of unemployment in the 1970s and 1980s.
It is difficult to argue that this increase was attributable in any
simple way to a deficiency of aggregate demand, since it was not matched
by other indications of increasing spare capacity and since it was
accompanied by bursts of rapid inflation. We must therefore address the
problem of 'structural unemployment', or an increase in the
NAIRU (the level of unemployment at which inflation is held constant) or
an increase in the equilibrium or 'natural' rate of
unemployment. But attaching labels to unemployment tells us little or
nothing about its origin, or its remedy. I shall summarise the possible
explanations of structural unemployment under three headings:
hysteresis, sclerosis and skedasticity. If these sound like the names of
serious diseases, that is appropriate enough, because they all represent
something going seriously wrong with the workings of the economy.
Hysteresis in this context means the long-lasting, perhaps even the
permanent, effect of an accident or stress to the system. Thus the
shocks caused by the two increases in world oil prices during the 1970s
each produced a sharp contraction of activity in most countries,
including the United Kingdom, cyclical downturns much larger than those
of the-1950s and 1960s. The hysteresis theories turn on the idea that
the associated sharp rises in unemployment were difficult even
impossible to reverse. For example the investment, the training and even
the technical improvements which should have taken place during the
years of recession may not have been made good, even when growth was
resumed. Another theory of the same kind suggests that the workers made
redundant in a recession lose contact with the labour market, are no
longer protected by their union, are regarded with suspicion by
employers and become demoralised or demotivated. If this kind of theory
is correct we do not need a different theory for the trend from the
cycle. A succession of severe cycles would be enough to explain the
whole story. My own view is that this explanation, although it is
important, is not enough to account for all of the upward trend.
Sclerosis, blames the rise in unemployment on a lack of flexibility.
It is the main explanation given in the recent report published by the
OECD, and in the Mais lecture by the Chancellor of the Exchequer this
year. According to this view the difficulty is one of matching demand
and supply for labour. Relative wages do not change quickly enough to
clear the market, if indeed they move at all. Workers are reluctant to
change their location or occupation, or to learn new skills. According
to this view there does exist a labour market equilibrium at which full
employment would be restored, but the market takes a very long time
indeed to reach it, especially in Europe.
Those who favour sclerosis theories would claim that the problem has
got much worse since the 1960s. The need for adjustment has become
greater, but the ability to adjust has become less. They point to
rigidities introduced into labour markets, especially in Europe, in the
1960s and 1970s. These include increased union power, increased
regulation of terms and conditions of employment, greater job security
(which could ironically increase unemployment by making firms reluctant
to take on new staff) and the statutory enforcement of minimum wages.
The weakness of the theory is that the economy was highly regulated, and
in a sense inflexible, during the war and for some time afterwards; yet
then we had full employment. I am in favour of flexibility, of course,
but I am not convinced that an increase in inflexibility can explain the
rise in unemployment since the 1960s, at least so far as the UK is
concerned.
Skedasticity is a term I have invented to describe those theories
which emphasise the variation or inequality of earning power in the
labour force. Suppose that this inequality has increased for some
reason, but that the inequality of actual wages cannot increase, because
of minimum wage provisions or the level of unemployment benefits. The
result will be higher unemployment. The possible reasons for a widening
in the dispersion of earning power are many and various. Some blame
international trade, especially imports from low-wage countries; some
blame new technology, which benefits the average worker but not the
least skilled; some blame the increased participation of women
especially in relatively low-paid jobs, others blame an actual
deterioration in training and education. The situation could be made
worse by increased competition between firms obliging them to eliminate
any job which is not essential, and to make quite sure that none of
their employees are paid any more than a strict assessment of their
contribution to the business would justify.
I should emphasise that these theories do not suggest that trade,
technology, competition and so on are bad for the economy as a whole. On
the contrary, the point is that they do raise average living standards and average pay, but this means that the minimum level of pay which
employers will offer or workers accept also goes up--and that leaves a
significant minority with no work at all. I suspect that theories which
emphasise the problems of inequality and low skills do explain a good
deal of the increase in unemployment particularly in the UK.
