Migration, skill composition and growth.
Kim, Young-Bae ; Levine, Paul ; Lotti, Emanuela 等
The UK, with its relatively liberal immigration policies following
recent enlargements, has been one of the main recipients of migrants
from new EU member states.T his paper poses the questions: what is the
effect of immigration on a receiving economy such as the UK? Is the
effect beneficial or adverse for growth? Does emigration have brain
drain effects on sending economies? How differently would skilled (or
unskilled) migration affect both receiving and sending economies? What
factors would contribute to immigration/emigration benefits/costs and
economic growth driven by migration? Who are the winners and losers in
both the sending and host regions? We utilise a two-bloc endogenous
growth model with labour mobility of different skill compositions to
address these questions. We show that migration, in general, is
beneficial to the receiving country and increases the world growth rate.
With remittances, the sending country in aggregate can also benefit. The
only exception is in the case of unskilled migration, which can actually
have a detrimental impact on the world growth rate. This possibility
however seems to be unlikely by our examination of migration trends.
Winners are migrants, and the skill group in the region that sees its
relative size decrease.
Keywords: Migration; labour mobility; skill composition; economic
growth
JEL Classifications: F22; F43; J24; J61; O41
I. Introduction
Labour mobility is one of the most important and controversial
issues in contemporary economic and political debates. In the lead-up to
the recent general election in the UK, it appears that migration was
perceived as a burden for the indigenous population, resulting in less
liberal migration policies proposed by all the major political parties.
It is clear that the post-enlargement migration in the European Union,
as well as migration from outside the EU15, has raised the UK population
since the beginning of the 1990s. Since the onset of the economic
crises, immigration has declined, but still over 14 per cent of those of
working age in the UK were born abroad. (1) The UK economy, with its
relatively liberal immigration policies following the two most recent
enlargements, has been one of the main recipients from the new EU
countries. Does this make the UK economy stronger or weaker? What are
the economic benefits/costs associated with migration? The answers to
these questions clearly have major implications not only for the UK, but
also for the migrants' countries of origin. The overall balance is
likely to have an impact first on the natives' attitude towards
migration, and second on future immigration policies at home and in the
sending economies.
In general, it is argued that inflows of migrants can have an
impact on the host country's labour market as well as on its
welfare and pension systems, effects that can be either beneficial or
negative. However, the fiscal burden of migration, the impact on
unemployment and arguments related to migrants' labour mobility,
whilst important, are not covered here. Our focus in this paper is on
the dynamic long-run growth implications of migration for both the UK
and the EU. We examine migration of different compositions and identify
both aggregate effects and the beneficiaries and losers. (2)
We must therefore start with the following question: who is the
typical immigrant to the UK and the EU from within and from outside the
EU? Immigrants' skill composition plays a fundamental role in our
analysis and for this reason migration trends by skill group are
examined in some detail in section 2. The rest of the paper is then
organised as follows. Section 3 reviews related empirical evidence of
the economic impact of migration and its skill composition. Section 4
presents our theoretical framework in which we describe a two-bloc
endogenous growth model with labour mobility of different skill
compositions. Section 5 then reports simulation results based on this
model. Finally we conclude and discuss some policy implications in
section 6.
2. Migration trends
The purpose of this section is to assess both the aggregate inflows
and the skill composition of migration into the UK and the EU from the
early 1990s.
2.1 Total and net migration for the UK
Our figures are obtained from the Office for National Statistics
for all International Migration estimates, which are mainly based on the
International Passenger Survey. Although these are the official
estimates for the UK, the sampling variation is quite large and it only
considers long-term migration (those intending to stay/ leave for more
than one year on arrival/departure) so will miss many A8 migrants. (3)
The number of immigrants in the UK has doubled between 1992 and
2009. Figure 1 shows that over 500,000 migrants are estimated to have
arrived in each year since 2004. This compares with a figure of fewer
than 300,000 in 1992, gradually increasing over the following decade.
The figure jumped to 586,000 in 2004 (the year of major EU enlargement)
and reached the highest figure on record, 596,000, in 2006, followed by
the second highest figure, 590,000, in 2008, of which 86 per cent were
non-British citizens.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The estimated number of people leaving the UK was just under
300,000 in the early 1990s, similar to the number of immigrants. This
trend was maintained until 1997 and, since then, the number of emigrants
has increased by over 100,000 to 400,000 in 2006 and to 427,000, the
highest numbers on record, in 2008. This is compared with 340,000 in
2007. The rise in 2008, the year the UK was hit by the worldwide
financial crisis, was the result of a large (about 50 per cent) increase
in emigration of non-British citizens, especially returning A8 migrants.
Net migration, measured by the difference between these inflows and
outflows, was around 50,000 until 1997 and increased to 244,000 (the
record highest) in 2004 and slightly decreased in 2005 and 2006, picking
up again to 237,000 in 2007. The figure then decreased to 163,000 in
2008. Despite this long-term increase in net immigration it should be
pointed out that the share of immigration stock in total population (
10.7 per cent in 2007) is lower in the UK than in other OECD countries
such as Canada (20.1 per cent), Sweden ( 13.4 per cent), and Germany (13
per cent). (4)
2.2 Skill composition of all immigrants in the UK
Immigrants in the UK have, on average, higher educational
attainment than UK-born workers and more recent immigrants appear to be
more educated than existing immigrants. (5) Figure 2 shows that, as
total immigrants rise, the number of immigrants with every usual
occupation prior to migration has increased since 1991. From this
figure, the biggest occupational category of immigrants to the UK has
been the professional and managerial group. By contrast, the absolute
number of immigrants with 'other adults', consisting of adult
dependents and adults with no job prior to migration, has been fairly
steady.
