Academic salaries in the UK and US.
Stevens, Philip Andrew
We examine the wages of graduates inside and outside of academe in
both the UK and US. We find that in both the UK and the US an average
graduate working in the HE sector would earn less over his or her
lifetime than graduates working in non-academic sectors. The largest
disparity occurs throughout the earlier and middle career period and so
if people discount their future earnings, the difference will be even
greater than these figures suggest. Academics in the UK earn less than
academics in the US at all ages. This difference cannot be explained by
differences in observable characteristics such as age, gender or
ethnicity. This leads us to conclude that the differences in UK and US
academic wages are unlikely to be due to differences in the academics
themselves, but rather to differences in labour markets generally and in
systems of higher education between the two countries, which suggests
that there is a strong pay incentive for academics to migrate from the
UK to the US.
I. Introduction
There are currently serious concerns about the recruitment and
retention of higher education (HE) academics. As with other public
sector jobs, the HE sector is perceived to pay lower wages than those
available in the private sector (and other areas of the public sector).
The concern over labour shortages in the sector has increased in recent
years, particularly in areas such as business, economics and
engineering. When one takes into account the present government's
aims for the expansion of HE, the problem of labour shortages is likely
only to get worse.
The education sector is an international one. One quarter of
academic staff moves within the HE sector are to higher education
institutions (HEIs) outside the UK (Stevens, 2004). Much of this
movement is made up of non-UK nationals (63 per cent of academics who
move to an HEI abroad are non-UK nationals). This is because non-UK
academics working in UK HEIs are more than three times as likely to move
to HEIs in other countries as UK nationals. Nevertheless, the US is by
far the most popular destination for UK academic migrants, representing
the destination of over one third of staff who move to an HEI abroad.
(1)
The subject of this paper is differences in earnings. Obviously,
pay is only one of many factors which influence the decision to enter
and remain in academe and to move between academic institutions. It may
be expected that international moves have similar determinants to
intra-national moves: academics may move, for example, because they seek
promotion, higher pay, a more highly ranked institution or a better
quality of life. However, international moves are more problematic
because they entail more unknowns, both about the employment market and
about non-work aspects. At the same time, there are well-trod career
paths, entailing permanent and temporary moves abroad.
We begin our study by reviewing some evidence regarding recruitment
and retention difficulties in UK HE and previous international
comparisons of academic salaries. The latter section is brief because
previous work is scanty.
2. Evidence of recruitment and retention difficulties
Recruitment and retention difficulties for academic staff in higher
education appear to be recent phenomena. Certainly, the literature
pointed to few concerns in the UK about the ability of universities to
recruit and retain academic staff during the 1970s and 1980s (HEFCE,
2003), (2) with the exception of concern about a potential retirement
crisis. The issue became more prominent during the 1990s and evidence,
based on the difficulties reported by university human resource
specialists, suggests that difficulties have grown over the last decade.
With respect to retirement, concern that the age profile of
academics in many disciplines was sharply skewed towards those close to
retirement was causing concern in the early 1980s and the 1990s (UGC,
1984; Keep, Storey and Sisson, 1996). However, the age profile of
academics is generally similar to that of the workforce as a whole
(PREST, 2000), although analysis of the age structures of departments
shows considerable variation, with the proportion of staff set to retire
in the next five years ranging from under 10 per cent to over 25 per
cent (UCEA, 2002).
In more recent years, evidence has emerged of HEIs experiencing
difficulties recruiting and retaining academic staff (see, for example,
Bett, 1999 and HEFCE, 2003). As might be expected, difficulties are not
uniform and vary by institution, location, subject, grade and contract,
and also vary by type of individual. At the end of the 1980s the only
area where there were major difficulties was engineering and technology
(Pearson et al., 1990). Even by 1998, there were still not widespread
problems with recruitment and retention, although the number of areas in
which difficulties existed had increased (Bett, 1999). Problematic areas
included recruitment and retention in business subjects, IT, electronic
engineering and some rarer specialisms, and in the recruitment of
academics with professional experience (e.g. in law, health studies and
teaching). (3) Other areas suffering problems with retention included
researchers and teaching staff on fixed-term contracts (Bett, 1999).
Recruitment problems were sharpest in the old universities, in the
South-East (excluding London) and in the West Midlands.