So we do not lack explanations of the rise in unemployment, nor
suggestions for policies to reverse it. As inflation and unemployment
rose from the mid-1960s to the late-1970s the initial response of policy
was to try to repair the post-war consensus. By this stage it was
evident that the problems of rising prices and balance-of-payments
deficits were so serious that the government could not restore full
employment simply by adding to demand. For the twenty years or so after
the war it was possible to maintain a 'seller's market'
for labour, as Beveridge had wished. But this could continue only so
long as a combination of regulation and co-operation kept the lid on
price and wage inflation. The lid was blown off in the 1970s and no
attempt to put it back on again has succeeded for long. We have had to
reduce the temperature, that is to say the pressure of demand in the
economy. A market economy cannot operate with a persistent excess of
demand.
A great deal has changed in the labour market since we last
experienced full employment. New developments of technology, especially
information technology, have transformed working conditions requiring
new skills and making old skills obsolete. The participation of women
has increased and with that has grown the practice of part-time working.
Self-employment has become much more widespread. Job changes have become
more frequent, and employment has become less secure. The influence of
trade unions in wage bargaining has declined, although they still have
an important role to play and still have popular support. Management has
become more scientific (at least the jargon it uses sounds more
scientific) and its approach to employment has become more
businesslike--perhaps because competition between firms has become more
intense. To sum up, we have seen the evolution of a market economy in
this country, much more like the market described in economic textbooks,
and it is in that context that the issue of full employment must now be
addressed.
What does full employment mean now?
Since Beveridge wrote about full employment much has changed, but
much also remains the same. It is still true that enforced idleness
destroys self-respect and that 'misery generates hate'. There
is still the same need to belong to society, to serve and to be valued.
For most people, indeed for more of the population than in earlier
generations, this need to belong can be satisfied only by participation
in the economy, in paid work, part-time or full-time, permanent or
temporary, for an employer or for your own business. High levels of
unemployment have not destroyed liberal democracy as seemed possible in
the 1940s, but they have divided society and alienated a substantial
minority. We have to ask what kind of society we want to live in. I
think that most people would say that they want a society in which
everyone is able to participate, in which there is effective access for
all to work in exchange for an income. The work is important as well as
the income, because it is still true, as Beveridge said, that idleness
is a separate evil from want and that no-one should be told by society
that they have nothing useful to contribute.
Looking into the far distant future we can perhaps imagine a world in
which the need for work has been almost eliminated, a world in which the
machines have taken over most of the jobs now done by human hands or
brains. In such a world if it ever exists, and I am not sure it will,
most of the population would in a sense be idle most of the time. But it
would be idleness of a very different kind from that now experienced by
the unemployed. It would be voluntary idleness, a life of leisure chosen
in preference to work, or indeed a life of voluntary work undertaken for
its own sake and with no financial reward. Because it would affect the
workforce as a whole it would not be socially divisive. It may be useful
to speculate about such possibilities and to consider their implications
for society, sometime in the twenty-first century. But this does not
help us to solve the urgent problem of involuntary unemployment today
and the need for all who wish to participate in economic life to be
given an opportunity to do so.
We cannot be certain that this need to participate will necessarily
be satisfied in a market economy. In the property market buildings can
stand empty for years; in the market for consumer goods some of the
stock has to be written off. If we treat labour as simply another
commodity to be bought and sold, then it is human lives that will
sometimes be written off and declared to be redundant. It is appropriate
to use emotive language, because the issue here is one of feelings
rather than calculation. We want the labour market to be humane in its
treatment of individuals, as well as efficient, and we may fear that it
is becoming less so. This is in part a matter of the way in which
employers and employees choose to behave towards one another, but it is
a matter of public policy as well.
For many professional economists unemployment is the most important
policy issue of all. We see our role as contributing to the solution of
a social problem, not just making the economy more productive. We would
be most reluctant to abandon the objective of full employment, because
it points beyond economics to a goal which is not just increasing
individual utility but also the cohesion of society as a whole.
Setting full employment as a policy objective, even in the context of
a market economy, makes it clear that society as a whole has an interest
in the way that individuals are treated. It does involve the concept of
a community and something which Beveridge called 'public
spirit'. We need, in the very different circumstances of today, to
find the institutional setting within which that common purpose can be
achieved.
Clearly there is no way in which society can underwrite the continued
existence of particular jobs or even occupations. Neither can there be a
right to a job of one's own choosing at a wage one considers fair.