Turning to occupational shares in figure 3, the proportion of other
adults to total migration inflow has gradually decreased over time from
over 20 per cent in 1992 to below 10 per cent in 2004. The share of
immigrants with professional and managerial occupation has been around
or over 30 per cent of total immigrants for all years since 1991. The
share of immigrants in manual and clerical occupations has gradually
increased from under 20 per cent in 1991 to above 25 per cent in 2005
with a rapid increase in its absolute number since 1997--from 50,000 in
1997 to 150,000 in 2005. This flow recently decreased to 126,000 in
2008. Similarly, but more dramatically, the number and share of
immigrants who were students prior to immigration to the UK (and would
possibly become students again, employed or unemployed), has increased
from 50,000 (17 per cent) in 1992 to 175,000 (30 per cent) in 2006. Such
a trend towards skill-biased immigrants to the UK is comparable with
that of unskilled-biased migrants to the US. (6)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
However, looking at the post-migration occupational distribution of
immigrants compared to the UK-born labour force, one can find a pattern
which is somewhat different from their occupational distribution prior
to migration. (7) As discussed in Wadsworth (2010), despite the high
qualifications of immigrants compared with average UK-born workers, they
mainly tend to work in less skilled jobs than might be expected given
their previous job experience and qualifications. Importantly, this
implies that looking at immigrants' post-migration occupations
alone may well be underestimating their skill composition. This is
particularly the case for A8 migrants.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In fact, from table 3 in Wadsworth (2010) it appears that the
largest proportion of immigrants were working in professional
occupations (16.5 per cent of all immigrants). This is greater than the
share of UK-born workers in the same occupational group (13.1 per cent)
and marginally greater than a share of UK natives in managerial
occupations (16.4 per cent). At the same time, almost 16 per cent of all
immigrants worked in elementary occupations in 2009. This share has
sharply increased for new immigrants (28.4 per cent) and was much higher
than the share of the UK-born labour force serving in this occupational
group (about 10 per cent). This post-migration figure indicates that
there seems to be co-existence of both the skilled and unskilled bias of
immigrants to the UK.
2.3 Total and net migration in the EU
Figure 4 presents the long-term trends of net migration of old EU15
members and new EU12 members. There was no significant change in net
migration for either old or new EU member countries until the mid-1980s.
Since then, the size of net immigration to western EU15 countries has
gone up dramatically from virtually zero in 1980-84 to 2 million people
in 2003, followed by a fall to about 1.6 million in 2005 and then
rebounding to 1.8 million in 2007. In contrast, there was no noticeable
change in the figure for new EU12 members, with the exception of a
temporary fall in 2000-1 led by outflows from Poland, Bulgaria and
Romania.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Looking at the share of foreign citizens in the total population
for individual EU15 countries in figure 5, every old member country with
one exception (Germany, from 8.9 to 8.8 per cent) has experienced a rise
in international immigrant stock in 2000-8. Most dramatic increases are
observed in Spain, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, and the UK. Zaiceva and
Zimmermann (2008) show that most people who 'intend to move
abroad' in old EU15 countries were more likely to have relatively
non-professional occupations. However, the share of potential emigrants
with these occupations has clearly declined since 2002, and people with
other professional, self-employed, or general management occupations
have become more willing to move abroad.
2.4 Summary and issues
The main trend observed here is that both immigration and net
migration to the UK has risen since 1993 and the net migration recently
started to fall from 2007. Immigrants to the UK are, on average, more
educated than UK-born workers. (8) Immigrants to the UK with
professional and managerial occupations prior to migration tend to
comprise the largest share of total immigrants. At the same time, the
share of immigrants with manual and clerical occupations has gradually
increased, at least partly due to an increasing inflow of migrants
employed in non-professional jobs from the new EU accession countries.
This means that the high proportion of skilled immigrants has been
maintained by high inflows of relatively more professional workers from
elsewhere, such as other old EU members and non-EU overseas countries.
Like the UK, most of the other old EU member countries have experienced
a rise in international migration stock in recent years. People who
moved abroad from both the old EU15 and new EU10 countries were more
likely to have relatively non-professional but nevertheless skilled
occupations.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Finally the post-migration distribution of immigrants'
occupations is less skilled than their pre-migration occupations, which
shows overall that there does not appear to be a bias towards unskilled
migration into the UK or the old EU15. This suggests that migrants tend
to take less skilled occupations than expected given their pre-migration
occupations and qualifications and that looking at the post-migration
occupation may give a misleading estimate of skill composition.
3. Empirical evidence
A vast number of studies have investigated the economic impacts of
international migration and a large proportion of this literature has
focused on the effects of migration on economic growth. The literature
has been reviewed extensively in Borjas (1999), Card (2005), Drinkwater
et al. (2003) and Hanson (2008). Among these studies, Barro and
Sala-i-Martin (1992, 1995) investigate the effect of migration on
economic growth and income convergence based on neo-classical models in
which net migration would foster economic growth through faster
convergence to a steady state level of income per capita. They find that
regional net migration has positive effects on growth in OLS regressions
for the US and Japan (no statistically signicant growth effect is found
for European countries) and the inclusion of the migration variable
slightly increases the estimate of beta-convergence. More relevant
empirical studies have used the similar convergence regression model but
found no consensus on the effect of migration on growth and convergence.
