Tighter financial regulation and its impact on global growth.
Barrell, Ray ; Holland, Dawn ; Karim, Dilruba 等
The financial crisis that started in mid-2007 enveloped the world
economy and caused a serious recession in most OECD countries. It is
widely believed that it has also left a scar on potential output because
it will have raised perceptions of risk and hence reduced the
sustainable capital stock people wish to hold. It is inevitable that
policymakers should ask what can be done to reduce the chances of this
happening again, and it is equally inevitable that the banks would
answer that it is too costly to do anything. There are four questions
one must answer before it is possible to undertake a cost-benefit
analysis of bank regulation. The first involves asking what are the
costs of financial crises? The second involves asking what are the costs
of financial regulation? The third involves asking what causes crises?
The fourth, and perhaps the most important, involves asking whether
regulators can do anything to reduce the risk of crises? Our overall
approach to these issues is spelled out in a report written for the FSA
in the aftermath of the crisis (see Barrell et al., 2009).
In this note we discuss the short and long-run consequences of
tighter regulation and also throw some light on recent BIS proposals for
'Countercylical Capital Buffers'. We first look at our answer
to the other three questions. We also briefly discuss the current state
of financial markets in Europe and the 91 major banks going through a
stress test.
The causes and consequences of financial crises
The literature on the causes of financial crises is extensive, and
we have contributed to it in a number of ways. In Barrell, Davis, Karim
and Liadze (2010)i we showed for the first time that regulatory factors
affected crisis probabilities in a significant way, and that the
inclusion of unweighted capital and liquidity ratios, along with lagged
effects from rising real house prices, were preferred to the normal
variables from previous studies (mainly of emerging markets) which
included credit growth, monetary policy indicators, real interest rates,
inflation and government deficits. In OECD countries these factors do
not affect the probability of a financial crisis happening. In
subsequent papers we have shown that including the current account
deficit (Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2010a) and an indicator of
off-balance sheet activity (Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2010b)
improves our ability to predict crises. These results are invariant to
using a narrower definition of liquidity or including the crises in 2007
and 2008 in our sample. Our robust results suggest that stronger
defences through higher capital and liquidity standards significantly
reduce the probability of crises, and hence policymakers have tools
available to them, and there is a case for using those tools.
A great deal has also been written on the costs of crises, and the
National Institute has made two recent contributions. We have set the
exploration of the costs of crises in the context of the determinants of
productivity, and have factored out other influences. There are articles
such as Cerra and Saxena (2008) that do not do this but instead use
time-series methods to look at the long-run effects of a variety of
crises in a variety of places. They conclude that financial crises in
the OECD have had a negative impact on output. Although on average this
is clearly the case, as Cecchetti, Kohler and Upper (2009) also show,
not all crises have a negative impact, and some may even have had a
significant positive impact on long-run sustainable output. This latter
paper suggests that of 40 systemic crises in the past few decades nine
have had significant permanent negative effects on output.
Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2010c) look at the drivers of
output per person hour in thirteen OECD countries in a panel context,
and they include R&D, FDI, and other indicators of technology as
well as financial crises. They show that the majority of financial
crises since 1980 have had no impact on the equilibrium level of output,
although the average impact of crises on output is around -2 to -3 per
cent, which is not out of line with the estimate in Cerra and Saxena
(2008).
Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2010c} show that it is not
possible to impose a common long-run output effect from crises, but some
crises do have a significant longrun impact. Systemic crises are
different, with three of the four in the sample showing significant and
negative effects on productivity. The scale of these significant
estimated effects ranges from -4 per cent in the US in the 1980s and
Japan in the 1990s to-10 per cent in Finland in the early 1990s.
Although Sweden had a systemic crisis at the same time it does not show
up in the longrun determinants of productivity, which may reflect
changes in the political and institutional structure that increased the
scope of the market in the economy. These changes may in turn be the
consequence of the crisis.
Barrell, Holland and Liadze (2010) look at a different sample and a
longer data period which includes the financial crisis in the UK in the
mid 1970s. In a cointegrating regression of the factors affecting
productivity that crisis shows up as producing a permanent scar.
However, this result disappears when the model is estimated in a panel
with common factors as the financial crisis approximately coincides with
the oil crisis. This had a similar effect on productivity across all
OECD countries, and the step down in the UK is reflected in similar
movements in countries that did not have a financial crisis at this
time. Hence we would conclude that no financial crisis in the UK since
1900 has had a permanent effect on the sustainable level of output.
