首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月30日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Migration, skill composition and growth.
  • 作者:Kim, Young-Bae ; Levine, Paul ; Lotti, Emanuela
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:July
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 摘要:Keywords: Migration; labour mobility; skill composition; economic growth
  • 关键词:Economic growth;Emigration and immigration;Emigration and immigration law;Immigration law

Migration, skill composition and growth.


Kim, Young-Bae ; Levine, Paul ; Lotti, Emanuela 等


The UK, with its relatively liberal immigration policies following recent enlargements, has been one of the main recipients of migrants from new EU member states.T his paper poses the questions: what is the effect of immigration on a receiving economy such as the UK? Is the effect beneficial or adverse for growth? Does emigration have brain drain effects on sending economies? How differently would skilled (or unskilled) migration affect both receiving and sending economies? What factors would contribute to immigration/emigration benefits/costs and economic growth driven by migration? Who are the winners and losers in both the sending and host regions? We utilise a two-bloc endogenous growth model with labour mobility of different skill compositions to address these questions. We show that migration, in general, is beneficial to the receiving country and increases the world growth rate. With remittances, the sending country in aggregate can also benefit. The only exception is in the case of unskilled migration, which can actually have a detrimental impact on the world growth rate. This possibility however seems to be unlikely by our examination of migration trends. Winners are migrants, and the skill group in the region that sees its relative size decrease.

Keywords: Migration; labour mobility; skill composition; economic growth

JEL Classifications: F22; F43; J24; J61; O41

I. Introduction

Labour mobility is one of the most important and controversial issues in contemporary economic and political debates. In the lead-up to the recent general election in the UK, it appears that migration was perceived as a burden for the indigenous population, resulting in less liberal migration policies proposed by all the major political parties. It is clear that the post-enlargement migration in the European Union, as well as migration from outside the EU15, has raised the UK population since the beginning of the 1990s. Since the onset of the economic crises, immigration has declined, but still over 14 per cent of those of working age in the UK were born abroad. (1) The UK economy, with its relatively liberal immigration policies following the two most recent enlargements, has been one of the main recipients from the new EU countries. Does this make the UK economy stronger or weaker? What are the economic benefits/costs associated with migration? The answers to these questions clearly have major implications not only for the UK, but also for the migrants' countries of origin. The overall balance is likely to have an impact first on the natives' attitude towards migration, and second on future immigration policies at home and in the sending economies.

In general, it is argued that inflows of migrants can have an impact on the host country's labour market as well as on its welfare and pension systems, effects that can be either beneficial or negative. However, the fiscal burden of migration, the impact on unemployment and arguments related to migrants' labour mobility, whilst important, are not covered here. Our focus in this paper is on the dynamic long-run growth implications of migration for both the UK and the EU. We examine migration of different compositions and identify both aggregate effects and the beneficiaries and losers. (2)

We must therefore start with the following question: who is the typical immigrant to the UK and the EU from within and from outside the EU? Immigrants' skill composition plays a fundamental role in our analysis and for this reason migration trends by skill group are examined in some detail in section 2. The rest of the paper is then organised as follows. Section 3 reviews related empirical evidence of the economic impact of migration and its skill composition. Section 4 presents our theoretical framework in which we describe a two-bloc endogenous growth model with labour mobility of different skill compositions. Section 5 then reports simulation results based on this model. Finally we conclude and discuss some policy implications in section 6.

2. Migration trends

The purpose of this section is to assess both the aggregate inflows and the skill composition of migration into the UK and the EU from the early 1990s.

2.1 Total and net migration for the UK

Our figures are obtained from the Office for National Statistics for all International Migration estimates, which are mainly based on the International Passenger Survey. Although these are the official estimates for the UK, the sampling variation is quite large and it only considers long-term migration (those intending to stay/ leave for more than one year on arrival/departure) so will miss many A8 migrants. (3)

The number of immigrants in the UK has doubled between 1992 and 2009. Figure 1 shows that over 500,000 migrants are estimated to have arrived in each year since 2004. This compares with a figure of fewer than 300,000 in 1992, gradually increasing over the following decade. The figure jumped to 586,000 in 2004 (the year of major EU enlargement) and reached the highest figure on record, 596,000, in 2006, followed by the second highest figure, 590,000, in 2008, of which 86 per cent were non-British citizens.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The estimated number of people leaving the UK was just under 300,000 in the early 1990s, similar to the number of immigrants. This trend was maintained until 1997 and, since then, the number of emigrants has increased by over 100,000 to 400,000 in 2006 and to 427,000, the highest numbers on record, in 2008. This is compared with 340,000 in 2007. The rise in 2008, the year the UK was hit by the worldwide financial crisis, was the result of a large (about 50 per cent) increase in emigration of non-British citizens, especially returning A8 migrants.