(9)
Turning to the empirical evidence of the relationship between
migration, skill composition of migrants, and economic growth, Winters
(2001) suggests that if workers migrating from a developing country to a
developed county face a quarter of the wage gap between the two
economies, the liberalisation of the immigration quotas with a 5 per
cent increase in populations of developed countries would bring about a
global welfare gain of about $300bn at 1997 prices. Similarly, Walmsley
and Winters (2005) argue that the lifting of immigration restrictions by
developed countries on both unskilled and skilled workers from
developing countries by 3 per cent of the developed countries'
labour force would yield a global welfare gain of $150bn at 1997 prices.
A much higher (more than four times greater) welfare gain from the same
liberalisation is estimated by the World Bank (2006) using various
estimated models, concurring with our results below.
Rodrick (2004) estimates a positive gain of emigration for sending
countries, among various estimation results, such that liberalised
labour mobility with a 3 per cent increase in developed countries'
labour forces which are supplied by temporary immigrants from developing
countries for 3-5 years would stimulate the latter's annual welfare
by $200 billion. The World Bank (2006) reports that a lifting of
immigration quotas by 3 per cent of the labour force in developed
countries would deliver welfare gains to natives in both developing and
developed countries and new migrants in the latter, but this change
would cause welfare loss for old migrants in the latter. Walmsley et al.
(2009), using a model of bilateral migration flows, find that
liberalisation of quotas on both unskilled and skilled workers from
developing economies by 3 per cent of the labour force in high-income
countries would yield increases in real GDP for the developed economies
which use the increased labour supply in production, while, in the
spirit of our exercise in the next section, gains to the developing
countries seem to depend on the magnitudes of remittances sent home and
thus differ across the labour exporting developing economies.
Walmsley et al. (2009) also suggest that although the labour
importing developed countries would experience gains per migrant from
both unskilled and skilled migration, the gains from skilled migration
are greater than those from unskilled migration. Again this concurs with
our results (see sections 5.2 and 5.3). Such increases in labour supply,
induced by the lifting of the imnqigration quotas, are found to reduce
the wages of both unskilled and skilled workers in the labour-importing
developed economies by approximately 1.5 per cent. However, there is
little econometric evidence that immigration to the UK has reduced wages
and employment for UK-born workers in the UK (see Manacorda et al.,
2007). All natives in both country groups would experience gains in
terms of real GDP because the increased migration brings about increased
returns to capital and increased tax revenues to the labour importing
developed countries, while it raises wages and remittances from abroad
in the labour-exporting developing countries.
Recent literature has found that, since higher returns to education
are expected from skilled workers than from unskilled workers, an
increase in the skilled migration prospects would foster human capital
formation even from the perspective of the sending countries. In Beine
et al. (2001, 2008), for instance, it is found that, when an economy is
open to migration, such increased migration opportunities, particularly
in economies with low-skilled emigration rates, stimulate investment in
education due to higher expected returns to education and thus increase
human capital stock. They also find that this beneficial brain effect of
migration dominates the drain effect owing to the emigration of some
workers. In contrast, Marchiori et al. (2009) show that for countries
with high-skilled emigration rates, the brain drain effect dominates the
brain gain effect as reduced-skilled workers would hamper innovation
activities or technology adaptation in the sending country on top of the
reduced capacity in domestic production. This concurs with our results
(see section 5.2).
4. A theory of growth, migration and skills
We first need to model the process by which innovation and other
economic processes affect longer-term rates of growth. This has been the
subject of a burgeoning theoretical and empirical literature in recent
years. In contrast with the earlier neoclassical theory developed by
Solow, which invoked exogenous technical change to explain sustained
growth, the focus of this new endogenous growth theory is on how the
consumption and savings decisions of households, the investment
decisions of firms and public policy determine growth. Positive
externalities from R&D expenditure and investment in physical or
human capital figure prominently in this theory and indeed can provide
the engine for sustained growth, providing a potential role for
governments to raise growth by providing subsidies to private
investment, R&D, training and education.
The endogenous growth literature can usefully be divided into two
broad strands. The first is closer to the Solow tradition and emphasises
capital accumulation as the engine of growth, with capital broadly
defined to include human and physical components. In the Solow model
growth cannot be sustained in the long run without the presence of
exogenous technical change because capital accumulation is accompanied
by a fall in the marginal product of capital. Income from investment and
therefore savings also fall to a point where the latter only replace
worn-out equipment and plant. The economy then only grows in the long
run if there is labour or capital augmenting technical change. Various
mechanisms have been suggested by which the tendency of the marginal
product to fall can be offset, allowing investment to generate sustained
growth. The introduction of human capital accumulation or capital
externalities can in principle prevent the marginal product of physical
capital diminishing as the latter accumulates and long-run growth
emerges, driven ultimately by the determinants of investment. The
complete story is not as straightforward as all this implies; the
contribution of the human and physical capital externality must be
sufficient to prevent growth petering out, but at the same time these
effects must not be excessive, otherwise a balanced growth path is not
achieved. Rather restrictive theoretical conditions are needed to ensure
that this is so, which may not hold true in the real world.
The model to be developed here draws upon a second broad strand of
the literature in which the discovery of new goods and processes
provides the engine of growth. R&D activity provides blueprints for
these innovations and in turn requires the input from what Grossman and
Helpman (1991) refer to as knowledge capital, by which they mean a body
of scientific knowledge and techniques not specific to any one
production process. Knowledge capital has two important characteristics
that drive growth. First, it is a public good. It is non-rival (ie one
firm's consumption of knowledge does not reduce the amount
available to others) and it is non-excludable. Second, corresponding to
the idea of learning by doing in Arrow (1962), knowledge capital
increases with the cumulative R&D experience and therefore with the
total stock of new goods in the economy. These two assumptions regarding
knowledge capital can be used to explain the idea of a capital
externality in the previous strand of growth theories. For the R&D
strand of growth theory one question remains: what drives R&D
investment? Schumpeter (1942) argued that it is driven by the expected
profitability of the new product reflecting conditions in the relevant
factor and product markets that determines the amount invested in
R&D and with it the pace and direction of industrial innovation.
