Lessons from America.
Britton, Andrew
In addition to our coverage of the United States as part of the world
economy programme, four recent or current projects at the Institute
involve comparisons between Britain and America. The main focus is on
labour market institutions, productivity, training and education. This
note draws on this work, and also on a recent visit to Washington to
meet both policy makers and independent economists. It has benefited
from discussion with the editorial board, but consists nevertheless of
my own personal reflections.
Comparisons between economic policies and performance in Britain and
the United States are often informative, and they are particularly so at
the present time. Despite the proximity of Britain to the rest of Europe
and our increasing integration into a single market, it is striking how
closely our experience still seems to parallel that of the United
States. In the heated debate which continues without let-up in this
country about how closely Britain should be integrated into the European
Union, the alternative, spoken or unspoken, which many of the opponents
of such integration, especially those in the Conservative Party, have in
mind must be assumed to be continued development along the American
path. One reason for taking a closer look at the United States therefore
is to see more clearly where that path is leading.
Another reason why the United States is of particular interest to us
in this country at the present time is that the Clinton Administration,
after two years, seems to be almost completely frustrated in its
attempts at economic policy reform. In some respects the aspirations of
the Democrats have been parallel to those now being expressed in this
country by the leadership of the Labour Party. Can anything be learnt
then about the problems which could beset a future Labour government,
and how if at all they could be overcome?
The note is in three parts. The first is about macroeconomic policy,
the way in which fiscal and monetary policies are conducted, and the
control of demand and inflation. The second is about microeconomic policy and the measures which improve economic performance in the longer
run, especially in the labour market. The third offers some general
comments and conclusions.
Macroeconomic Policy
The timing of the recent recovery in America has been somewhat ahead
of that in the UK. They too have been experiencing a very favourable
combination of growth with low inflation. Indeed their recovery has in
some respects been more impressive than ours, with a sustained rise in
private investment as well as rapid growth in employment. The
Administration there, like the Government here, has been taking credit
for this happy situation, without however winning much applause thereby.
Perhaps the time is passed in both countries when the public regarded
the year by year changes in economic performance as being due to the
wisdom or folly of the powers that be.
The Federal Reserve Board conducts monetary policy with a view to
economic conditions generally and not solely with the goal of low
inflation (although there are currently proposals in America to redefine
the responsibilities of the central bank more narrowly). The
Administration has no role in the setting of interest rates.
Nevertheless the conduct of policy in Britain and America is now more
striking for its similarities than its differences. In the early stages
of the US upturn short-term interest rates were raised in anticipation
of inflationary pressure. A very similar approach has been followed
here, perhaps in conscious imitation.
An important difference between the two countries in the conduct of
monetary policy concerns the role of the exchange rate. America, as a
large economy relatively insulated from international markets, is able
to take a relatively relaxed view of a falling exchange rate. Almost
no-one in America cares about the external value of the dollar. The same
can never be true of sterling in Britain; our monetary policy can never
be conducted on a purely national basis.
The scale of public sector borrowing was treated for a time in the
1980s in America as if it too could be the subject of 'benign
neglect'. It has fallen to the Clinton Administration and a
Republican Congress to agree the measures necessary to rectify earlier
extravagance. Fiscal reform may have contributed to the fall in
long-term bond yields around 1993 and hence to the economic recovery. In
1994 however long-term rates rose again. On a much smaller scale,
something rather similar has happened in this country. The fiscal
prudence of the earlier Thatcher years was followed by a miscalculation in the late 1980s which led to excessive public sector deficits for a
period in the early 1990s. This has now been put right by some tough
budget measures, which have cost the Major government much in terms of
political popularity. A Labour Government would therefore inherit a
rather better fiscal position than did the Democrat Administration in
America.
In both countries the constraints on borrowing and on taxation must
limit very severely what action can be taken either in macroeconomic or
microeconomic terms. Many of the ambitions of the Clinton Administration
have come to nothing simply because no money is available to implement
them. The same constraints are now recognised by the Labour leadership
in this country. One could argue precisely how tight they need be, what
ratio of debt to GDP is really improvident, but in both political and
market terms the margins for manoeuvre look small.