However, we gauge that the recent crisis is one which has had a
permanent effect both in the UK and elsewhere. It is worth seeing if we
can act to prevent such crises.
The costs of tighter financial regulation
Policy should be set by balancing the costs of action against the
benefits of action. If the average crisis reduces sustainable output by
2 1/2 per cent, then the expected costs of crises are high. The expected
benefits from regulation are the reduction in the probability of a
crisis multiplied by its costs. The costs of regulation are the net
present discounted value of its impact on output or welfare. The
short-run impacts may differ from the long-run impacts, and they may be
larger on impact than once markets have adjusted. Proposals for
regulatory change should be evaluated in the light of their expected
benefits evaluated over a long period of time. Regulations need to be
chosen to maximise the impact on probabilities whilst minimising the
impact on output.
The obvious first step for the regulators would be to raise capital
and liquidity standards to get crisis probabilities down to an
acceptable level. Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2010d) calculate
that if capital and liquidity standards had been around 4 percentage
points of total assets higher over the past fifteen years we might well
have avoided the sub-prime crises, although the Spanish and perhaps
French banking systems may still have been under stress at present. It
is important therefore to ask what impact higher capital standards would
have on output. Barrell et al. (2009) suggested that an optimal response
to the recent crisis would have involved raising capital and liquidity
by 3 percentage points, and we look at that proposal below.
There are a number of approaches to calculating the costs of
tighter regulation, varying from a careful study of balance sheets, as
in Elliott (2010) to econometric work as in Barrell et al. (2009). All
involve looking at the effects of increasing the share of liabilities in
equity (and assets in liquid form) on the cost structure of banks. In
Barrell et al. (2009) we suggested that excess cost of equity capital as
compared to deposits was about 11 percentage points, and that increases
in capital ratios would be reflected in a wider spread between deposit
and lending rates in banks. As a result the average cost of loans would
rise by 11 basis points for every unit increase in regulatory capital.
After calculating an offset for the impact of lower risks on equity
costs, Elliot (2010) suggests the increase would be around 8 basis
points.
Barrell et al. (2009) also look for a role for liquidity holdings
in the margin between borrowing and lending rates in banks. They find
that marginal increases in liquidity holdings in US banks could raise
costs by up to 500 basis points for every 1 percentage point increase in
liquid asset ratios. Hence a 1 point increase in required liquidity
would raise the lending margin by 5 basis points in the US. The marginal
cost would be noticeably lower in the UK and Europe as banks there
generally hold much less liquidity, and hence have to shed less high
yielding assets to hold more liquidity. We would judge that a 1
percentage point increase in required liquid asset holding would raise
the spread betweeen borrowing and lending rates by 1.5 basis points in
Europe. The impact of these increases in borrowing costs depends upon
how investment is financed and upon the impact of lower equilibrium
investment (and higher saving) on the risk-free real interest rate.
It is possible to assess the impact of a 3 percentage point
increase in capital and liquidity in Europe and North America using our
global macro model NiGEM. We have models of 24 members of the EU as well
as the US, Canada, Mexico, Japan, China and a number of other countries.
In the fifteen largest EU countries as well as in North America (and
elsewhere) we have a fully spelled out supply side of the economy where
the equilibrium capital stock depends upon the user cost of capital.
This in turn depends on the shares of finance from equities and from
borrowing, and these differ across countries. An increase in bank
borrowing costs will be reflected in the user cost both directly and
through its effects on bond market borrowing costs. Barrell et al.
(2009) show that in normal times the spreads in these two markets move
together. This is in part because firms will arbitrage between these
markets until the marginal (shadow) cost of borrowing is equalised. The
spread between borrowing and lending rates facing consumers is also
modelled on NiGEM, and an increase in this spread will reduce
consumption in all countries, whether or not the personal sector is a
net debtor or net creditor, as is discussed in Barrell and Holland
(2007).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In order to evaluate the effects of a 3 percentage point rise in
capital and liquidity standards, we raise these spreads by 400 basis
points in Europe and 500 basis points in the US (to reflect the higher
marginal cost of liquidity there). We assume financial markets are
forward looking, and firms invest in relation to expected output levels
and the user cost of capital. Consumers react to their incomes and their
housing and financial wealth, and governments change taxes to achieve
their deficit targets in the long run. The long-run real (equilibrium)
interest rate is determined by the global savings and investment balance
and the long-run equilibrium affects long real rates now with forward
looking financial markets. The monetary authorities are assumed to
target inflation using the short-term interest rate. Long rates are the
forward convolution of expected future short rates.