Monopoly profits from the sale of new goods play a central role, another
Schumpeterian idea, and this departure from perfect competition is a
further feature that distinguishes the R&D-led view of economic
growth. Translated into formal theory, an investment in a new blueprint
will be undertaken if the expected net present value from the future
stream of monopoly profits (taking into account the possibility of
losing the monopoly position through an erosion of patent rights) equals
the initial outlay on R&D. The resulting growth of the aggregate
economy will depend on the interaction between firms producing
distinctive goods and earning monopoly profits, the same or different
firms engaging in R&D activity to invent new blueprints and
consumers making savings and consumption decisions and supplying labour.
Globalisation of economies adds a further dimension to the theory
of growth. Trade, borrowing and lending in world financial markets and
the international mobility of factors of production can all contribute
to growth on a world scale. Knowledge capital now becomes a public good
on an international scale. Every country can benefit from the emergence
of new scientific knowledge and techniques in any single country.
Countries that are best equipped both to absorb these spillovers as well
as generate new ideas themselves will outperform others.
It is necessary at this stage to distinguish between two products
of R&D. The first we have discussed and is described as knowledge
capital. To recap, this is not specific to any particular new product
but is a public good consisting of a stock of general scientific and
technical ideas which will prove useful to the next generation of
innovators. The second product is a private good protected, albeit
imperfectly, by patent laws and consists of a blueprint for a new good
or industrial process. Firms will undertake R&D if the expected
value of future monopoly profits exceeds the initial fixed costs.
By introducing migration into the picture, asymmetries between
sending and host regions now become a central feature. Following Parente
and Prescott (2000) we assume that both East and West have access to the
same common technologies, but the ability of firms to avail themselves
of the best technology differ in the two blocs, leading to different
total factor productivities (TFPs). Estimates from Hall and Jones (1999)
suggest that TFP levels are far lower in the new EU10 than the old EUI5.
Since our focus is on long-run growth, the question arises as to whether
large TFP differences will persist for long in the transitional
economies. Estimates of TFP growth and labour productivity for Eastern
and Western Germany in the 1990s from Burda and Hunt (2001) show that in
the first half of the decade convergence was rapid, but in the second
half it slowed down considerably, leaving Eastern labour productivity
almost frozen at around two-thirds of that in the West. This suggests
that in the transitional economies we may expect some rapid convergence
at first, but that some significant East-West TFP productivity
difference will persist for some considerable time. This is what we
assume in the model we set out below. The remaining differences between
East and West are the factor endowments of skilled and unskilled labour
and initial capital which are both higher in the West.
The questions that remain are: given that there may well be a
skill-bias if anything, what is the effect of immigration on receiving
economies in the West such as the UK? Is the effect beneficial or
adverse for growth? Does emigration have brain drain effects on sending
economies? How differently would skilled (or unskilled) migration affect
both receiving and sending economies? What factors would contribute to
immigration/ emigration benefits/costs and economic growth driven by
migration? Who are the winners and losers in both the sending and host
regions?
4.1 The model
To answer these questions, we use a formal two-bloc endogenous
growth model, based on the work of Currie et al. (1999), Chui et al.
(2001)and Levine et al. (2010) which in turn builds on the work of
Grossman and Helpman (1991). The model has two blocs, 'East'
and 'West' with the following features in each bloc:
* There are three factors of production: skilled labour, unskilled
labour and physical capital.
* In the absence of specialisation there are four sectors: a
high-technology manufacturing sector producing an expanding variety of
differentiated goods; a traditional traded sector producing a single
traded homogeneous good (e.g., food, steel); a traditional non-traded
sector produces another homogeneous good (e.g., construction, services)
and an R&D innovative sector producing blueprints for new
manufactured goods.
* As well as producing blueprints for new goods, R&D generates
knowledge capital which is a public good within and between the two
regions.
* The ranking of unskilled-skilled labour intensiveness is:
traditional non-traded, traditional traded, manufacturing and R&D.
* The assumed market structures for outputs are competitive for the
traditional and R&D sectors and monopolistic for manufacturing.
* Labour markets are assumed to clear and there are no free public
services.
* In the basic model there is no labour mobility between East and
West and this is subsequently compared with the case where migration
between these blocs occurs.
* Migration of skilled workers from East to West reduces the size
of the R&D and high-tech sectors in the East and increases it in the
West. This is the sectoral reallocation effect of migration. Potentially
with a sufficient exodus of this category of workers the East can be
left with an economy specialising in low-tech activity.
* Since TFP is higher in the West there is an efficiency effect of
East-West migration from workers with any skill level and capital being
more effectively employed.
A solution to the model constitutes a general equilibrium involving
the interaction of financial, product and labour markets. Using formal
mathematical models such as this has a number of advantages over simple
descriptive analysis. Often mathematical modelling confirms the initial
intuition of more descriptive models and therefore provides an
invaluable check on the coherence of the argument. Sometimes formal
models provide surprises and further insights which either explain
stylised facts or provide the basis for empirical investigation.
4.2 The immigration and emigration surpluses
The 'immigration surplus' according to Borjas (1995) is
the increase in income of the indigenous population of the host country
following immigration. The simplest model to assess the magnitude of the
immigration surplus is as follows. Consider two economies,
'East' and 'West' where wages are perfectly
flexible. Capital of both the physical and human variety is fixed and
higher in the West. Both average and marginal output per worker is
therefore higher in the West. In addition, following the recent
literature on income differences between countries (10) we assume that
total factor productivity is higher in the West, which creates a further
outward shift in the Western marginal product of labour curve relative
to the East.