A commitment to full employment will leave many individual ambitions
unsatisfied and hopes disappointed. There will still be closures and
redundancies, but perhaps we can find a better way of dealing with the
consequences. Perhaps we can prevent people being too dependent on the
continuation of a particular job and widen the opportunities they have
to recover from misfortune when it hits them.
If this is to be achieved then in practice something may well have to
be given up in return. The recipe for full employment proposed by Keynes
was in effect a 'free lunch'. By making good the deficiency in
demand everyone could be better off. If, however, unemployment is now a
structural problem then it is unlikely that a painless cure can be found
for it. One interpretation of the rise in unemployment is that society
has given up the aim of full employment because it found the cost in
terms of other objectives was too great. Perhaps no such conscious
choice was ever actually made. If, however, we are now to make the
deliberate choice that full employment is to be given priority then we
need to know what else is being given up. To make a choice between aims
we need to know the means that will be adopted. I turn therefore to the
question of how a commitment to full employment in a market economy
might actually be fulfilled.
There is no shortage of recent studies of unemployment, certainly no
shortage of policy recommendations. In the last two years extensive work
has been done on the subject both by the European Commission and by the
OECD. The latter organisation has produced not one solution to the
problem but sixty. It may be inevitable that international
organisations, which have to take account of the very different
situations in all their member states, will produce recommendations with
no clear single focus. Moreover there is a natural tendency, not
confined to international organisations, to include within the policy
menu a large number of reforms, which could be thought worthwhile in
their own right, but which are at best of marginal value in relation to
unemployment. Those who favour causes as diverse as privatisation,
European integration, or nursery education will want to argue that they
have something to offer as part of the package. Those who are looking
around for attractive ingredients to put in the package will find these
offers difficult to resist. But if we are serious about achieving full
employment then we must concentrate on the search for policies which
will really make a big difference.
Macroeconomic policy
It follows from what I have already written that the problem of
unemployment cannot be solved by macroeconomic policy on its own, simply
by more public spending, by tax cuts or lower interest rates. We have
quite recent evidence of the effects of stimulating aggregate demand. In
the late-1980s, partly as a result of credit liberalisation, partly as a
result of tax cuts, both consumer spending and fixed investment
accelerated. The result for a few years was a rapid growth of output. In
some parts of the country at least there was briefly a
'seller's market' for many kinds of labour, as national
unemployment fell sharply and skill shortages developed. But the
consequences were rapid growth of imports, renewed inflation and an
increase in interest rates. The expansion had to be stopped and there
followed one of the most severe recessions since the war.
We are now in the recovery phase of the cycle, with unemployment
falling again and capacity utilisation rising. Macroeconomic policy
became expansionary after sterling was forced out of the Exchange Rate
Mechanism, and the impetus given by the depreciation and reduction in
interest rates is still carrying the economy forward despite the tax
increases coming into effect this year. There is some purely cyclical
fall in unemployment still to come, but on the basis of past experience
I do not think that the level can be held much below 2 to 2 1/2
millions. Several years of really rapid growth of output, unless it was
accompanied by improved competitiveness and growth of capacity, would
lead only to fresh problems of inflation and for the balance of
payments. There are some optimists who believe that the level of
structural unemployment, the NAIRU or the equilibrium rate (whatever
term one uses) is already much lower than that, perhaps no more than 1
million, thanks to the free market policies introduced since 1979. There
is not much evidence from the behaviour of the aggregate economy to
support that view. I would like to believe it is true, but I shall
proceed on the assumption that it is not.
If structural unemployment is indeed of the order of 2 to 2 1/2
millions then there is not much more that can be achieved by demand
expansion. The management of demand does, nevertheless, still have an
important part to play in a strategy to achieve full employment. As has
already been indicated, one theory of structural unemployment sees it as
a legacy of past recessions. If it were possible to keep the economy
growing steadily, with no recessions, and no unsustainable booms either,
then it is more likely that the damage done by the instability of the
last twenty years can gradually be put right.
