Labor markets in Britain and Continental Europe.
Britton, Andrew
This note is based on the discussion which took place at a meeting of
the Members Forum on Wednesday 20th July. The meeting was attended by
business leaders representing the corporate members of the Institute as
well as Institut governors and staff. It also draws on a number of
projects which have been carried out by the Institute and a discussion
with the Editorial Board. Responsibility for the views expressed rests,
nevertheless, with the author alone.
The last fifteen years has been a period of radical reform in British
labour markets. Regulations have been eased and the influence of trade
unions has diminished, giving employers far more freedom to determine
both pay and conditions of employment. At the same time there has been a
continuation of trends towards self-employment, part-time employment and
more frequent job changes. The dispersion of pay has widened markedly.
To the extent that these reforms are not home-grown, they follow an
American rather than a European pattern. At the same time as the British
economy has bee moving to closer integration with the rest of Europe
through trade and investment, and seeking convergence of interest rates
and inflation, there has been a marked divergence in respect of labour
market institutions and behaviour Does this matter? Should we hope that
differences will continue, reflecting different political priorities and
legal traditions? Or should we hope for convergence, perhaps on
something not too far different from the British model? Clearly we
cannot be indifferent to the way in which labour markets develop in the
economies of our Continental neighbours.
Comparing economic performance
Looking at the performance of European labour markets during the
1980s, using macroeconomic data on employment and pay, it is not clear
that Britain is much different from the rest. The large European
economies all experienced a substantial rise in unemployment combined
with continued growth in real earnings. In this very important respect,
Britain followed a European and not a American pattern. If anything it
is Germany rather than Britain that stands out over that period as being
able to sustain a relatively low level of unemploymen without
accelerating inflation. Despite the very different policies being
followed in Britain and in France very much the same aggregate
relationships could describe employment and wages in the two countries
up until a few years ago.
It is now claimed that the greater flexibility of the British labour
market is just becoming evident, in the growth of productivity during
the recession, in the unexpectedly low growth in earnings since sterling
was driven out of the ER and in the sharp fall in unemployment over the
past eighteen months.
All this can be contrasted with the continued stagnation of
Continental Europe. One must be cautious however in making such
comparisons. The timing of the economic cycle is flattering British
performance at present. Moreover it is difficult to judge the
significance of a fall in unemployment when there is not much evidence
of an increase in jobs.
In a flexible labour market one would expect to see those who have
lost their jobs making a relatively rapid transition back into
employment, and for most of the population that would mean into
full-time and 'permanent' employment rather than part-time or
temporary. One would expect the average duration of unemployment to be
correspondingly short. One would not expect to find large numbers of
'discouraged' workers dropping out of the labour force
altogether because they give up hope of finding any suitable job at all.
By these criteria the UK labour market is still not functioning as the
textbooks say it should. I other respects, however, for example the slow
growth of labour costs and the sustained improvement in competitiveness,
the British performance looks very promising at the present time--and it
is regarded with some admiration and envy by the rest of Europe.
There is now very widespread concern in Europe about the consequences
for international competitiveness of labour market regulations and
social welfare systems. Whilst there is nothing new about such
anxieties, they have become mor intense with the prospects of continued
rapid economic development in the Far East and the opening up of trade
with Central and Eastern Europe. Pessimism, especially about the
prospects for unemployment, is very widespread. Although the European
Union is fully committed to free trade, public opinion in many member
states inclines towards protection. The question being asked is whether
labour market regulation and free trade can really be combined. If not
then which way will Europe turn? The interpretation which the rest of
Europe puts on the British experience is very important to that choice.
The contrast between Britain and the rest of Europe should not be
exaggerated. In matters of employment conditions many British employers
set themselves highe standards that the law requires, and of course the
enforcement of law is not completely effective anywhere. There are some
signs moreover that Continental labour markets may be moving in a
British direction. One effect of regulation i to encourage the growth of
'atypical' forms of employment which are not so regulated.
Firms are also finding their way round the regulations, for example by
avoiding redundancies through the encouragement of early retirement or
disability claims. However this method of labour force adjustment is
itself dependent on a generous level of social security benefits, and
that in turn has to be paid for by taxes or by insurance contributions.
The decline of trade union powers in Continental Europe is not as
straightforward as in Britain. The level of trade union membership in
France fo example is very low indeed, especially in the private sector.
Yet trade union negotiations still play a very important part in setting
pay and conditions of work. It is doubtful whether such a system is
viable in the long term, but it i far from clear what new pattern will
emerge. Again the interpretation of Britis experience is part of the
debate. In fact the issue of employee representation needs further
consideration by UK firms as well as by firms on the Continent. The
European Court has ruled that there should be consultation in the case
of redundancies whether a trade union is recognised or not--a ruling
based on legislation dating back to the 1970s and quite unconnected with
the Social Chapter of the Maastricht Treaty.
The Social Chapter
How best can British industry and the British Government use what
influence the have on developments elsewhere in the European Union? Some
would argue that we do best to stand aside from the debate until such
time as our neighbours come t appreciate the benefits of our own way of
doing things. The economic success of the British model will speak for
itself. Others believe that a more effective British voice would help to
ensure that the merits of our institutions are full appreciated--and
admit that we may have something to learn as well. For the present the
political capital invested in the 'opt-out' from the Social
Chapter is such that the issue is hardly worth raising. However that
leaves open the question of the direction in which we should be moving.