Figure 6 shows what happens when migration from East to West
occurs. The Eastern workforce (fully employed by assumption) falls from
OA by an amount HA increasing the Western workforce by the same amount
AB = HA. The area under the marginal product of labour (MPL) curves
gives total output and the MPL (West) is higher than its Eastern
counterpart MPL (East) because physical and human capital is higher in
the West. Ignore for the moment human capital differences; then one unit
of Eastern labour is equivalent to one unit of Western labour. Output
then rises by an amount KDBA in the West and falls by an amount FJAH =
ECBA in the East. The net increase in world output is therefore given by
the region KDCE. The real wage falls in the West and rises in the East.
If there are costs associated with migration and migrants maximise
income net of costs, migration will cease before wages are equalised.
Figure 6 shows the case of factor price equalisation where migration
costs are zero and migration leads to equal wage rates. Migrants gain by
an amount EDCJ; non-migrants in the East see total output fall by an
amount FJG. The original Western population gains by the shaded amount
KDE--the immigration surplus. This constitutes a total gain of [w.sub.w]
[KD.sub.w] for Western capital and a loss of [w.sub.w] [KE.sub.w] for
Western workers. Similarly the non-migrants in the East lose by an
amount F GJ = EJC; wF [Gw.sub.E] is a gain for Eastern workers and wF
[Jw.sub.E] is a loss for Eastern capitalists. Thus the losers are the
original Western workers and Eastern capitalists; the winners are the
migrants and Western capitalists.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
This simple analysis does not differentiate between different types
of labour but Borjas (1995) does go on to discuss the importance of the
skill composition of immigrants. This is because the skill level of
immigrants will determine the degree to which immigrants will be
competing with natives for jobs and hence what impact they will have on
their wages as well as establishing the relationship between these
different skill groups and capital. Borjas (1995) suggests that as the
complementarity of skilled labour and capital rises (Hamermesh, 1993),
the immigration surplus can increase substantially if immigration
consists mainly of skilled workers, although this will depend on the
original mix of unskilled and skilled workers in the population.
Therefore, the key issue to establish is whether immigrants and natives
are substitutes or complements in the production process and, as a
result, a relatively large literature has emerged on estimating the
extent of the substitutability/complementarity between native and
immigrant workers. (11)
The welfare gain (or loss) in the East, the Emigration Surplus and
the World Surplus are assessed in a similar fashion. In the numerical
results both are measured in utility terms as the percentage equivalent
permanent consumption change relative to the balanced-growth steady
state.
5. Simulation results
The properties of the general equilibrium solution obtained
numerically and the calibration used are set out in detail in Levine et
al. (2010). Here we provide a summary of the main findings.
The impact of migration in the host and in the receiving country is
a result of counteracting forces. Some authors focus on the impact on
wages and on labour market conditions in general, as in Borjas (1995).
Others, such as Lundborg and Segerstrom (2000, 2002) look at the
negative impact on the asset value of equity issued to finance R&D.
In our general equilibrium framework the factors that contribute to the
immigration/emigration surplus/deficit are: technological
complementarities, terms of trade, change in asset prices, efficiency
and sectoral reallocation effects. The static and dynamic effects often
have a counteracting impact on economic welfare at home and abroad.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
We consider the case where the East is relatively less endowed with
skilled labour and total factor productivity (TFP) is lower in the East.
With this particular pattern of skill-labour endowments and TFP in the
two regions, we examine the effect of East-West migration with different
skill compositions. Though all the effects are present in our
simulations, by concentrating on migration with and without skill bias,
keeping the other parameters fixed, we focus our analysis on the
efficiency and the sectoral reallocation effects of international
migration highlighted above.
5.1 Migration with no skill bias
Figure 7 shows the effect of a 10 per cent increase in the Western
population from immigration with no skill bias in its composition. An
increase in growth now occurs of 0.25 per cent which is almost entirely
the result of a movement of workers from a country with a low TFP to one
with a high TFP (the efficiency effect). All sectors in the West grow as
they absorb the immigrant workers. The transfer of workers from a less
to a more efficient R&D sector sees the Western share of new
products rise and world growth rises. The consequent increase in demand
for high-skill labour causes the relative skill-unskilled wage in both
blocs to rise. There is a small rise in the Western R&D share and a
small decrease in the corresponding share in the East. The world surplus
is worked out as the equivalent percentage permanent change in
consumption for a representative household consisting of skilled and
unskilled workers, in the East and in the West, weighted according to
post-migration proportions. There is a maximum world surplus of 9 per
cent when migration reaches 10 per cent of the Western workforce. The
details of the effect of these changes on welfare is summarised in
panels (b) to (d) of figure 7. The world surplus breaks down into 1 per
cent for Western skilled workers and about 0.5 per cent for native
unskilled workers, giving an immigration surplus of around 0.85 per cent
for the representative Western native household (figure 7b). For those
remaining in the East, skilled workers gain by over 0.75 per cent,
unskilled workers lose by -1.35 per cent, giving an emigration deficit
for the representative Eastern nonmigrant of about -1.2 per cent (figure
7c). Finally, figure 7(d) shows that the representative migrant gains by
a substantial 200 per cent. In summary, with our parameter values, the
positive efficiency effect comes to dominate the potential static
negative effects highlighted in the literature. Winners in order of the
size of gain are migrants, overwhelmingly, followed by skilled workers
in the West, unskilled workers in the West and skilled workers in the
East. The only losers are unskilled workers in the East.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
5.2 Migration with skill bias
We now show the impact in our model of a 10 per cent increase in
the Western population from immigration with skill bias. A change in the
composition of labour will have an impact on the way resources are
allocated between the different sectors (sectoral reallocation effect)
with a positive or negative impact on growth depending on the type of
migration we are considering. In this framework with biased migration,
the manufacturing and R&D sectors play an important role. Our next
set of simulations in figure 8 looks at the effect of a 10 per cent
increase in the Western population consisting of skilled workers. Now
there are substantial reallocation effects in both blocs, towards
high-tech activity in the West and the opposite in the East, arising
from the changes in the proportions of skilled to unskilled workers.