Microeconomic Policies
The avowed aim of policy under the Clinton Administration is to
'expand the nation's productive capacity', by encouraging
fixed investment, research and development, vocational education and
training. What most strikes a British observer, however, is the very
limited powers which the Federal Government actually has at its disposal
to influence any of these activities. To the extent that industrial
policies exist in the United States they are operated at the State or
local level, and vary greatly from one region to another. Moreover the
tendency in most States is for the involvement of government with
industrial planning of any kind to diminish rather than to increase and
there are few examples of successful initiatives in recent years.
Indeed, those who favour regional economic policies in America look with
some envy at what has been achieved in Scotland.
The US vocational education and training system still reflects the
needs of capital-intensive mass production methods with only a small
minority of production workers undergoing formal apprenticeships to
recognised craft or training standards. Instead there is a high rate of
participation in higher education and some US universities have
developed close links with industry. Problems of intermediate skill
formation arise because informal, on-the-job training is expensive in
both supervision time and output foregone. This has contributed to
increasing difficulties in the school-to-work transition since many US
managers prefer to recruit experienced workers. The experience of the US
in using university graduates instead of apprentice-trained supervisors
and technicians is relevant to the current situation in this country,
where the supply of graduates has increased sharply. Most graduates lack
the practical experience of those who acquire skills through
employment-based training. They can help to compensate in part for a
shortage of intermediate level skills in the workforce, but it is an
expensive way of tackling the problem.
The proposal for a levy in America to fund vocational training is in
abeyance. The role of government is confined essentially to supporting
the training of disadvantaged groups, such as recent immigrants or those
made redundant. The transition from school to work is a subject of
particular concern in America, as indeed it is here. The Federal
Government is supporting various schemes to strengthen links between
high schools and local employers. It is reported that the motivation and
achievements of the pupils, typically those who are not expected to go
to college, have been much improved by these links. (It is a good
example of the differences between the USA and the UK that a pioneering
scheme of this kind was initiated by a group of hospitals in Boston who
foresaw a need to expand their skilled labour force. Could that happen
in the National Health Service?)
The labour markets of the United States are undoubtedly more flexible
than those of Europe and even of the UK. There is substantially higher
mobility between regions, despite the much larger geographical distances
involved. This flexibility is generally accepted as one reason for the
lower level of structural unemployment in America than in Europe, and
for the creation of far more new jobs in the last ten or twenty years.
One reason for this difference may be the relative weakness and
declining influence of trade unions in America, but a more important
consideration is the relatively short duration of unemployment benefits.
After just six months the unemployed in America are, with a few
exceptions, left to fend for themselves.
Whilst this already seems a harsh regime by European standards, the
mood in America is clearly to make welfare provisions even less
generous. The main group now being targetted are single parent families
which are the main recipients of longer-term benefits. Under current
proposals they may have their period of eligibility curtailed or they
may be obliged to work in return for their welfare payments. At the same
time greater responsibility for operating the welfare system may be
transferred to State governments, whose approaches to the problem will
vary greatly. The danger is recognised that states may simply compete
with one another to reduce the costs of the welfare system to local
industry or taxpayers, with little regard for the implications for
hardship or poverty.
The dispersion of wages has widened quite markedly in the United
States, as well as in Britain, but not in Continental Europe. There have
been particularly sharp rises in the earnings of college graduates and
experienced workers compared with less skilled groups. Various
explanations have been suggested including 'skill-biased'
technical progress, international competition and the decline in
unionisation. These factors would presumably affect all industrial
countries, but in Continental Europe their effects may be reduced by
better opportunities for education and training or by the existence of a
statutory minimum wage.
The debate over minimum wages in this country turns in part on the
interpretation of American experience. Few studies seem to establish a
strong negative effect on employment. However it is important to
distinguish American minimum wages, which are generally low relative to
the median and which are targetted on specific groups in specific
locations, from the relatively high and uniform SMIC in France. The
Americans have not tried to halt or reverse the widening of wage
differentials, which is generally viewed as a necessary market
adjustment. What they have tried to do is minimise its effect on the
poorest groups.