However, over the next few years reported recruitment and retention
problems intensified and became more widespread. Based on HEI human
resource specialists reports of recruitment and retention, UCEA (2002)
pointed to a considerable increase in recruitment and retention
difficulties for both academic and support staff since 1998. Around one
in five institutions reported experiencing difficulties filling academic
positions in 2001 (18.1 per cent), compared to one in twenty in 1998
(5.8 per cent). The subject areas causing the most problems were similar
to those in the Bett Report, but had expanded. They now included
computing/IT, business subjects (accountancy/finance, business/
management, law and economics), engineering, science subjects
(biological sciences, chemistry and physics), nursing/midwifery and
professions allied to medicine and education. The increase in retention
difficulties was of a similar magnitude, with 7.6 per cent reporting
retention difficulties 'most of the time' or more in 2001,
compared to 2.2 per cent in 1998. Institutions reported that lecturers
were the most difficult to recruit, with almost 60 of all institutions
reporting difficulties. The percentage reporting difficulties in
recruiting lecturers was similar in new and old universities, but lower
in colleges. More old universities than new found it difficult to
recruit professors and research assistants.
Recruitment and retention problems were particularly acute in areas
which had to compete with the private sector, such as law, IT and
engineering (UCEA, 2002). However, the same was true in areas competing
with other public sector jobs with higher pay, such as subjects allied
to medicine (ibid). The result of this was that HEIs reported
difficulties attracting many candidates and those that they did attract
were often not of the requisite quality. Moreover, they also reported
that it was difficult to recruit good young academic staff as a result
of low starting salaries (ibid).
There are many similarities between the academic labour market and
that for school teachers. Certainly, Dolton (1990) found that, even
after accounting for education, race, gender and social class, both the
level and relative wages in teaching influence the relative supply of
teachers. He also found that, as with HE academics, the supply varies by
subject. More recently, Chevalier, Dolton and McIntosh (2002) also found
relative wages to be important. Dolton and van der Klaauw (1999)
estimated a competing risks model that discriminated between movements
from teaching to the non-teaching sector and those to the non-working
sector. They found that higher opportunity wages increase the tendency
among teachers to switch careers, but have no effect on exit to
non-work. A similar analysis by reason for leaving, which discriminated
between voluntary and involuntary exits, (4) also found an effect of
opportunity wages on the former but not on the latter.
Nevertheless, it should be noted that there are also a number of
differences between the markets for school teachers and HE academics
(Johnes, 1990). Since most academics have at least one postgraduate degree, the training required to become an academic is lengthier than
that to become a school teacher. Other differences include the fact that
there are proportionally many fewer women in academe and higher demands
placed on staff by changes in the staff/students ratio (numbers of
pupils in much of primary and secondary education have remained
relatively stable whereas numbers of students in HE have increased
greatly).
3. Previous international studies of academic wages
There have been very few international studies of academic wages
This is unusual when one considers that the university, sector labour
market is one of the few that has a truly international dimension. One
reason for the lack of international studies may be the difficulty in
obtaining data from the HE sector The international higher education
sector is a heterogeneous one, being made up of private and public
sector organisations. In many countries it is a combination of the two.
This has meant that the few existing studies have been based on earnings
data from a small number of HEIs in different countries in order to
obtain the required data on earnings. In this study we bypass this
problem by using national survey data.
The Association of Commonwealth Universities (ACU) has undertaken a
number of surveys of academic staff salaries and benefits in
commonwealth countries. Provan (2001) compared academics in universities
in six countries: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, the UK, South Africa and Singapore. The real salaries (converted using World Bank purchasing
power parity series) of UK academics were found to compare poorly with
Australia, New Zealand, South Africa and Singapore (but not Canada).
More recently, Maxwell and Murphy (2003) expanded the set of countries
to include Malaysia, with different results. Real UK academic salaries
were found to be more similar to those in Australia, Canada, New Zealand
and South Africa, but still lower than those in Singapore. However, the
problem with using Provan (2001) as a guide to policy on the influences
of international disparities in academic salaries on recruitment and
retention in UK higher education is that it excludes two major
destinations of UK academics: the US and mainland Europe (Stevens,
2004). Moreover, the method used by Maxwell and Murphy (2003) to account
for differences in purchasing power in the different countries--the
Economist's 'Big Mac Index'--is problematic. (5) This
index--created by comparing the prices of McDonalds' hamburgers in
different countries--is a long way short of an appropriate measure of
purchasing power. Indeed, its use appears to be a step back from the
association's earlier work (Provan, 2001), which used indices of
purchasing power based on more representative baskets of commodities to
calculate. Thus the difference in their results with those of Provan
(2001) may merely be due to the change in the conversion rates, as the
authors acknowledge.