Indeed skilled migration of over 5 per cent of the Western workforce
sees the R&D and high-tech sectors disappear altogether in the East.
Taken together with the efficiency effect of a movement from a less
to a more efficient economy, growth now rises by over 0.5 per cent
(figure 8a). The world surplus now rises to 11 per cent. The immigration
surplus is almost 12 per cent for unskilled natives, -2.5 per cent for
skilled natives averaging at almost 6 per cent (figure 8b). The
emigration surplus is 17 per cent for skilled, -50 per cent for
unskilled averaging at -10 per cent (figure 8c), but both skilled and
unskilled migrants gain substantially again (figure 8d). Winners, again
in order of gain, are migrants, unskilled workers in the West and
skilled workers in the East. The losers are skilled workers in the West
and unskilled workers in the East. So the distributional effect of
skilled migration is to reduce inequality in the West, but do the
opposite in the East.
5.3 Unskilled migration
We now look at the impact of a 10 per cent increase in the Western
population consisting of unskilled migration. This seems to be the least
relevant case according to our assessment of migration trends in section
2. Unskilled migration now has a negative impact on the world growth
rate. (12) From figure 9, in comparison with skilled migration, we now
have an opposite symmetrical sectoral reallocation effect owing to a
change in the opposite direction of the proportion of skilled and
unskilled workers in the West, but there is still a positive efficiency
effect due to a movement of workers from a country with a low TFP to one
with a high TFP. The world surplus is now a modest 0.4 per cent. The
emigration surplus is 13 per cent for unskilled and -12 per cent for
skilled while the immigration surplus is 5 per cent for skilled natives
and -16 per cent for unskilled natives. Winners, once again in order of
gain, are migrants, unskilled workers in the East and skilled workers in
the West. The losers are unskilled workers in the West and skilled
workers in the East. So now the distributional effect of unskilled
migration is to increase inequality in the West, but do the opposite in
the East.
5.4 Summary
The main result that emerges is that while unskilled migration
decreases growth, migration of no-skill bias and skilled migration from
a low to a high TFP region of the world increases growth, but in the
absence of some distribution mechanism there are winners and losers,
with remaining non-migrants in the latter category. The reason is that
the East sees a reduction in its share of high-tech goods which involve
a price mark-up over marginal cost, and the relative wage of the
unskilled workers falls. Distributional effects are summarised in table
1.
One possible distribution mechanism is through remittances from
migrants to their families remaining in the East. In Levine et al.
(2010) we examine the effects of skilled migrants remitting a given
percentage of their income ranging between 0 per cent and 50 per cent.
Assuming that families are either entirely skilled or unskilled, these
remittances will end up in the pockets of skilled households in the
East. This group were winners in the absence of remittances so
remittances in themselves do not mitigate the distributional effects of
migration. However if we assume that intra-country distributional
mechanisms exist, or that households are of a mixed skilled type, then
we can focus on the representative household in both blocs. Then we can
show that, at any remittance rate above around 35 per cent, migrants
remain substantial winners, and the Eastern representative household
begins to emerge as a winner. These welfare effects with remittances are
summarised in table 2.
6. Conclusions and policy implications
In this section we summarise our results and attempt to formulate
their policy implications. The East-West European migration that
followed the 2004 and 2007 enlargements has created one of the most
interesting migration-policy 'laboratories' in the world. In
light of the main results that emerge in section 5 it is useful to
summarise the nature of European migration flows since World War II.
Periods of labour shortages such as in the 1960s induced active
recruitment policies in some European countries. This openness was
followed by a period of restrained migration. Since the fall of the
Berlin wall, all CEECs now grant their citizens the right to migrate and
from that time East-West migration started to gain particular attention.
However some EU countries still maintained barriers to immigration.
Following recent enlargements, much East to West migration was
anticipated. The UK did not initially impose any transitional
restrictions on labour mobility and has clearly experienced an increase
in the number of immigrants, particularly from the East. A well-known
result shown in the migration literature, namely the prediction that
benefits and losses from integration will be distributed unevenly among
the individual factors of production, deserves special attention.
In a static economic analysis of labour markets, migration could
decrease wages or the probability of being employed of workers who
directly compete with immigrants. In our general equilibrium framework
we look at the overall picture and we focus on the dynamic long-run
aspect of migration. Section 5 shows that migration, in general, is
beneficial to the receiving country and increases the world growth rate.
The only exception is in the case of unskilled migration which can
actually have a detrimental impact on the world growth rate. This
possibility however seems to be unlikely from our examination of
migration trends in section 2 which suggests that, if anything, the
skill composition of immigrants is biased towards skilled workers. (13)
The debate which has focused on the role of institutions and
governments as mechanisms that can regulate migration and its
composition as well as mitigate the potential negative impact of
immigration on the receiving countries, poses many controversial
questions. Here we focus on an aspect that can capture them all: what
are the dynamic consequences of migration in the host and in the sending
economy? To summarise the main result of our theoretical framework, the
dynamic aspect magnifies the role of high-skilled migration. Depending
on the skill group, some workers in the East and West lose even if
overall the receiving and the sending economies gain.