A great deal has been learnt about the management of demand since the
white paper was issued fifty years ago. Far more statistical information
is available and econometric models have been developed to improve
forecasting methods. Nevertheless, the record of demand management has
been disappointing. We know, from many years of experience, the
inevitable limitations of economic forecasting, and hence the difficulty
of taking timely action to offset the economic cycle. The white paper
said in 1944 that 'the Government are prepared to accept in the
future the responsibility for taking action at the earliest possible
stage to avert a threatened slump'. I think the government is still
prepared to play that role if it can, and that a long-drawn out slump
could probably be corrected, but clearly it is not always possible to
avert a sharp recession.
Given the limits of demand management it would be very beneficial if
more stability could be built into the economic system itself. A
relatively free market economy may be more prone to cyclical variation
than the more regulated economy of the post-war period. The British
economy seems to have had a more bumpy ride than most other economies in
Europe. Possible reasons for this include the structure of financial
markets and the importance of home-ownership. These considerations are
relevant to the problem of unemployment, and need to be considered in
that context, but obviously more direct action is needed as well, if a
commitment to full employment is to be fulfilled.
Industrial policy and international competitiveness
The foreword to the 1944 white paper ends with the following
sentence: 'But the success of the policy outlined in this paper
will ultimately depend on the understanding and support of the community
as a whole--and especially on the efforts of employers and workers in
industry; for without a rising standard of industrial efficiency we
cannot achieve a high level of employment combined with a rising
standard of living'. The point is an important one and still valid
today.
There are those who believe that the whole economy needs to be
strengthened and reformed before full employment can be achieved. They
stress the need for greater industrial efficiency and competitiveness if
Britain is to participate in the open markets of Europe and the world as
a whole. This broad approach is particularly attractive if it could make
possible an increase in industrial employment at the same time as real
wages were rising. Moreover the potential constraint on growth arising
from the deficit on the balance of payments would be lifted if
Britain's trade performance were improved.
The white paper published by the European Commission last December
puts great emphasis on improved industrial competitiveness as the best
approach to job creation. Implicitly it is assuming that Europe can gain
employment at the expense of other industrial countries for example
America and Japan. (The OECD report prepared for the governments of all
industrial countries jointly on the other hand could not make
recommendations which would help some member states at the expense of
others.) In considering policy options for the UK we must remember that
considerable scope remains for raising our standards of performance and
productivity to match those of our Continental neighbours. Indeed a
considerable effort may be needed to ensure that we do not fall further
behind.
Having accepted all this, it would nevertheless be wrong to
concentrate too much attention in this paper on industrial policy. In
the first place there is no agreement as to the actual policy measures
which are most likely to achieve the desired result of improving
Britain's competitiveness and efficiency. Whilst some economists
argue for a 'developmental' approach, which would involve some
kind of national planning, others regard that with disdain and see the
proper role of the state as confined to regulation--and no more of that
than is unavoidable. I do not need to take sides in that debate on this
occasion.
The second reason for placing the main emphasis elsewhere is real
doubt as to the scale of effects on unemployment which could be achieved
by industrial policy of any kind. One could imagine a successful
industrial policy which achieved its main goal of improving
international competitiveness, whilst leaving the problem of structural
unemployment largely unsolved. The theories of what I have called
'skedasticity' attribute unemployment to the distribution
within the workforce of skills and other characteristics relevant to
employment. If this approach is right we need to concentrate on the
lower end of that distribution, not on the midpoint. It is to policies
with that focus that I turn next.
Labour market policies
We now have a great deal of experience of special employment measures
in this country, and plenty of examples to draw on from the experience
of other countries as well if we wish. The list of schemes gets longer
and longer, although many of the new ones turn out to be variations on
themes which have been tried out before. There have been selective
employment subsidies and schemes to promote employment in the public
sector. More recently the emphasis has been more on help with searching
for work and tightening up the conditions for the receipt of benefit. At
the most, these schemes may have reduced unemployment by a few hundred
thousand each year since the mid-1970s.
Proposals to introduce similar schemes on a much larger scale run
into problems of administrative feasibility. If unemployment was low,
say half-a-million or a million in total, then it would be possible to
consider each case individually, and to show a genuine care on behalf of
society. Training and counselling could be provided on a generous scale.