Stevens (2004) used data from labour force surveys to compare a
number of indicators of earnings across nine countries. These countries
were selected to include the main English-speaking countries to which UK
academics move (the US and Australia), together with other
English-speaking nations (New Zealand and Canada) and three European
countries (Denmark, France and Sweden). The results of this study were
that, overall, UK academics earn less in real terms than those in the US
and Canada; they earn an amount similar to those in Denmark and France,
and more than those in Australia, New Zealand, Japan and Sweden. The UK
academic earnings distribution was found to lie somewhat in the middle
of the sample of countries, being more dispersed than those in Nordic
countries, but less so than in the US. It is the comparison with the US
that is perhaps the most important for this study. It was found that it
is not merely the higher real salaries that set academic staff in the US
apart; the distribution is much more dispersed. Although academics at
the lower end of the scale in the UK and US earn similar amounts, the
median worker in the US earns more than three-quarters of UK academics.
The upper reaches of US academics earn far more than their UK
counterparts. From this it was concluded that in the US there is a
premier league of academic high flyers that does not exist in the UK.
4. Estimation and data
Our analysis is based on the UK Labour Force Survey Spring 2001 to
Winter 2001 and the US Current Population Survey 2001. In order to
remove any potential bias to our results, we focus our analysis on the
full-time workers in the graduate sector of the economy (i.e. on those
individuals with at least a bachelors degree) (6) since this sector of
the labour market reflects the choices and opportunities open to
potential and actual academics.
In order to account for the differences in academic and
non-academic earnings, we model the log of weekly wages (w) as dependent
upon whether the individual is an academic in addition to a quadratic in
age, whether the individual only has a first degree (i.e. the baseline
is a higher degree) (degree) and a vector of control variables (C) to
account for differences between men and women, ethnic groups etc, (7)
that is: (8)
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
It may be the case that there are important differences between the
structure and profile of lifetime earnings of men and women, or
academics and non-academics. Therefore, we include interaction terms in
our initial specification to account for this. In the results presented
below we have excluded those additional interaction terms that were not
found to be statistically significant. We also included double
interactions to see if there were more complex interactions, but none
were found to be significant. The full set of variables used in the
analysis is set out in table 1.
One issue of potential concern is the fact that the academic
variable may be endogenous. The endogeneity of occupational choice has
been the subject of much research. Individuals may make the choice of
becoming an academic dependent upon their expectation of future
earnings. School teachers, for example, tend to have lower grades on
average than other graduates (Chevalier et al., 2002; Nickell and
Quintini, 2002). This is less likely to be the case for academics in
higher education than school teachers, but must be borne in mind when
one considers the results. Indeed, one suspects that academics will not
have a lower unmeasured ability than all other graduates; certainly they
are on average likely to have a higher class of degree. (9) If this is
the case, the estimate of [[alpha].sub.1] will be downward-biased. A
related issue is the degree variable. As can be seen from table 1,
academics are more likely than other graduates to have a higher degree.
Since we find the return to graduates without a higher degree to be
lower, ceteris paribus, one must bear this in mind when considering the
size of the 'academic wage gap' suggested by [[alpha].sub.1].
In our consideration of the results, we take this into account by
considering the average academic and non-academic (i.e. taking the mean
values of the other variables for the relevant population) when
comparing earnings. (10)
Because of the potential for our estimates to be biased because of
participation decisions, we employ a 'Heckman
correction/selection' methodology in estimating wages (Heckman,
1976). In this model (1) is modified to account for the fact that the
dependent variable in the earnings regression is only observed if a
secondary inequality is satisfied (the 'selection equation').
That is, the dependent variable in equation (1) for individual i is
observed only if
(2) [gamma][z.sub.i] + [v.sub.i] > 0
where z is a set of variables that affect participation (11) and
[gamma] is a set of parameters to be estimated, the error term v ~
N(0,1) and corr([epsilon], v) = [rho].
When [rho] [not equal to] 0, a standard regression of equation (1)
will yield biased results. The Heckman selection model provides
consistent, asymptotically efficient estimates for all the parameters in
such models. In the results, in addition to reporting [rho], we report
the Wald test of independence of the selection and earnings equations,
i.e. the likelihood ratio test that [rho] = 0.
We estimate (1) using both OLS and a Heckman-selection method with
data from the UK Labour Force Survey Spring 2001 to Winter 2001 and the
US Current Population Survey 2001. The results of the selection
equations are included in the appendix.
The primary data issue is how to identify higher education
academics. This was done using information on occupation and industry.
Individuals were considered to be higher education academics if they
were in an appropriate occupation (e.g. lecturer or researcher) and
working in the higher education sector (although in the US it is not
possible to separate teachers and researchers at universities from those
at state colleges, who also conduct teaching undertaken in the FE sector
in the UK). One issue to note is that it is possible that pro-vice
chancellors and deans may be excluded from our analysis if they were
coded as managerial occupations. This will only take place if the
majority of their time is spent in managerial tasks. Moreover, the
number of such staff is very small.