How does this translate in terms of policy recommendations? First
of all, given the potential benefits of migration for the long-term
growth rate, especially if migrants are high-skilled, an overly
restrictive migration policy may constrain the overall growth in both
regions. However our analysis gives strong support to policies supported
by all mainstream parties in the UK to restrict immigration from non-EU
countries to skilled workers. Second, whether the resulting immigration
and emigration surpluses are significant or not, winners and losers
remain and this suggests that compensating redistributive policies can
mitigate the distributional effect of migration. We have examined one
such mechanism--remittances--but clearly there is a role for policy
that, as well as encouraging these flows, needs to ensure that overall
economic gains are more equally distributed through measures using the
tax system, welfare-to-work and the provision of public services.
Finally, our analysis points to a greater need to integrate immigrants
in order to reduce the gap between post-migration and premigration
distribution of immigrants' occupations. While part of this gap can
be explained in terms of the temporary nature of migration, particularly
for A8 migrants, we believe there is scope for improving migrants'
integration (i.e language effective training, advice from employment
services etc). We think that migrants' skill depreciation due to
limited integration can pose a severe limit to their economic
contribution and requires special attention.
Clearly, our investigation of the macroeconomic impact of migration
is not exhaustive. For example, we do not look at the impact of
migration on unemployment. While short-run effects on unemployment in
the host country are not excluded, Ortega (2000) offers a theoretical
explanation of why immigration can be beneficial to the native worker,
while Borjas' (2001) 'greasing the wheels' argument (14)
provides another optimistic view of the labour market impact of
migration in the host economy. The impact of migration can also be
analysed from a different perspective. For example, an important
question concerns the role that migrants can have in mitigating the
fiscal burden associated with the phenomenon of an aging population. A
strand of research, using a general equilibrium overlapping generations
framework, looks at the net fiscal impact of migration. The answer to
this is in part related to the skill composition of the migrant (Ortega,
2005, Cohen and Razin, 2009, and Cohen et al., 2009).
Concerns over skilled migration have been raised by the literature
on the 'brain drain' in the source economies. We have seen
from a theoretical perspective that, as high-skilled migrants move to
the country with a higher TFP, world growth increases, but results in a
decrease in the size of the 'modern' manufacturing and R&D
sectors in the sending economy. Although not formalised in our
framework, migration can increase the overall level of human capital in
the source economy by increasing investment in human capital (Beine et
al., 2008). Remittances, which in our model have only the function of a
redistributive device, can provide important benefits by increasing
human and physical capital investment. Clearly, different policy
recommendations in the sending economy are dependant on whether it
perceives either a brain drain or brain gain.
doi: 10.1177/0027950110380321
REFERENCES
Arrow, K.J. (1962), 'The economic implications of learning by
doing', Review of Economic Studies, 29, 3, pp. 155-73.
Barrell, R., FitzGerald, J. and Riley, R. (2007), 'EU
enlargement and migration: assessing the macroeconomic impact',
NIESR Discussion Paper 292.
Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992), 'Regional growth and
migration: a Japan-United States comparison', Journal of the
Japanese and International Economies, 6, pp. 312-46.
--(1995), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill.
Beine, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2001), 'Brain drain
and economic growth: theory and evidence', Journal of Development
Economics, 64(I), pp. 275-89.
--(2008), 'Brain drain and human capital formation in
developing countries: winners and losers', Economic Journal,
118(528), pp. 631-52.
Borjas, G. (1995), 'The economic benefits from
immigration', Journal of Economic literature, 9(2), pp. 3-22.
--(1999), 'The economic analysis of immigration', in
Ashenfelter, O.C. and Card, D. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics,
Amsterdam, North-Holland, pp. 1697-760.
--(2001), 'Does immigration grease the wheels of the labor
market?' Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 69-133.
Buch, C.M. and Toubal, F. (2009), 'Openness and growth: the
long shadow of the Berlin Wall', Journal of Macroeconomics, 31, pp.
409-22.
Burda, M. and Hunt, J. (2001), 'From reunification to economic
integration: productivity and the labour market in Eastern
Germany', Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 1-92.
Card, D. (2005), 'Is the new immigration really so bad?',
Economic Journal, 115, 507, pp. 300-23.
Chui, M., Levine, P. and Pearlman, J. (2001), 'Winners and
losers in a North-South model of growth, innovation and product
cycles', Journal of Development Economics, 65, pp. 333-65.
Cohen, A. and Razin, A. (2009), 'Skill composition of
migration and the generosity of the welfare state: free vs.
policy-controlled migration', mimeo 641, Tel-Aviv University.
Cohen, A., Razin, A., and Sadka, E. (2009), 'The skill
composition of migrants and the generosity of the welfare state',
CEPR Discussion Paper Series 7185, February.
Currie, D., Levine, P., Pearlman, J. and Chui, M. (1999),
'Phases of imitation and innovation in a North-South endogenous
growth model', Oxford Economic Papers, 51 (1), pp. 60-88.
Drinkwater, S. and Clark, K. (2008), 'The labour-market
performance of recent migrants', Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
24(3), pp. 495-516.
Drinkwater, S., Levine, P., Lotti, E. and Pearlman, J. (2003),
'The economic impact of migration: a survey', International
Journal for Economic Development, 5, 2.
--(2007), 'The immigration surplus revisited in a general
equilibrium model with endogenous growth', Journal of Regional
Science, 47(3), pp. 569-601.
Dustmann, C., Fabbri, F. and Preston, I. (2005), 'The impact
of immigration on the British labour market', Economic Journal
115(507), F324-F341.
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the
Global Economy, Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press.
