Work and well-being: introduction.
Bryson, Alex ; Freeman, Richard B.
Work absorbs a huge share of the lives of most people. It is the
major source of income. How people fare at work, the conditions under
which they work and the mechanisms for remedying problems at work impact
subjective well-being, labour market behaviour, and mental and physical
health. While economic analysis treats work as creating disutility, many
people are workaholics for reasons beyond income, and one of the robust
findings from the new economics of happiness is that unemployment is one
of the major depressants of subjective well-being. The independent
Strategic Review of Health Inequalities, headed by Professor Sir Michael
Marmot, noted in its June 8, 2009 policy dialogue that "employment
conditions influence health both directly and indirectly" and
argued for structural interventions at workplaces, organisations and
broader policies to make a significant contribution toward healthier
work. As the world economy has fallen into a sharp recession, the
increase in joblessness, potential delays of retirement due to reduced
value of pensions, particularly in the private sector, and the probable
intensification of work among those who remain employed can be expected
to have major impacts on well-being and social behaviour. It is
therefore timely to devote an issue of the National Institute Economic
Review to work and well-being.
Our collection of four papers tackles different aspects of the
links between work and well-being that illuminate issues of substantial
relevance to policy debate. In contrast to most of the earlier
literature, that relates measures of life or job satisfaction as the
principal indicator of well-being to employment compared to
unemployment, the empirical papers in this issue relate diverse measures
of mental health and of satisfaction to the quality of jobs and
employment compared to retirement. In contrast to the bulk of earlier
literature, that looks at cross-section relations between personal
attributes and well-being, they use longitudinal (panel) data as their
main source of information, which enables them to eliminate unobserved
person fixed effects, and thus to determine better the impact of changed
incentives on satisfaction or other outcomes.
Ana Llena-Nozal examines the impacts of changes in a person's
workforce status on their mental well-being. She looks at changes in
mental well-being when people gain employment and how the change in
well-being depends on the nature of the work they gain. Her panel
analysis for four advanced industrialised economies (the UK, Australia,
Switzerland and Canada) shows that the mental health pay-off to
employment depends crucially on the type of employment the individual
enters. Mental health benefits for inactive individuals are much greater
when they move to jobs with greater job security and when they obtain
greater job satisfaction from their job. In some cases, but not all, the
gains are smaller for those obtaining non-standard jobs than for those
moving into standard employment contracts. But she also finds strong
persistence in mental health distress. In addition, the analysis
uncovers differences in the impact of types of jobs by gender and
country, suggesting that there remains more to do to obtain a full
accounting of the job-mental health link. Still, the bottom line message
is clear; work of the appropriate kind should be considered as part of
the toolbox of 'medical' cures for mental health distress.
The standard analysis of satisfaction and employment compares the
well-being of the employed to that of the unemployed. Andrew Clark and
Yarine Fawaz undertake a different comparison by examining the change in
mental well-being using questions about depressive symptoms, strain,
inability to cope, anxiety-based amnesia, and so on, when persons move
from employment to retirement. Their panel analysis includes eleven
countries from a European panel data set and the UK from the British
Household Panel Survey. To the extent that individuals choose their
retirement voluntarily, marginal analysis suggests that there will be
only modest changes in well-being. In fact, they find that on average
there is a modest increase in well-being from retirement but they show
that there is a great deal of variation across individuals and according
to the jobs individuals held prior to retirement around the average
level of change. Some workers gain substantially on leaving work, while
others experience substantial falls in well-being on retiring,
suggesting that they may have preferred to carry on working. They note
that persons having high education and good jobs tend to have higher
gains in well-being, which they hypothesize results from having
higher-valued pensions. Paralleling Llena-Nozal, they find considerable
differences across countries and among regions in the United Kingdom.
They stress that the groups whose well-being falls the most upon
retirement are those whom policy should encourage to keep working. By
extension, those whose well-being rose the most from retirement may
arguably be working too long.
Decisions about the division of time between work and household
activities should depend on the situation of a household rather than
solely on that of an individual. Patrik Hesselius considers the value of
time off work relative to working when one's spouse is retired and
at home. Are persons with a retired spouse more likely to take
sick-leave than persons with a working spouse? There are three reasons
to expect workers to value time at home more when their spouse is at
home than when both persons work and thus to make greater use of
sickness absence than persons whose spouse is working. The employed
person may obtain greater pleasure from being at home through
synchronisation of leisure with their spouse. They may choose to stay
home more when they feel ill because there is someone at home to care
for them. And they may seek to stay home to care for their retired
spouse. Hesselius uses Swedish panel data to explore how old age
retirement of one's spouse affects the working spouse's use of
sickness absence. Retirement of the male spouse increases female average
long-term sickness absence by about a week per year. When the male
spouse retires for reasons of disability, the increase in sickness
absence rises to two weeks per year for the employed woman. The response
of employed men to the retirement of female spouses is modest and not
statistically different from zero, while the response of employed men to
the disability retirement of female spouses is about one week per year.
Without information about how persons on sick-leave allocate their time
at home, one can only speculate about the extent to which spouses take
sick-leave to care for their retired spouse, be cared for by their
retired spouse, or enjoy leisure together. Whatever the importance of
these three possibilities, the message of this paper is clear;
policymakers need to give careful consideration to household labour
supply decisions when devising sickness and retirement policies and
should consider the impacts on the healthcare system as well.
Finally, John Treble points to the big differences in the way in
which modern economies provide insurance against sickness. He proposes a
framework for understanding the policy choices made in terms of optimal
absenteeism and optimal insurance provision. His model suggests that an
efficient market solution entails a system in which firms fix a wage, an
acceptable level of absence and experience-rated insurance such that
workers' ability to supply labour reliably is matched to
firms' demands for reliable labour. He notes the use of
'sick-leave banks' in some US and UK firms and points out the
problems involved when sick-leave is a tradeable commodity. The paper is
timely given the revisions currently underway in the US, Sweden and
Germany regarding the design of sick-leave policies.
The new studies of the link between well-being and work are
important in two ways. They open a new terrain in labour market analysis
that should provide a richer understanding of the way work and labour
policies affect lives. Second, they bring labour analysis and medical
analysis closer together, which directs attention to the use of
firm-based human resource policies as part of health policies,
particularly regarding mental health.
Alex Bryson, National Institute of Economic and Social Research and
Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics. e-mail:
[email protected].
Richard B. Freeman, Harvard and Centre for Economic Performance,
London School of Economics.
NOTE
(1) Strategic Review of Health Inequalities in England Post 2010. A
Policy Dialogue on the Social Determinants of Health Work Social
Protection, Monday 8 June at the Royal College of Physicians.