5. Results
5.1 UK
The results of the estimation of our model in the UK are presented
in table 2. We can see that wages increase over an individual's
lifetime, although the effect is non-linear--they do so at a decreasing
rate. This can be seen more clearly when we consider the predicted
lifetime earnings profiles below. Academics have a different lifetime
earnings profile to non-academic graduates, with their earnings starting
from a lower point, but increasing faster over their working life, as
evidenced by the positive coefficient on academicxage. The negative
coefficient on femalexage suggests that women's wage profile, on
the other hand, is flatter than men's, increasing at a slower rate.
The negative coefficient on degree suggests that graduates without a
higher degree earn less than those with them once one accounts for
whether the individual is an academic. This suggests that the result
that is often found of a negative return to higher degrees (e.g.
O'Mahony and Stevens, 2004) is likely to be due to the occupational
choices made by these individuals, rather than negative
within-occupation returns indicative of individuals with lower
unmeasured ability undertaking graduate study or of a negative amount of
human capital being imparted by graduate instruction.
Once we account for age, qualifications and ethnicity, UK academics
earn less than non-academics, ceteris paribus. However, one has to be
careful to interpret the significant negative coefficient on academic in
the wage equation as evidence of a ceteris paribus earnings gap on its
own because of the non-linear nature of the equation (i.e. because of
the inclusion of the academicxage term) and possibly because of the
endogeneity of the academic term. Once we account for non-linearity, we
see that the wage an individual can earn as an academic will be below
that which they could earn elsewhere until the end of their career
(chart 1). The experiences of men and women working in higher education
are different. Women's wages generally fall relative to men over
their working life. This may be due to the effect of periods out of the
labour force on experience or because there is inequality in promotion
behaviour. However, the significant positive coefficient on the
femalexacademic term suggests that female academics fare well relative
to their male colleagues within academe by comparison to those in
non-academic employment.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Elsewhere in this issue, Dolton and Chung (2004) calculate the rate
of return on career choice (RRCC) of being a school teacher relative to
other occupations. If we apply this method to academics and use the
wages of other graduates, as the value of the alternative to (or
'cost' of) working in academe, controlling for personal
characteristics, we find that the RRCC of working in academe is -0.78
per cent for men and -0.83 per cent for women. Note that these figures
are based on taking the working life from 25 onwards and controlling for
whether or not the individual has a doctorate. If we consider the cost
of a PhD (which is increasingly seen as a prerequisite for working in
academe) as an additional cost (both in terms of fees and foregone earnings), these figures will be even lower.
We can get a clearer picture of the pattern of earnings by
considering the lifetime wage profiles of our average workers by age,
presented in chart 1. This figure shows the annual wage of average
academics and nonacademics alike. (12) Academics earn less than
nonacademics at almost all ages. At the age of thirty, the average
academic earns 72 per cent of the average graduate outside academe. At
forty this figure is 79 per cent and at fifty it is 86 per cent.
Academics achieve parity with non-academics only at the very end of
their working life. It is important to note that this difference is not
due to differences in personal characteristics. Although these lines
represent the average academic and non-academic graduate, the effect of
differences in characteristics is negligible: using our estimates, if we
plotted a line to show what an average academic would earn outside of
academe, it would be indistinguishable from the lifetime wage profile
for non-academics. Therefore, this difference represents the pay cut a
new academic would have to suffer entering from outside of the HE sector
and the pay premium an academic would be expected to achieve if they
left the sector. (13)
It is important to note that, not only are the lifetime earnings of
academics lower than that of non-academics, but that the disparity is
greater throughout the earlier and middle career period. Because of
this, if people discount their future earnings, the difference between
academic and non-academic earnings is greater than these figures
suggest. These differences may, therefore, have a greater impact upon
recruitment and retention of young staff.
5.2 US
The results of our estimation for the US are presented in table 3.
The earnings profile of US academics is similar to those in the UK,
although it is flatter (chart 2). The average US academic's
earnings continues to increase over his/her entire working life,
although the rate at which these earnings increase slows over his/her
career. Unlike in the UK, US academic wages reach a plateau at the end
of their career.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
A question of particular interest to this study is what UK
academics could--or believe that they could--earn in the US. Academics
in the US earn more at all ages (table 4 and chart 3). However, it is
important to note that the US data include individuals working in the US
state colleges, who undertake teaching similar to UK FE colleges and so
this comparison may actually understate the differences in wages.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
If the US figure does indeed represent what they could earn in the
US, this will provide an incentive to UK academics. However, we must
first discount the possibility that the difference in earnings
represents differences in the personal characteristics of UK and US
academics.