The point of the 'opt-out' was not to exclude ourselves from
the counsels of Europe and we shoul be seeking ways of minimizing that
effect.
A fairly typical example of the kind of regulation from which Britain
is excluded as a result of the 'opt-out' is the Young Workers
Directive. Its main effect would have been on paid work done by school
children, for example in delivering newspapers--not a matter of
strategic importance for either economic or social policy (although a
case could be made in favour of the directive on grounds of educational
policy). However there is a widespread belief in this country that
regulations of this kind might be the thin end of a very large wedge. In
particular there is a fear that the ultimate aim of the Commission is to
introduce a common European minimum wage, however much that may now be
denied. Whilst agreeing that the attempt to introduce such a common
minimum would indeed be a serious mistake, one may respond that the
danger is remote. I would be even more remote if the British government
were in a better position t block it.
There is also in this country a widespread impatience with the way in
which the Commission has addressed some of the leading issues of labour
market regulation in recent years. This is independent of the more
fundamental political question about subsidiarity and the extent of
'closer union' which people in this countr really want to see.
It is more like the familiar complaint, heard also in this country, that
officials simply do not understand the business world. The impatience
may be understandable and justified up to a point, but British interests
will not be well served in Brussels unless someone is prepared patiently
to express our point of view again and again. My own view is that
eventually Britain both should and will 'opt in' to the social
chapter, probabl in a modified form. If this is correct we need now to
be considering what kind of social policy would be best for Europe,
including ourselves.
The future direction of social policy in Europe
It is often said, rightly enough, that the history and traditions of
individual member states vary greatly in matters of social policy and
labour market regulation. But it is also true that no country can afford
to be constrained by its own past. None of the various
'models' of labour market behaviour in Europe appears to be
working very well at present, especially if the test is the ability to
sustain full employment. We should be prepared to look at new
'models' as well as old ones.
Four general points can be made which are equally relevant to all
member states The first is that social policy should be designed to
benefit society as a whole. It should help the disadvantaged across the
whole community, the non-employed as much as those in employment. There
must be a balance for exampl between employee protection and job
creation; and it should be concerned with the interests of consumers as
well as producers.
The second point is that the workforce has an interest in the future
of any enterprise which has to be recognised, formally or informally, if
they are to co-operate fully with the policies of management. There is
therefore a need for collective consultation in addition to the need to
respect the rights of individual employees. But equally it is clear that
good industrial relations practices cannot be forced on management by
legislation or directives alone.
As another general point, it should be emphasised that any
regulations that are agreed at a European level should be enforceable
throughout the EU. Provision should be made for them to be enforced,
where appropriate using the agencies of member states, but with
oversight of the enforcement procedures by the Commission or some other
body serving the EU as a whole. Where common standards cannot in
practice be enforced then it would be better to have no regulation at
the EU level at all.
As a final point we should note the ambiguity of
'flexibility' as an aim of social policy. In the short term
flexibility is served by institutions which allow rapid adjustment in
the size and composition of the workforce in a firm o an industry. In
the long term however, continuity of employment may result in higher
levels of training and experience which encourage high quality productio
and technical innovation. In the long run innovation is what matters
most to industrial success, not the ability to cut costs quickly.
The underlying issues facing social policy over the next ten years or
so are likely to be much the same in many countries of Europe, for
example Britain, France, Germany and the Benelux countries. There is
likely to be some spontaneous convergence of practice whatever
government or EC policy may be. This will be especially true of the
practices of multinational firms, as these economies become more closely
integrated. (The pressure on some large British firms to conform to a
European norm is already considerable.) Rules will evolve in response to
the economic environment, and models which work well in one country may
spread to the rest. This is not a process from which one country ca
'opt out'. It will result from a multitude of small decisions
taken by firms themselves.
There is also a good case for encouraging convergence of regulations
in some areas. As European countries compete with one another there may
in some cases b a tendency for the least regulated economies to gain
market share. This will be reduced to the extent that relative wages
move to keep unit labour costs in different countries in line with one
another. But in practice some, perhaps most, of the costs of labour
regulations fall on capital rather than labour, at least in the short
run. The situation is therefore not unlike that faced by countries which
have different rates of company tax combined with free mobility of
capital. When that happens the countries concerned have a strong
incentive t harmonize tax rates, rather than allow competition between
tax regimes to reduc or even eliminate the tax base. Pressure of this
kind will probably make some increased harmonization of social provision
within Europe unavoidable.
A judgment has to be made as to what kinds of regulation really do
affect international competition to a significant degree and which do
not. The deliver of newspapers by schoolchildren for example does not
raise issues which call fo regulation at a European level. Health and
safety regulation on the other hand may well do so, and so may maternity pay. The British insistence on the principle of subsidiarity is well
founded. If the scope of European social regulation is limited to areas
where the need for it can be demonstrated, then it is likely to command
wider support, in this country and also in Europe as a whole.