Hall, R. and Jones, C.I. (1999), 'Why some countries produce
so much more output per worker than others', Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 114, pp. 82-116.
Hamermesh, D. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton, Princeton University
Press.
Hanson, G.H. (2008), 'The economic consequences of the
international migration of labor', NBER Working Paper 14490,
November.
Kahanec, M. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2008), 'Migration in an
enlarged EU: a challenging solution?', IZA Discussion Paper No.
3913, December.
Kyrdar, M.G. and Saracoulu, D.S. (2008), 'Migration and
regional convergence: an empirical investigation for Turkey',
Papers in Regional Science, 87(4), pp. 545-566.
Levine, P., Lotti, E., Pearlman, J. and Pierse, R. (2010),
'Growth and welfare effects of world migration', Scottish
Journal Of Political Economy (forthcoming).
Lundborg, P. and Segerstrom, P. S. (2000), 'International
migration and growth in developed countries: a theoretical
analysis', Economica, 67, pp. 579-604.
--(2002), 'The growth and welfare effects of international
mass migration ', Journal of International Economics, 56, pp.
177-204.
Manacorda, M., Manning, A. and Wadsworth, J. (2007), 'The
impact of immigration on the structure of male wages: theory and
evidence from Britain', CEP Discussion Paper No. 754.
Marchiori, L., Shen, I. and Docquier, F. (2009), 'Brain drain
in globalization: a GE analysis from the sending countries'
perspective', prepared for a Conference at the World Bank.
Maza, A. (2006), 'Migrations and regional convergence: the
case of Spain', Jahrbuch fur Regional-wissenschaft, 26, pp.
191-202.
OECD (2009), International Migration Outlook, Paris, OECD.
Ortega, F. (2005), 'Immigration quotas and skill
upgrading', Journal of Public Economics, 89, pp. 1841-63.
Ortega, J. (2000), 'Pareto-improving immigration in an economy
with equilibrium unemployment', The Economic Journal, 110(460), pp.
92-112.
Parente, S.L. and Prescott, E.C. (2000), Barriers to Riches,
Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press.
Perssons, J. (1997), 'Convergence across the Swedish
counties', European Economic Review, 41, pp. 1835-52.
Rodrick, D. (2004), 'How to make the trade regime work for
development', mimeo, Harvard University.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New
York, Harper.
Toya, H., Hosono, K. and Makino, T. (2004), 'Human capital,
migration, and regional income convergence in the Philippines',
Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University (Tokyo)
Discussion Paper Series, No. 18.
Wadsworth, J. (2010), 'The UK labour market and
immigration', National Institute Economic Review, 213, July.
Walmsley, T.L. and Winters, L.A. (2005), 'Relaxing the
restrictions on the temporary movement of natural persons: a simulation
analysis', Journal of Economic Integration, 20(4), pp. 688-726.
Walmsley, T.L, Winters, L.A. and Ahmed, S.A. (2009),
'Measuring the impact of the movement of labor using a model of
bilateral migration flows', paper prepared for a Conference at the
World Bank.
Winters, L.A. (2001), 'Assessing the efficiency gain from
further liberalization: a comment', in Sauve, P. and Subramanian,
A. (eds), Efficiency, Equity and Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading
System and the Millennium, Chicago, Chicago University Press. pp.
106-13.
World Bank (2006), Global Economic Prospects 2006 : Economic
Implications of Remittances and Migration, Washington, DC, The World
Bank.
Zaiceva, A. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2008), 'Scale, diversity,
and determinants of labour migration in Europe', Oxford Review of
Economic Policy, 24(3), pp. 427-51.
NOTES
(1) See Wadsworth (2010).
(2) See Barrell et al. (2007) for an earlier analysis of the impact
of EU enlargement on various macroeconomic variables in both sending and
receiving countries
(3) See Drinkwater and Clark (2008) for more details and issues
arising from the inadequacy of migration data.
(4) See OECD (2009).
(5) See Wadsworth (2010).
(6) See Dustmann et al. (2005).
(7) Figures 2 and 3 use pre-migration occupations.
(8) See Wadsworth (2010).
(9) See Perssons (1997), Toya et al. (2004), Maza (2006), Kyrdar
and Saracoulu (2008) and Buch and Toubal (2009).
(10) See, for example, Parente and Prescott (2000).
(11) See Borjas (1999) for a summary of early studies.
(12) In Drinkwater et al. (2007) we also investigate the impact of
migration on the immigration surplus for different degrees of
complementarities and we show that when skilled labour and capital are
complements changes in asset prices can have a signicant effect and that
the complementarity worsens the impact of unskilled migration.
(13) This is supported by the analysis in Wadsworth (2010).
(14) Immigration injects in the economy a group of highly mobile
self-selected individuals, ready to move to exploit economic
opportunities in different areas.
Young-Bae Kim,* Paul Levine* and Emanuela Lotti**
* University of Surrey. ** University of Southampton and University
of Surrey. E-mail:
[email protected]. The authors would like to thank
Stephen Drinkwater for very helpful comments.
Table 1. Winners and losers from migration
Migration No bias Skilled Unskilled
group bias bias
Migrant Winners Winners Winners
Western Skilled Winners Losers Winners
Western Unskilled Winners Winners Losers
Eastern Skilled Winners Winners Losers
Eastern Unskilled Losers Losers Winners
Table 2. Growth, immigration surplus (IS), emigration
surplus (ES) of representative households
Type of migration Growth IS (%) ES (%)
effect (%)
Unbiased 0.3 0.85 -1.2
Skilled 0.5 5.5 -8.0
Skilled with 50%
remittances 0.5 5.5 7
Unskilled -0.35 -0.05 -6