Every effort could be made to find or to create jobs which are within
the capability of each unemployed person. It might even be right, in
that context, to insist that job offers are not refused. One could
readily imagine an employment 'fallback' provision, even an
employment guarantee of some kind to cope with a relatively small number
of people who for one reason or another have difficulty in finding or
keeping employment. But I do not think that mass unemployment, running
to two millions or more, can be tackled in this way. The task becomes
unmanageable and the expense becomes prohibitive.
It might be possible by something akin to conscription to create work
of a kind for even two million unemployed, but there would be no
question of giving individual attention to the needs or the potential
abilities of such vast numbers. It would mean creating a large
regimented sector clearly differentiated from the rest of the economy.
This is not at all what Beveridge had in mind when he wrote about full
employment. The underlying purpose of renewing that commitment today
could not be fulfilled by special employment measures on a gigantic scale. The social marginalisation and alienation caused by unemployment
would remain, and the need to feel that everyone belongs to the
community would not be satisfied. On a small scale they undoubtedly have
an important part to play, and it matters a great deal how that role is
performed. But they cannot be the main means by which a promise to
restore full employment would be kept.
Taxes and subsidies
In a market economy economic policy works best by influencing
relative costs and prices, by creating incentives for individuals or
firms to behave in a socially-desired way. Thus the burning of fuel
which may threaten the environment is not prohibited or rationed, but it
is taxed. Energy saving is not made compulsory, but it is encouraged by
subsidies. A similar approach could work in the labour market.
The aim is not to encourage employment as such, but to increase the
employment opportunities for those who, for any reason, are likely to
earn wages well below the average. This relates to the dispersion or
skedasticity theory of unemployment. We want to offset the widening in
the range of earning power which seems to be one reason for the upward
trend in unemployment. The Chancellor took a small step in that
direction last November when he reduced by 1 per cent the National
Insurance contributions of lower paid employees and widened the 20p
income tax band. Could the same approach, on a very much larger scale,
be the centre-piece of a strategy to restore full employment?
Taxes and subsidies apply to the population as a whole, not just to
particular individuals identified as requiring individual attention. The
state operates at arms length. No-one has to be identified as requiring
special help; there is no need to interfere in their lives or question
their motivation. Unlike special employment measures, taxes and benefits
can operate on a very large scale without the danger of stigma or
marginalisation.
If the intention is to encourage employment creation then the natural
place to start reform is with national insurance contributions, as the
Chancellor has already indicated. I shall not attempt to go into any
detail, but two general points can be made. The first is that
employees' contributions must in the long run influence employment
prospects just as much as do employers' contributions. The need is
to improve incentives to seek employment as well as incentives to
provide it. If the employers' contribution is cut then there will
be a tendency for wages to rise because the demand for labour will
increase, and if the employees' contribution is cut there will be a
tendency for wages to fall because the supply of labour will increase.
The net effect on labour costs and take-home pay should be much the same
in the end--and both employers and employees would benefit. The second
point to make is that the graduation of contributions should relate to
pay per hour. The intention is to improve the employment prospects for
those most at risk of unemployment, that is those whose earning power is
relatively low, whether they work full-time or part-time.
Whilst national insurance contributions are the natural place to
start, the reforms could affect other forms of taxation as well. Income
tax thresholds could be raised. But if the wish is to focus specifically
on earned income then there would need to be a new form of tax allowance
designed with that in mind. This too would need to be related to pay per
hour--an innovation so far as the tax system is concerned.
Instead of cutting national insurance contributions a very similar
result could be achieved by subsidies to employers, also related to pay
per hour. For the lowest paid it might be necessary for the subsidy to
represent a large proportion of the wage before sufficient growth of
employment could be induced.
One of the merits of a general tax cut or employment subsidy for the
low paid is that we do not have to know in advance where the new jobs
will be created. That can be left to the market to decide, so long as
the state does not stand in the way. My own guess is that many of them
would be in services, and more generally in sectors which do not compete
with imports. This inevitably points to activities, for example health
and education, which are largely in the public sector. If this approach
is to be effective, then employment by central and local government must
be allowed to increase even if total public spending is left unchanged.
It would be absurd to adopt a target of full employment and then say
that the public sector is not allowed to contribute to its achievement.