Some success can be claimed for two more positive policy changes in
America. The negative income tax, which is paid only to those in work,
does have the potential to relieve the poverty of families dependent on
low earnings and hence to improve the incentive to take a job. The main
problem seems to be that the assessment is based on annual income, so
that it cannot respond quickly to the needs of those whose circumstances
change month to month. This incentive has been reinforced by job
placement schemes which have had support from the Federal Government.
They appear to have been successful in speeding up job search by benefit
recipients without changing greatly the kinds of jobs which they
ultimately secure.
There is one area of policy where the US administration has much more
power than government in the UK. Trade policy is now conducted more by
the EC than by its member states, whilst in America this is one role
which belongs unambiguously to the Federal level of government. In fact
the most significant policy measures affecting the economic performance
of America introduced in the first two years of the Clinton
Administration have been trade liberalisation, in particular through
GATT and NAFTA, but also through new initiatives in Asia Pacific. Even
under an administration more sympathetic than most to active
intervention by government in the economy, free international trade is
still regarded as the best regime to stimulate growth in America. The
assumption is that a rather small, but extremely productive,
manufacturing sector in the US will continue to benefit from expanding
markets, and that this matters more than the continued decline of more
traditional exporting industries. Moreover they see great advantage to
them, as well as their trading partners, from extending the free market
to internationally traded services. The aim of US policy is to encourage
regional trading blocks, but to reduce the barriers to trade between
such groupings as well as within them.
Conclusions
The trends in America towards greater market flexibility, less
government intervention in the economy and more faith in individual
enterprise all continue unabated. The philosophy of the Clinton
Administration is rather different, and it won popular support for a
time, but its influence is now much diminished.
The American system sustains a very high level of productivity and a
very high standard of living for most of the population, although the
rate of growth has not been very high. For a significant minority,
productivity and living standards are low even by our standards, and the
dispersion of incomes is likely to widen further. Despite its
outstanding performance in most respects the system may ultimately prove
unsustainable because it involves the creation of groups antagonistic to
society as a whole. This possibility is, of course, a source of anxiety
in America itself, and one reason for the political support which the
Democrats enjoyed a few years ago.
The failure to build much on that popular support is partly
attributable to institutions peculiar to America. The separation of
powers between the Administration and Congress, and between federal and
State levels of government, largely accounts for the inability of
would-be reformers to make substantial changes. However, historically
the same Constitution did not altogether thwart the ambitions of
reformers who enjoyed continued popular support, for example in the
1930s. The American constitution does not necessarily underwrite the
existing economic system at all times and in all respects. The failure
to achieve substantial change at the present time must partly rest on
the lukewarm popular support for it, when it comes to practicalities and
increasing real costs as opposed to rhetoric.
The economic philosophy of a future Labour government in Britain
would be similar in some ways to that of the Clinton Administration.
There would be a similar degree of commitment to the market system, with
the same sort of qualifications about the need for a positive role for
government action as well. The aspiration to 'expand the
nation's productive capacity' would be the same, and the hope
that in the process the problems of poverty and social exclusion could
be mitigated. There are sound economic as well as political arguements
in support of such an agenda. (The advisers to the Labour Party and the
Democrats have read the same academic literature on growth theory and
drawn similar conclusions.)
The British constitution allows much more freedom of action to a
reforming government than does that of America. This is true both of
macroeconomic policy (as long as the Bank of England is not independent)
and microeconomic policy (including especially training and education).
On the other hand the need to preserve confidence in international
financial markets is a more pressing concern in Britain, affecting the
scale of borrowing as well as some issues of regulation. But a
determined government with strong popular support can sustain market
confidence where a weaker one would be open to attack.
What the American example demonstrates is ultimately the need for
popular support, not of a party or its leader, but of its policy
proposals. This involves a willingness to accept changes in regulations
which cannot always benefit everyone. It also involves a willingness to
pay for new public expenditure in some areas either by taxation higher
than it would otherwise be, or by reductions of spending elsewhere. The
detailed proposals for a future Labour government are gradually becoming
clearer. The success of the leadership in presenting those plans may not
be crucial to the result of the next election, but it will nevertheless
be crucial to their achievements in office if they in fact win it.