Education and inequality.
Britton, Andrew
This note is based on the discussion which took place at a meeting of
the Members Forum on 9th February. The meeting was attended by business
leaders and experts representing the Corporate Members of the Institute,
as well as Institute Governors and staff. It draws on the programme of
research by the team at the Institute led by Professor Prais the full
results of which will be published in the spring. The views expressed
here are my own reflections, rather than the consensus of those who took
part in the discussion.
Comparative studies of education and training in this country and on
the Continent over many years have shown that the British system has
failed to develop the potential of all but the most able young people
entering the labour force. The recent report of the Joseph Rowntree
Foundation Inquiry on Income and Wealth drew attention to the
exceptional increase in income inequality in Britain since the
late-1970s. In particular the poorest 20 to 30 per cent of the
population did not share at all in the benefit of economic growth. They
say that 'it is hard to overstate the importance of raising
education and training standards for the problems we have
described'. They are clearly right to make this connection.
Tests of mathematics and practical skills show exceptionally wide
variation of knowledge and achievement amongst British school children.
This divergence is amplified by the concentration of resources on higher
education for the minority rather than craft or intermediate level
training for the majority. These are long-standing characteristics of
British education and training, and historically they have not always
been associated with an exceptionally wide dispersion of personal
incomes. However changes seem to have taken place in the labour market
since the late 1970s which have worked in favour of those who have
marketable skills and against those who do not.
Labour markets have become more competitive. This is in part the
result of deregulation: the end of incomes policy, the reduced power of
trade unions, the absence of legal minima and so on. At least as
important has been the change in the attitudes of employers, encouraged
no doubt by increased competition in product markets, both national and
international, indeed forced on them in many cases by the threat of
business failure. Firms have shed labour, cutting out jobs which are not
indispensable to their main business; part of the rise in income
inequality results from the rise in unemployment. Firms have also learnt
how to relate individual reward better to individual promise or
achievement; logically this must tend to widen the dispersion of pay.
The public sector has been in the forefront of both these trends.
Economic theory suggests that the result will be a more efficient
allocation of resources, as the costs of different kinds of labour
correspond more closely to their marginal products. No doubt in the
process some individuals become rich or poor simply as the result of
good or bad luck. That is just a side-effect. The case for a more
competitive market is that it creates the right incentives for both the
employer and the employee.
However the initial wide disparity of skill levels created by the
British education and training system cannot be attributed to the market
mechanism, and there is no reason to suppose that it benefits the
economy as a whole. On the contrary it is a serious handicap, making the
production of high quality goods and services in Britain very difficult
except on a small scale. Inequality also contributes to the burden of
taxation falling on industry directly or indirectly, since a high
proportion of those who do badly at school must end up dependent on
social security benefits for part at least of their incomes.
In social terms the rise in inequality is even more unwelcome. The
most serious social problem is unemployment, which deprives those
affected of their chance to participate in production. But poverty in
work can also be alienating and damage what the French call the
'cohesion' of society. From every point of view we need to
examine the causes of variation in skill levels, with a view not only to
raising average standards but more particularly to raising the standards
of those now falling far behind the best.
Training
In comparison with the Continent we spend more on university
education and less on vocational training. This does not mean however
that we should, or could, finance the necessary expansion of the one at
the expense of the other. The social return to higher expenditure on
training would justify its finance from a levy on industry as a whole or
indeed from general taxation. But the main requirement is a redirection of spending within the training area.
Employers should pay for the more specialist training which is of
direct benefit to them. (They could reasonably expect employees to repay
some of that cost if they change jobs within a contract period after
their training is completed.) Public spending should be concentrated on
basic transferable skills. Within that definition one should include
craftsmanship, as distinct from specialised craft skills. The mastery of
one craft, and the capacity for sustained careful work it implies, is
the best foundation for the acquisition of other crafts later on as
changes in technology require. The basic requirements for skilled work
also include communication both written and spoken, presentation of
ideas and information in an attractive style and so on. Numeracy is of
very general application, as are various levels of computer programming
and use. At present by far the most urgent task for vocational training
is to put right the failure of schooling as it affects the lower half of
the ability range.
The introduction of National Vocational Qualifications, based on
testing competence in performing specific tasks, has not addressed the
main weaknesses of the British training system. By providing
nationally-recognised certificates of existing skills it could help to
raise awareness of their value, provided that the testing is rigorous
and independent. It has not however encouraged the general training or
apprenticeships required by young people entering the labour market for
the first time. Indeed it may have diverted attention from the main
problem, which is a deficiency in basic skills that has its origins in
schooling.
Schooling
In contrast to practice on the Continent, classes in this country are
commonly taught in small groups; each proceeds at is own pace and under
its own steam. On the Continent whole-class teaching is much more
important. The intention is that none of the children should be left
behind in the progress of the group as a whole. It seems that this
approach enables the pupils of average or below average ability to make
better progress than is the rule in this country. No doubt other factors
may be involved as well, but the organisation of the classroom may well
be of particular importance. An Institute project is now under way in 15
primary schools in this country to assess the effects of whole-class
teaching. The dilemma is that it can be undertaken only if all the
pupils begin at least roughly at the same level of attainment.
Some inequality of ability is of course inborn, and in some subjects
it may be bound to increase in the course of schooling. This divergence
would perhaps be minimised if teachers from the beginning of primary
schooling were encouraged to teach the class as a unit, making sure that
even the less able manage to master each stage before going on to the
next. At a later stage, in mathematics and some other similar subjects,
it would appear that whole class teaching will only be effective if the
pupils are taught in 'streams' or 'sets'. This may
appear to be divisive, but probably helps the less able make better
progress than they could if left to trail behind when working 'at
their own pace' in a class of very mixed ability.
Concern about standards of schooling led to the introduction of a
National Curriculum. There is little, if any, evidence that this has yet
got to the root of the problem, despite the great efforts devoted to it
by teachers and their advisers. The main need is not to prescribe in
detail what should be taught across the whole range of subjects. It is
to ensure that no pupil fails to acquire the grounding in the basic
skills of literacy and numeracy without which he or she will be excluded
from effective participation in the labour market.
Conclusion
An unkind critic of British society would describe it as elitism tempered by patronage. Its institutions actually favour the most able,
whilst witnessing to the bad conscience the beneficiaries sometimes feel
about the consequences for the others. Whilst actually rewarding only
the few, the others are supposed to be spared the early experience of
failure. This ignores the possibility that the risk of explicit failure
might provide an effective spur for further effort.
Those who would seek to limit or reduce inequality should ask
themselves which is the best approach. Should we recognise that some
children (and some adults) are more gifted that others (in terms of
potential earning power) and ensure that the less gifted make full use
of the gifts they have - or else insist that everyone has the potential
to be a doctor or a company chairman, as if no lower ambition than that
were worth achieving?
The experience of the last ten to twenty years in this country shows
an increasing contrast between individual economic success and failure.
This is how a competitive market works. But the education of nearly all
children in this country is a collective rather than an individual
responsibility. Economic failure for many begins in the primary school.
That is where the fundamental problem needs to be addressed.