When we account for differences in personal characteristics and see
what the average UK academic would earn in the US, (14) we see that the
lifetime wage profiles of the average UK and US academic are almost
identical. This leads us to conclude that the differences in UK and US
academic wages highlighted in table 4 are unlikely to be due to
differences in the academics themselves, but rather to labour markets
generally and to systems of higher education in the two countries. This
suggests that there is a strong pay incentive for academics to migrate
from the UK to the US.
Once we adjust for the minor differences in personal
characteristics, we find that the RRCC of working in UK academe compared
to the US, is -0.23 per cent for men and -0.63 per cent for women. This
figure is smaller than the difference between academic and nonacademic
graduates in the UK noted above, implying that UK academics would be
better off choosing nonacademic careers in the UK than academic careers
in the US, ceteris paribus. The RRCC for a potential UK academic working
in the US academic sector relative to working in the UK non-graduate
market is -0.54 per cent for men and -0.21 per cent for women. For men,
this negative return is two-thirds of that found when one compares UK
academe to the UK non-academic sector; for women this deficit is
one-quarter. If the non-pecuniary benefits of HE are the same for men
and women, these figures suggest that the incentive to leave academe
altogether are higher for men than women, ceteris paribus. If the
non-pecuniary advantages of academe are even higher for women--because
it is easier to combine work with family commitments, for example--this
difference in incentives would be even greater. However, the differences
in the non-pecuniary rewards of working in the US and UK HE sectors are
likely to be marginal by comparison. (15)
6. Conclusion
In both the UK and the US an average graduate working in the HE
sector would earn less over his or her lifetime than graduates working
in non-academic sectors. The largest disparity occurs throughout the
earlier and middle career period. Thus, if people discount their future
earnings, the difference between academic and non-academic earnings is
even greater than charts 1 and 2 suggest. It is likely therefore that
these differences will have a greater impact upon the recruitment and
retention of young staff. However, it is unlikely that the balance
between the pecuniary and non-pecuniary aspects will remain constant
over an academic's working life. Young academics may be willing to
accept lower earnings as academics because of the other attractions of
academic life, such as the ability to conduct research, flexible working
hours, leave entitlement and the ability to attend foreign conferences.
In later life, family commitments may increase the weight of salary
relative to non-pecuniary benefits in the individual's utility
function. Moreover, if the more negative aspects of academic
life--bureaucracy and administrative tasks, for example--increase over
their career, a higher wage will be required to compensate (Rosen,
1986).
Academics in the UK earn less than academics in the US at all ages.
The difference between the wages of UK and US academics is particularly
pronounced at the later stages of the academic's working life. This
may reflect the fact that HEIs in the US are less constrained in their
pay scales and are able to reward academic high-flyers in order to
attract and retain them. It is certainly the case that there is much
higher variation in US academic salaries than those in the UK, both
across grades and across subjects (Machin and Oswald, 2000; Stevens,
2004). The difference between the wages earned by UK and US academics
cannot be explained by differences in observable characteristics such as
age, gender or ethnicity. This leads us to conclude that the differences
in UK and US academic wages are unlikely to be due to differences in the
academics themselves, but rather to labour markets generally and to
systems of higher education between the two countries.
Data Appendix
UK
The UK data come from the four quarters of the 2001 Labour Force
Survey (LFS). Academics are defined using the three-digit 1992 Standard
Industrial Classification (SIC) and the three-digit 2000 Standard
Occupational Classification (SOC). Academics are defined as being in SOC
codes 2311, 2319, 2321, 2322 and 2329. The main SOC unit group for
academic staff is 2311, which refers to 'higher education teaching
professionals'. Other teaching staff from SOC unit group 2319
'teaching professionals not elsewhere specified' if they were
also coded as working in SIC class 80.3 'higher education'.
Also included as academics were individuals who were in SOC minor group
232 "research professionals, i.e. unit groups 2321 'scientific
researchers', 2322 'social science researchers' and 2329
'researchers not elsewhere specified' if they were also coded
as working in SIC class 80.3 'higher education'. The two
measures of salaries used are gross weekly wages (variable grsswk).
US
The US data come from the Merged Outgoing Rotation Group of the
2001 Current Population Survey. The industry an individual worked in was
determined using the three-digit 1980 Census of Population Industry
Classification (CPIC). The appropriate CPIC code was 822 'Colleges
and universities'. The individual's occupation was determined
using the four-digit 1980 Census of Population Occupation Classification
(CPOC). The majority of academics were identified as individuals whose
occupation was CPOC code 221 'teachers, postsecondary' and
who's CPIC industry code was 822 'Colleges and
universities'. Unfortunately the CPOC does not have an occupational
group for researchers per se. Therefore, these individuals were
identified using a number of scientific occupations (both in the social
and natural sciences) in combination with the CPIC code. Unfortunately
it is impossible to differentiate between teachers and researchers
teaching in the HE sector and the state colleges. The wage data used are
'earnings per week' (earnwke).