In Barrell et al. (2009) we undertook an analysis of a 3 percentage
point increase in capital and liquidity in the UK alone, and showed that
for every one point increase sustainable output would fall by 0.1 per
cent. As we can see from figure 1, the same regulatory change introduced
in a number of countries together has much less impact on sustainable
output. The UK is a small open economy, and when it acts alone the
change in regulation does not change the global saving and investment
balance. When all OECD countries act together the initial impact is to
lower investment and raise saving. Real interest rates fall as a result.
As equity markets reflect the discounted value of future profits and the
discount rate has fallen, equity prices rise and the cost of equity
finance falls. These two effects offset about two thirds of the output
costs we identified when the UK acted alone. Figure 2 plots the paths
for long-term interest rates and real equity prices in this scenario. As
we operate with a model with no restrictions on capital movements, the
changes in real interest rates and in equity prices are approximately
the same in all locations.
It would appear that the costs of tighter regulation are in the
long run small, and as the costs of crises are potentially high tighter
regulation would be wise. There are caveats to make. Moving too rapidly
to a tighter standard would be inadvisable, as it could induce a major
slowdown in activity, only some of which is visible in figure 1. Barrell
et al. (2009) show that UK banks react progressively more to falls in
their headroom, the excess amount of capital they hold above their
regulatory floor. As headroom gets close to zero lending margins facing
firms rise sharply to ration credit. A rapid increase in regulatory
capital would reduce headroom noticeably and could induce a new banking
crisis. The Bank of England (2010) shows that capital ratios have risen
noticeably since the crisis in 2007, but that increase has been more
marked in the UK than in continental Europe. Hence over-rapid regulatory
changes could worsen the situation of an already fragile banking system,
and start a second (or third) financial crisis in these countries.
Countercyclical capital buffers
The BIS has recently advocated the introduction of credit related
countercyclical buffers. As we show above, these will have costs. It is
not apparent that they will have benefits. In the sequence of papers by
Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2010; 2010a, b) cited above on the
causes of crises, we show that financial crises are driven by property
market bubbles, current account deficits and the growth of off-balance
sheet activity. In no case is there a role for credit growth directly.
Of course this could be a driver of the house price bubbles that
Rheinhart and Rogoff (2009) also identify as precursors of crises, but
evidence has to be presented to show this is the case.
It is widely believed that excessive lending leads to excessive
house price growth, but it is not clear that this is the case, as table
1 suggests. We have undertaken simple Granger causality tests of the
relationship between real house price growth and real credit growth in a
number of countries, and it appears that in some cases house price
growth 'causes' credit growth, whilst in others credit growth
'causes' real house prices. In Germany and Sweden there is
clear evidence that credit growth causes house price growth. The former
has not however experienced a housing market bubble, whilst the Swedish
correlation reflects events in the 1980s and 1990s. There is also
evidence that credit growth 'causes' house price growth,
albeit with a two-year or more lag in France and the US.
In countries with liberalised financial markets and forward looking
asset markets we might expect house prices to cause credit growth. If
perceptions of future incomes change, for instance because politicians
tell people income growth will be stronger in future, then house prices
may rise. Given transactions continue all the time, the increased price
will require increased credit to finance purchases. House prices then
cause credit. Only when individuals are constrained in the amount they
can borrow would we expect to see credit cause house prices, especially
when the credit constraints are relaxed. This is indeed the pattern we
observe in table 1. This would suggest that countercyclical buffers will
have little impact on housing market bubbles and hence will not reduce
the probability of financial crises.
House price bubbles may be related to changes in lending standards,
and hence it may be wise to introduce quantitative controls on the loan
to value ratio (LTV). These may be hard to enforce unless one can deal
with second mortgage markets by removing recourse from second loans.
Upper limits can be made self reinforcing, as in Germany where mortgages
cannot be securitised (a very mature market) if they exceed an LTV of 90
per cent. This may be one of the reasons why in 2006 the average LTV in
Germany was 72 per cent as against 80 per cent in the UK and typically
78 per cent in the US. The former did not have a housing bubble whilst
the latter two did. However, it is hard to find a role for LTV ratios in
econometric models of house prices because of the paucity of data, and
hence relying on this alone for regulation may not be good
evidence-based policy.
Stresses in Europe
In its April 2010 Financial Stability Report the IMF reduced its
estimate of losses in the global banking system to $2.3 trillion, and
suggested that about one third of those losses were yet to be made
public, with the majority of the unexposed bad assets being held in
European banks. Losses on this scale could remove a good proportion of
the equity base of those banks, and they are therefore likely to result
in higher lending margins. It was clear in April that those losses would
need to be taken on board by central banks and governments if they
wished to remove the credit rationing and margin increases that would be
necessary to produce the required reserve rebuilding by banks. Since the
April Report the focus of the regulators has shifted to problems with
sovereign debt in Europe.