If the problem of employment is addressed in this way it is bound to
be expensive in terms of revenue; there can be no disguising that. Large
sums of money must be involved if a large effect is to be achieved. If
the reform succeeded in its aim of reducing unemployment permanently to
a tolerable level then there would be substantial savings on benefits
now paid to those out of work. That would be an important offset to the
gross cost of the reform to the exchequer. Nevertheless I suspect that
the net cost would still be large. The political process must indicate
whether society is prepared to pay that cost, and if so in what form the
revenue should be raised. Options worth considering would include higher
NI contributions from the better paid, higher rates of VAT or taxes on
energy. None of these would be popular, but many people would say it was
a price worth paying for full employment. Over a number of years
significant changes in the impact of taxes and spending do take place,
so we should not dismiss this type of policy option simply because the
numbers involved are big.
The benefit system and minimum wages
In the UK, unlike many other industrial countries, the ratio of
unemployment benefits to wages has been falling since the 1960s. If the
rates of benefit were to be cut that might well reduce the numbers of
claimants but at the expense of increased poverty for those who remain
out of work. Most people would consider this a price not worth paying.
The replacement ratio could also be reduced however by paying
benefits to workers on low pay, which would of course tend to reduce
poverty rather than to increase it. Family Credit already does this and
the scheme has many admirers. Some would like to develop this approach
much further and make it a major element in a strategy to achieve full
employment. Certainly it merits careful examination and it is possible
that it is the best option available.
As compared however with the alternative of reforming NI
contributions and employment subsidies considered above it has two
disadvantages. The first is simply that it approaches the main problem
we are concerned with indirectly rather than directly, by focusing on
individual or household income when it should focus on job creation. The
second disadvantage, to my mind at least, is that most of the schemes
considered require some form of means test for the individual or the
household so as to keep down their cost. A relationship of dependency is
unavoidable between the recipients and the state as the donor. This may
be right and proper as a temporary relationship for individuals or
households in times of particular adversity, but it is not so
appropriate as a permanent relationship between the state and perhaps
millions of less skilled workers. I do not think that Beveridge would
have approved at all.
The attraction of paying benefits to those in work reflects the
increase in the dispersion of wages over the past decade, adding to the
prevalence of low pay, often of pay so low that workers gain little
compared to their benefit entitlements. The same increase in dispersion
has not been observed in much of Continental Europe, partly because of
minimum wage regulations.
Where minimum wages are high relative to rates of benefit they must
reduce the possibility of creating relatively low paid jobs for
relatively low skilled workers. The countries concerned therefore face a
difficult choice between better pay and more jobs, with a conflict of
interest between the employed and the unemployed to be resolved. The
issue has, of course, been much discussed in this country in recent
months and I do not think I have much to add to the debate. The main
issue so far as unemployment is concerned is not whether there should be
a minimum wage or not, but the level at which the minimum is set if we
do have one. If it was set high enough to require the wages now paid to
a large number of workers to be raised, then some, though not all, of
the jobs concerned would be lost.
The situation could be helped by the reforms to national insurance
contributions or the introduction of employment subsidies already
discussed. By cutting total unit wage costs for those offering
relatively low skilled jobs the incidence of very low pay should be
reduced. The need for minimum wage regulation would then be less, and so
also would be the loss of jobs if a minimum wage was in fact introduced.
Education and training
I have left until last what is perhaps the ideal solution to the
problem of unemployment. If only we could make the labour force more
productive, then of course the economy would be more competitive, real
wages and living standards would rise, and the prospects for employment
would improve as well. Everyone is in favour of better education and
training, for these reasons and many more.
In the context of structural unemployment however we should look not
just at the average level of education and training but at its variation
across the workforce. It is striking that in this country the variation
of educational achievement is greater than in most other European
countries. In the context of the distribution of 'earning
power' and its relation to unemployment this is an important and
disturbing fact. The widening seems to begin at an early age, with very
different rates of progress of children at primary school. It may then
be self-reinforcing as the children who have not benefited fully from
one stage in their education get left further and further behind. It is
also true that in this country we have been relatively good at providing
higher education opportunities for the academic elite and relatively bad
at organising craft training or vocational qualifications for the
population at large. Public awareness of these issues has increased over
the past ten years and new policies have been introduced. New
initiatives have been announced within the last few months. This is not
the occasion for a critique, but the intention behind these reforms is
clearly to address long-standing problems that have contributed to the
high level of unemployment in Britain.