Table A. 1 Selection equations
UK US
academic -0.541 * -0.777 ***
(0.299) (0.256)
female x academic -0.085 -0.169
(0.136) (0.118)
age 0.068 *** 0.1111 ***
(0.010) (0.005)
age (2)/100 -0.001 *** -0.002 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
female x age 0.005 *** 0.008 ***
(0.001) (0.001)
academic x age 0.024 *** 0.032 ***
(0.006) (0.005)
nonwhite -0.555 *** -0.043 *
(0.048) (0.026)
female x nonwhite 0.028 0.063 *
(0.073) (0.035)
academic x nonwhite -0.145 0.254
(0.225) (0.199)
degree -0.120 *** -0.003
(0.030) (0.017)
female x degree 0.000 -0.162 ***
(0.046) (0.024)
academic x degree -0.027 -0.299 ***
(0.144) (0.151)
married 0.169 *** 0.188 ***
(0.035) (0.022)
female x married -0.111 ** -0.465 ***
(0.051) (0.029)
children -0.008 -0.023 **
(0.015) (0.009)
female x children -0.174 *** -0.218 ***
(0.024) (0.012)
q1 -0.154 ***
(0.030)
q2 -0.018
(0.030)
q3 0.004
(0.030)
Constant -0.595 *** -1.162 ***
(0.191) (0.106)
Uncensored Obs. 14,785 50,795
Censored Obs. 9,164 36,145
Notes: Selection equation for whether individual is included in wage
equation. Standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 per
cent; ** significant at 5 per cent; *** significant at I per cent.
See table 1 for variable definitions.
Table 1. Variables used in empirical analysis
Non-
academics
Variable name UK US
Ln_Wage Log gross weekly earnings 6.32 6.82
academic HE academic 0 0
female Female 0.40 0.45
degree Only has first degree (a) 0.73 0.67
nonwhite Non-white 0.07 0.14
married Married 0.58 0.68
children No. of dependent children 0.69 0.75
age Age 38.8 41.6
femaleXvariable Female interacted with variable
academicXvariable Academic interacted with variable
UK-only variables
ql Spring 2001 survey 0.23
q2 Summer 2001 survey 0.25
q3 Autumn 2001 survey 0.26
Academics Total
Variable name UK US UK US
Ln_Wage 6.32 6.87 6.32 6.83
academic 1 1 0.04 0.03
female 0.39 0.38 0.40 0.45
degree 0.27 0.13 0.71 0.66
nonwhite 0.05 0.13 0.07 0.14
married 0.59 0.71 0.58 0.68
children 0.66 0.61 0.69 0.74
age 43.0 45.6 39.0 41.7
femaleXvariable
academicXvariable
UK-only variables
ql 0.23 0.23
q2 0.23 0.24
q3 0.27 0.26
Notes: (a) Note sample does not include individuals with only
a 2-year college degree. Data relate to full-time staff only.
Table 2. UK results
OLS Heckman
Academic -0.625 *** -0.574 ***
(0.112) (0.114)
femalexacademic 0.135 *** 0.141 ***
(0.050) (0.051)
Female 0.034 0.036
(0.045) (0.044)
age 0.096 *** 0.090 ***
(0.004) (0.005)
[age.sup.2]/100 -0.001 *** -0.001 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
femalexage -0.006 *** -0.006 ***
(0.001) (0.001)
academicxage 0.011 *** 0.009 ***
(0.002) (0.002)
Nonwhite -0.019 0.030
(0.025) (0.028)
femalexnonwhite -0.020 -0.020
(0.038) (0.038)
academicxnonwhite -0.049 -0.046
(0.104) (0.106)
Degree -0.075 *** -0.064 ***
(0.014) (0.014)
femalexdegree 0.006 0.006
(0.021) (0.022)
academicxdegree 0.067 0.069
(0.054) (0.055)
q1 -0.042 *** -0.029 **
(0.013) (0.014)
q2 -0.023 * -0.021
(0.013) (0.013)
q3 -0.008 -0.008
(0.013) (0.013)
Constant 4.306 *** 4.461 ***
(0.090) (0.096)
Observations 9,164 14,785
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.150
F/[chi] 101.9 *** 1,597.9 ***
[rho] -0.321
Wald 13.32 ***
Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. * significant
at 10 per cent; ** significant at 5 per cent;
*** significant at 1 per cent. See table 1
for variable definitions.