The stress test undertaken in July by the Committee of European
Bank Supervisors (CEBS) of 91 banks revealed some of the problems this
may have caused. Twenty-seven Spanish, six Greek and four Portuguese
banks were included. However there are also major stresses in French and
German banks, not all of which have become apparent. However, the stress
test probably revealed the majority of the hidden losses referred to by
the IME It was also able to make clear that capital issues and
government recapitalisations had made good most of these losses in bank
equity.
In recent years banks in the Euro Area have built up large holdings
of Euro Area governments debts. These assets were liquid and had no
apparent currency risk, and for a long period after 2002 they attracted
similar interest rates whichever sovereign they were issued by. They
seemed good substitutes for each other, but recent movements in
sovereign spreads over German government long rates have shown they are
not. Bank of England calculations suggest that the German banking system
holds up to three times its equity base in Euro Area government debt
with about a tenth of that in Greek, Spanish, Irish and Portuguese
governments' debt (Bank of England, Financial Stability Report,
June 2010). Exposure to Greece alone represents 10 per cent of bank
equity capital in that country. The French banking system's
exposure is only marginally lower at more than two and a half times its
equity base held in Euro Area sovereign debt, with the amount held in
debt from the same four countries being as large as a quarter of its
equity base. The UK, Italian and Spanish banking system are less exposed
to sovereign debt, and especially less to foreign sovereign debt. The
stress test included relatively stringent potential losses on these
sovereign debts. The chance of an Argentinian-style default, even in
Greece, is extremely low. A rescheduling that involves a 23 per cent
write-down in the value of Greek debt is the worst it is wise to assume.
Putting a potential write-down of 10 per cent in German government debt
was stringent.
The recently produced stress test on European banks has gone some
way to allaying fears about solvency risks. Of the 91 banks tested seven
failed, with five savings banks in Spain and one bank each in Germany
and Greece. Another twelve were marginal, again with six in Spain and
two in Germany. Most of Spain's problems were in the savings bank
system. The core commercial banking system was sound and this is more
important for long-term economic health. Parts of the stress test were
stringent, and others were not, but at least they may have identified
where some of the problems may exist. The probability of the stress
scenario, at a one in twenty event probability, was more stringent than
that in the US in 2009, which had a one in fifteen event probability.
However, the application by domestic supervisors may have been patchy.
Conclusion
The financial crisis that overtook the World Economy in 2007 and
2008 made it clear that banks were holding too little equity for the
risks they were taking, and that some countries such as the UK had
allowed liquid asset holdings to drop to unsafe levels. There is a
strong case for raising required equity and liquidity ratios by 3 per
cent of the unweighted assets of the OECD banking system. This would
reduce the probability of crisis and would have a limited effect on
growth. However, there is more that could be done. House price bubbles
are commonly associated with crises and it would be wise to flatten
these bubbles with different regulations on lending and on transactions.
However, there is limited evidence that reducing credit growth will
impact on house price bubbles. Indeed it is probably more common for
housing market bubbles to cause lending growth than the other way round.
European banks have been raising equity in the past two years, either
from the state or from the market, and this might be why the majority
passed the recent stress tests. US banks have also raised equity and
hence an increase in requirement may have less impact on lending costs
than we currently project as the equity that will be needed is already
in place.
doi: 10.1177/0027950110381838
REFERENCES
Bank of England (2010), 'Financial Stability Report',
June, Issue no.27.
Barrell, R., Davis, E.P., Fic, T., Holland, D., Kirby, S. and
Liadze, I. (2009), 'Optimal regulation of bank capital and
liquidity: how to calibrate new international standards', FSA
Occasional Paper no. 38, October.
Barrell, R., Davis, E.P., Karim, D. and Liadze, I. (2010),
'Bank regulation, property prices and early warning systems for
banking crises in OECD countries', NIESR Working Paper 331, Journal
of Banking and Finance, 34, pp. 2255-64.
--(2010a), 'The impact of global imbalances: does the current
account balance help to predict banking crises in OECD countries?',
NIESR Working Paper No 351.
--(2010b), 'Calibrating macroprudential policy', NIESR
Discussion Paper no. 354.
--(2010c), 'Evaluating off-balance sheet exposures in banking
crisis determination models', NIESR Discussion Paper no. 357.