Net migration, measured by the difference between these inflows and outflows, was around 50,000 until 1997 and increased to 244,000 (the record highest) in 2004 and slightly decreased in 2005 and 2006, picking up again to 237,000 in 2007. The figure then decreased to 163,000 in 2008. Despite this long-term increase in net immigration it should be pointed out that the share of immigration stock in total population ( 10.7 per cent in 2007) is lower in the UK than in other OECD countries such as Canada (20.1 per cent), Sweden ( 13.4 per cent), and Germany (13 per cent). (4)

2.2 Skill composition of all immigrants in the UK

Immigrants in the UK have, on average, higher educational attainment than UK-born workers and more recent immigrants appear to be more educated than existing immigrants. (5) Figure 2 shows that, as total immigrants rise, the number of immigrants with every usual occupation prior to migration has increased since 1991. From this figure, the biggest occupational category of immigrants to the UK has been the professional and managerial group. By contrast, the absolute number of immigrants with 'other adults', consisting of adult dependents and adults with no job prior to migration, has been fairly steady.

Turning to occupational shares in figure 3, the proportion of other adults to total migration inflow has gradually decreased over time from over 20 per cent in 1992 to below 10 per cent in 2004. The share of immigrants with professional and managerial occupation has been around or over 30 per cent of total immigrants for all years since 1991. The share of immigrants in manual and clerical occupations has gradually increased from under 20 per cent in 1991 to above 25 per cent in 2005 with a rapid increase in its absolute number since 1997--from 50,000 in 1997 to 150,000 in 2005. This flow recently decreased to 126,000 in 2008. Similarly, but more dramatically, the number and share of immigrants who were students prior to immigration to the UK (and would possibly become students again, employed or unemployed), has increased from 50,000 (17 per cent) in 1992 to 175,000 (30 per cent) in 2006. Such a trend towards skill-biased immigrants to the UK is comparable with that of unskilled-biased migrants to the US. (6)

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

However, looking at the post-migration occupational distribution of immigrants compared to the UK-born labour force, one can find a pattern which is somewhat different from their occupational distribution prior to migration. (7) As discussed in Wadsworth (2010), despite the high qualifications of immigrants compared with average UK-born workers, they mainly tend to work in less skilled jobs than might be expected given their previous job experience and qualifications. Importantly, this implies that looking at immigrants' post-migration occupations alone may well be underestimating their skill composition. This is particularly the case for A8 migrants.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

In fact, from table 3 in Wadsworth (2010) it appears that the largest proportion of immigrants were working in professional occupations (16.5 per cent of all immigrants). This is greater than the share of UK-born workers in the same occupational group (13.1 per cent) and marginally greater than a share of UK natives in managerial occupations (16.4 per cent). At the same time, almost 16 per cent of all immigrants worked in elementary occupations in 2009. This share has sharply increased for new immigrants (28.4 per cent) and was much higher than the share of the UK-born labour force serving in this occupational group (about 10 per cent). This post-migration figure indicates that there seems to be co-existence of both the skilled and unskilled bias of immigrants to the UK.

2.3 Total and net migration in the EU

Figure 4 presents the long-term trends of net migration of old EU15 members and new EU12 members. There was no significant change in net migration for either old or new EU member countries until the mid-1980s. Since then, the size of net immigration to western EU15 countries has gone up dramatically from virtually zero in 1980-84 to 2 million people in 2003, followed by a fall to about 1.6 million in 2005 and then rebounding to 1.8 million in 2007. In contrast, there was no noticeable change in the figure for new EU12 members, with the exception of a temporary fall in 2000-1 led by outflows from Poland, Bulgaria and Romania.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

Looking at the share of foreign citizens in the total population for individual EU15 countries in figure 5, every old member country with one exception (Germany, from 8.9 to 8.8 per cent) has experienced a rise in international immigrant stock in 2000-8. Most dramatic increases are observed in Spain, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, and the UK. Zaiceva and Zimmermann (2008) show that most people who 'intend to move abroad' in old EU15 countries were more likely to have relatively non-professional occupations. However, the share of potential emigrants with these occupations has clearly declined since 2002, and people with other professional, self-employed, or general management occupations have become more willing to move abroad.