Table 3. US results
OLS Heckman
Academic -0.706 *** -0.604 ***
(0.081) (0.085)
female x academic 0.052 0.059 *
(0.034) (0.035)
Female -0.114 *** -0.069 ***
(0.026) (0.027)
Age 0.058 *** 0.047 ***
(0.002) (0.003)
age (2)/100 -0.001 *** -0.000 ***
(0.000) (0.000)
female x age -0.004 *** -0.004 ***
(0.001) (0.001)
academic x age 0.012 *** 0.009 ***
(0.002) (0.002)
Nonwhite -0.129 *** -0.124 ***
(0.011) (0.011)
female x nonwhite 0.086 *** 0.077 ***
(0.015) (0.016)
academic x nonwhite 0.050 0.035
(0.049) (0.051)
Degree -0.182 *** -0.181 ***
(0.008) (0.008)
female x degree 0.035 *** 0.015
(0.012) (0.012)
academic x degree 0.023 0.011
(0.050) (0.052)
Constant 5.555 *** 5.810 ***
(0.051) (0.061)
Observations 36,145 50,795
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.134
F/[CHI] 432.05 *** 5164.56 ***
[rho] -0.447
Wald 45.52 ***
Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis * significant at 10 per cent;
** significant at 5 per cent: *** significant at 1 per cent. See
table 1 for variable definitions.
Table 4. Comparative actual academic earnings,
[pounds sterling] PPP
UK
Men Women
Under 30 19,744 [pounds sterling] 20,386 [pounds sterling]
30-39 28,277 [pounds sterling] 26,094 [pounds sterling]
40-49 34,802 [pounds sterling] 28,455 [pounds sterling]
50-59 37,290 [pounds sterling] 31,330 [pounds sterling]
Over 60 41,433 [pounds sterling] 31,824 [pounds sterling]
Total 32,763 [pounds sterling] 26,821 [pounds sterling]
US
Men Women
Under 30 21,730 [pounds sterling] 18,997 [pounds sterling]
30-39 38,331 [pounds sterling] 28,891 [pounds sterling]
40-49 44,535 [pounds sterling] 35,611 [pounds sterling]
50-59 47,461 [pounds sterling] 38,354 [pounds sterling]
Over 60 52,440 [pounds sterling] 39,252 [pounds sterling]
Total 43,225 [pounds sterling] 33,580 [pounds sterling]
Note: Real salaries are converted using PPP rates from OECD Main
Economic Indicators.
NOTES
(1) One third of UK 'academic migrants' move to the US;
for non-UK academics the figure is one-fifth.
(2) The story is slightly different in the US, where predictions of
staff shortages from the 1970s (e.g. Freeman, 1971, 1975; Stapleton,
1989) led to an increase in interest in academic labour markets (see
Ehrenberg, 2003, for a summary). In the US, however, the main thrust of
the enquiry was the shortages of PhD students rather than issues
pertaining to academic staff themselves (Carster, 1976; Ehrenberg, 1991,
1992)
(3) These figures come from the staff survey conducted for the
Independent Review of Higher Education Pay and Conditions. This was the
result of surveys sent to heads of personnel of all 178 UK HEIs. The
overall response rate was 77 per cent, giving information pertaining to
246,027 of the estimated 300,780 staff in the UK, including 110,070 of
the estimated 133,977 academic, clinical academic and research staff in
UK HEIs.
(4) Which included exits for family reasons.
(5) This method is also used by OnE and Mitchell (2000), who
include institutions from the US, with similar results (i.e. UK
academics salaries are the lowest in their sample).
(6) In the US. this excludes those whose highest qualification is a
two-year degree.
(7) For the UK estimation we also include a dummy variable for each
of the first three quarters because the data is made up of four appended
quarters of data to ensure a large enough sample size.
(8) Unfortunately we cannot account for degree subject, because
there is no information on this for the US.
(9) For example, a recent survey of ten institutions of higher
education conducted by NIESR found that three-quarters of academic staff
had at least an upper second or equivalent.
(10) Running the regressions excluding the academic term provides
almost identical coefficients for the other terms (including the degree
term).
(11) These include the variables in the wage equation, plus
variables to account for whether the individual is married, the number
of dependent children, and a number of additional interactions. The
selection equations are set out in the appendix to this paper.
(12) That is, the values of the variables in table 2 are set to
their mean values for academics and non-academics and the predicted
value of the wage is calculated at each age.
(13) It may also be the case that there are certain unobservable
differences between academics and non-academic graduates, although it is
not clear what these might be. In the returns to education literature,
it is argued that the most important omitted variable is
'ability'. It seems unlikely that academics have lower ability
than graduates as a whole. A more likely candidate is a taste for
certain non-pecuniary aspects of academic life that are unavailable
elsewhere.
(14) i.e. given the coefficients in the US earnings regression
(15) For a classic statement of the equalising differences model,
see Rosen (1986).
REFERENCES
Bett, M. (1999), Independent Review of Higher Education Pay and
Conditions, Norwich, Stationery Office.