In reviewing the various forms of policy action which might help
reduce unemployment we must keep in mind the very different time
horizons over which they might be effective. The reform of education and
training for the population as a whole will mainly affect the employment
opportunities of the next generation. That does not make them any the
less important or urgent, but it means that on their own they are not a
sufficient response to unemployment today. If the government made a
commitment to full employmemt it would be reasonable to ask to what time
period the commitment referred. If the answer was well into the
twenty-first century, then the popular endorsement would not be so
enthusiastic.
Conclusions
It is remarkable how support of the objective of full employment has
survived despite the failure for over twenty years to achieve it.
Clearly it accords with a popular perception of the responsibility of
the State and the well-being of society. Self-interest may also be
involved now that so few people can feel really secure in their
possession of jobs. The concerns which led to the commitment made in the
1944 white paper are no less relevant today. A job is still, for most
people, the basis for participation in the community, and to be deprived
of a job is to be rejected or pushed to the margins.
The full employment of the post-war period reflected a condition of
persistent excess demand in the labour market in which inflation was
suppressed by regulation and by restraint in the use of market power. It
also depended on a consensus, not just between political parties about
the conduct of policy, but also between employers and employees about
the priority of jobs as against pay.
Those tacit agreements broke down in the 1960s and attempts to
replace them with the formal structure of prices and incomes policies
have all been unsuccessful. Structural unemployment has developed for a
combination of reasons, which may include the lasting effects of three
severe recessions, a lack of flexibility in relative rates of pay, and a
widening in the dispersion of potential earnings within the labour
force. Since 1979 (but not only because of the change in government) the
British economy has been transformed from a largely corporatist to a
free-market system. This is the context within which a new commitment to
full employment would now be made.
It would be a cruel deception to speak of full employment as an
objective if there were no way of achieving it. My own view is that full
employment is possible, although only at a considerable cost. Some form
of taxation would have to be increased or some form of public
expenditure cut. The sums involved could be large. The question remains
therefore whether political support can be found in the country for the
measures which would be needed. There is no lack of support for the
objective, but the real challenge is to build support for a sustained
effort over many years and for some sacrifice in the interests of social
solidarity.
Steady, non-cyclical, growth, if it can be achieved, would be a great
help, but on its own it will not result in full employment. A successful
industrial policy, if that can be achieved, would also be of value both
in supporting real wages and escaping from a balance-of-payments
constraint. The employment problem could be greatly eased by
improvements in education and training, and for the long term this is
the most attractive solution. But the group most likely to be helped by
such reforms would consist of new entrants to the labour force, so as a
means of achieving full employment, this may take us well into the next
century.
Special employment measures, targetted on the unemployed themselves,
to improve their job prospects on an individual basis, will always be of
value if they are well-designed. But they cannot be expected to cope
with mass unemployment as we have known it since the 1970s. Extending
them to a much larger scale would run the risk of creating another form
of marginalisation, not very different in its social implications from
unemployment itself.
In a market economy the main instrument for increasing job
opportunities for those at risk of unemployment should be incentives and
relative costs. These can be influenced by changes in the system of
national insurance contributions, changes in income taxation or public
spending on transfers and subsidies. The reforms needed to bring about
full employment by this method would be on a large scale and involve
substantial costs to the general taxpayer. It is best to aim as directly
as possible at the objective of creating more jobs, and for that reason
reform of national insurance contributions and subsidies for low-skill
employment seem more appropriate than benefits paid to low income
individuals or households. They also avoid the intrusiveness, and the
sense of dependency, which is always associated with a means test. They
would have to be introduced gradually, and the scale of change needed
could not be calculated accurately in advance. Suppose however that the
reform was continued to the point where the cost of employing the
lowest-paid workers fell mainly on the community as a whole rather than
on the employer. If one went to that extreme then I have little doubt
that full employment would be the result.
There may be other means of reaching the same objective, not covered in this paper. I hope I will have provoked some of my professional
colleagues to continue the debate by responding to what I have said. I
hope that most of them would agree that full employment is a very
worthwhile aim, and that, given a high enough priority, it is an aim
that we can achieve.