--(2010d), 'The effects of banking crises on potential output
in OECD countries', NIESR Discussion Paper no. 358.
Barrell, R. and Holland, D. (2007), 'Banking crises and
economic growth', National institute Economic Review, 202, October,
pp. 34-41.
Barrell, R., Holland, D. and Liadze, I.(2010), 'Accounting for
UK economic performance 1973-2009', NIESR Discussion Paper no. 359.
Cecchetti, S.G., Kohler, M. and Upper, C. (2009), 'Financial
crises and economic activity', NBER Working Paper 15379.
Cerra, V. and Saxena, S.C. (2008), 'Growth dynamics: the myth
of economic recovery', American Economic Review, 98:1, pp. 439-57.
Eiliott D. (2010), 'A further exploration of bank capital
requirements: effects of competition from other financial sectors and
effects of size of bank or borrower and of loan type', Brookings
Institution, http://www.brookings.edu/ -/
media/Files/rc/papers/2010/0129_capital_elliott/
Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. (2009), This Time Is Different:
Eight Centuries of Financial Folly, Princeton University Press.
NOTE
(1) An earlier write-up appeared in Barrell et al. (2009).
Ray Barrell, Dawn Holland and Dilruba Karim *
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research and Brunel
University.
Table 1 Granger Causality tests on growth in real house prices and
personal sector real borrowing
Personal debt [right arrow] Property prices:
null hypothesis: no Granger Causality
F-stat (probability)
1 lag 2 lags 3 lags 4 lags
Belgium 0 0.73 0.68 0.87
(0.99) (0.49) (0.57) (0.49)
Canada 1.61 1.65 1.39 0.79
(0.21) (0.21) (0.27) (0.54)
Denmark 6.97# 3.4 2.3 2.0
(0.01)# (0.05) (0.1) (0.13)
Finland 1.03 0.21 0.65 1.08
(0.32) (0.81) (0.59) (0.4)
France 2.55 1.81 3.99# 3.04#
(0.12) (0.18) (0.02)# (0.04)#
Germany 8.53# 8.79# 4.59# 3.24#
(0.01)# (0.0)# (0.01)# (0.03)#
Italy 0.0 1.38 0.88 1.02
(0.97) (0.27) (0.46) (0.42)
Japan 3.7 2.89 0.93 1.07
(0.06) (0.07) (0.44) (0.39)
Netherlands 0.3 0.33 0.53 0.56
(0.59) (0.72) (0.67) (0.7)
Sweden 14.38# 8.5# 5.35# 4.03#
(0.0)# (0.0)# (0.0)# (0.01)#
Spain 0.31 2.2 1.56 1.31
(0.58) (0.13) (0.22) (0.29)
UK 0.32 0.76 0.37 0.38
(0.58) (0.47) (0.78) (0.82)
USA 1.72 2.96 4.26# 2.89
(0.2) (0.07) (0.02)# (0.05)
Property prices [right arrow] Personal debt:
null hypothesis: no Granger Causality
F-stat (probability)
1 lag 2 lags 3 lags 4 lags
Belgium 0.07 2.15 1.29 1.02
(0.8) (0.13) (0.3) (0.41)
Canada 4.35# 3.32 2.54 3.88#
(0.04)# (0.05) (0.08) (0.01)#
Denmark 0.19 0.17 1.19 0.57
(0.67) (0.84) (0.33) (0.69)
Finland 0.2 1.87 2.53 3.29#
(0.66) (0.18) (0.09) (0.04)#
France 1.08 1.81 1.3 0.47
(0.31) (0.18) (0.29) (0.76)
Germany 0.4 0.16 0.08 0.66
(0.53) (0.85) (0.97) (0.62)
Italy 11.51# 7.43# 1.79 0.89
(0.0)# (0.0)# (0.18) (0.48)
Japan 0.71 5.12# 1.0 3.03#
(0.41) (0.01)# (0.41) (0.04)#
Netherlands 0.28 0.62 1.6 1.45
(0.6) (0.55) (0.21) (0.25)
Sweden 0.48 0.51 0.4 0.12
(0.49) (0.6) (0.75) (0.97)
Spain 1.49 2.36 1.41 0.99
(0.23) (0.11) (0.26) (0.43)
UK 0.07 0.28 0.5 0.77
(0.8) (0.76) (0.68) (0.55)
USA 0.0 1.14 1.66 1.32
(0.99) (0.33) (0.2) (0.3)
Note: 95% significance effects in bold type.
Note: 95% significance effects in bold type is indicated with #.