Cartter, A.M. (1976), Ph.D.'s and the Academic Labor Market,
New York, McGraw Hill
Chevalier, A, Dolton, P. and McIntosh, S. (2002), "Recruitment
and retaining teachers in the UK: an analysis of graduate occupation
choice from the 1960s to the 1990s', CEE Discussion paper no 21.
Dolton. P.J. (1990), The economics of UK teacher supply',
Economic Journal, 100, S91-S104.
Dolton, P. and Chung, T.P. (2004). 'The rate of return to
reaching: how does it compare to other graduate jobs?', National
Institute Economic Review, 190, October.
Dolton, P. and van der Klaaw, W. (1999), 'The turnover of
teachers: a competing risks explanation," Review of Economics and
Statistics, 81, pp. 543-52.
Ehrenberg, R.G. (1991), 'Academic labor supply', in
Clotfelter, Ehrenberg Getz and Siegfried (eds), Economic Challenges in
Higher Education, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
--(1992), 'The flow of new doctorates', Journal of
Economic Literature, 30, pp. 830-75.
--(2003), 'Studying ourselves: the academic labor
market', Journal of Labor Economics, 21, 2, pp. 267-87.
Freeman, R.J. (1971), The Market for College-Trained Manpower,
Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press.
--(1975), "Supply and salary adjustments to the changing
science manpower market: physics 1948-1973', American Economic
Review, 65, pp. 287-311.
Heckman, J. (1976), 'The common structure of statistical
models of truncation, sample selection, and limited dependent variables
and a simple estimator for such models', The Annals of Economic and
Social Measurement, 5, pp. 475-92.
HEFCE (2003), Appointment. Retention and Promotion of Academic
Staff in Higher Education Institutions, Report to the HEFCE by the
Scottish Council for Research in Education, University of Glasgow and
Nottingham Trent University.
Johnes, G. (1990), The Economics of Education, Basingstoke,
MacMillan.
Keep, E., Storey. J. and Sisson, K. (1996), 'Managing the
employment relationship in higher education: quo vadis?', in
Cuthbert, R. (ed.), Working in Higher Education, SRHE/OUP.
Machin, S. and Oswald, A.J. (2000), 'UK economics and the
future supply of academic economists', The Economic Journal, 110,
pp. 334-49.
Maxwell J. and Murphy, D. (2003), Academic Staff Salaries and
Benefits in Seven Commonwealth Countries, 2001-2002, Association of
Commonwealth Universities.
Nickell, S.J. and Quintini, B. (2002), 'The consequences of
the decline in public sector pay in Britain: a little bit of
evidence', Economic Journal, 112, pp. F107-18.
O'Mahony, M., Stevens, P.A. (2004), 'International
comparisons of performance in the provision of public services: outcome
based measures for education', presentation to NIESR conference on
'Productivity and Performance in the Provision of Public
Services' at the British Academy.
Ong, L.L., and Mitchell, J.D. (2000), 'Professors and
hamburgers: an international comparison of real academic salaries',
Applied Economics, 32, pp. 869-76.
Pearson, R., Buchan. J. Bevan, S., Jackson, C. and Stock, J.
(1990), The Recruitment and Retention of University Academic and
Academic Related Staff, IMS Paper 157, Brighton.
PREST (Policy Research in Engineering, Science and Technology
University of Manchester) (2000), Impact of the Research Assessment
Exercise and the Future of Quality Assurance in the Light of Changes in
the Research Landscape. Report to the Higher Education Funding Council for England.
Provan, D. (2001), Academic Staff Salaries and Benefits in Six
Commonwealth Countries, 2000-2001, Association of Commonwealth
Universities.
Rosen, S. (1986), 'The theory of equalizing differences',
in Ashenfelter, O. and Layard P.R.G. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics,
I, Amsterdam, North Holland.
Stapleton, D.C. (1989), 'Cohort size and the academic labor
market', Journal of Human Resources, 24, pp. 221-52.
Stevens, P.A. (2004), An International Comparison of Academic
Wages, Report to the Department for Employment and Skills.
UCEA (2002), Recruitment and retention of staff in UK higher
education: A survey and case studies, report commissioned by the HEFCE,
SCOP, UCEA and UUK.
UGC (1984),A Strategy for Higher Education into the 1990s,
University Grants Committee.
Philip Andrew Stevens *
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research (e-mail:
[email protected]). The research reported here was funded by the
DfES. Data were supplied by the Higher Education Statistical Agency.
Thanks go to Martin Weale, Peter Dolton and participants at the
NIESK/DfES/ESRC conference on 'Recent Developments in the UK
Graduate Labour Market' for helpful comments, although the usual
caveats apply.