2.4 Summary and issues

The main trend observed here is that both immigration and net migration to the UK has risen since 1993 and the net migration recently started to fall from 2007. Immigrants to the UK are, on average, more educated than UK-born workers. (8) Immigrants to the UK with professional and managerial occupations prior to migration tend to comprise the largest share of total immigrants. At the same time, the share of immigrants with manual and clerical occupations has gradually increased, at least partly due to an increasing inflow of migrants employed in non-professional jobs from the new EU accession countries. This means that the high proportion of skilled immigrants has been maintained by high inflows of relatively more professional workers from elsewhere, such as other old EU members and non-EU overseas countries. Like the UK, most of the other old EU member countries have experienced a rise in international migration stock in recent years. People who moved abroad from both the old EU15 and new EU10 countries were more likely to have relatively non-professional but nevertheless skilled occupations.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

Finally the post-migration distribution of immigrants' occupations is less skilled than their pre-migration occupations, which shows overall that there does not appear to be a bias towards unskilled migration into the UK or the old EU15. This suggests that migrants tend to take less skilled occupations than expected given their pre-migration occupations and qualifications and that looking at the post-migration occupation may give a misleading estimate of skill composition.

3. Empirical evidence

A vast number of studies have investigated the economic impacts of international migration and a large proportion of this literature has focused on the effects of migration on economic growth. The literature has been reviewed extensively in Borjas (1999), Card (2005), Drinkwater et al. (2003) and Hanson (2008). Among these studies, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992, 1995) investigate the effect of migration on economic growth and income convergence based on neo-classical models in which net migration would foster economic growth through faster convergence to a steady state level of income per capita. They find that regional net migration has positive effects on growth in OLS regressions for the US and Japan (no statistically signicant growth effect is found for European countries) and the inclusion of the migration variable slightly increases the estimate of beta-convergence. More relevant empirical studies have used the similar convergence regression model but found no consensus on the effect of migration on growth and convergence. (9)

Turning to the empirical evidence of the relationship between migration, skill composition of migrants, and economic growth, Winters (2001) suggests that if workers migrating from a developing country to a developed county face a quarter of the wage gap between the two economies, the liberalisation of the immigration quotas with a 5 per cent increase in populations of developed countries would bring about a global welfare gain of about $300bn at 1997 prices. Similarly, Walmsley and Winters (2005) argue that the lifting of immigration restrictions by developed countries on both unskilled and skilled workers from developing countries by 3 per cent of the developed countries' labour force would yield a global welfare gain of $150bn at 1997 prices. A much higher (more than four times greater) welfare gain from the same liberalisation is estimated by the World Bank (2006) using various estimated models, concurring with our results below.

Rodrick (2004) estimates a positive gain of emigration for sending countries, among various estimation results, such that liberalised labour mobility with a 3 per cent increase in developed countries' labour forces which are supplied by temporary immigrants from developing countries for 3-5 years would stimulate the latter's annual welfare by $200 billion. The World Bank (2006) reports that a lifting of immigration quotas by 3 per cent of the labour force in developed countries would deliver welfare gains to natives in both developing and developed countries and new migrants in the latter, but this change would cause welfare loss for old migrants in the latter. Walmsley et al. (2009), using a model of bilateral migration flows, find that liberalisation of quotas on both unskilled and skilled workers from developing economies by 3 per cent of the labour force in high-income countries would yield increases in real GDP for the developed economies which use the increased labour supply in production, while, in the spirit of our exercise in the next section, gains to the developing countries seem to depend on the magnitudes of remittances sent home and thus differ across the labour exporting developing economies.

Walmsley et al. (2009) also suggest that although the labour importing developed countries would experience gains per migrant from both unskilled and skilled migration, the gains from skilled migration are greater than those from unskilled migration. Again this concurs with our results (see sections 5.2 and 5.3). Such increases in labour supply, induced by the lifting of the imnqigration quotas, are found to reduce the wages of both unskilled and skilled workers in the labour-importing developed economies by approximately 1.5 per cent. However, there is little econometric evidence that immigration to the UK has reduced wages and employment for UK-born workers in the UK (see Manacorda et al., 2007). All natives in both country groups would experience gains in terms of real GDP because the increased migration brings about increased returns to capital and increased tax revenues to the labour importing developed countries, while it raises wages and remittances from abroad in the labour-exporting developing countries.

Recent literature has found that, since higher returns to education are expected from skilled workers than from unskilled workers, an increase in the skilled migration prospects would foster human capital formation even from the perspective of the sending countries. In Beine et al. (2001, 2008), for instance, it is found that, when an economy is open to migration, such increased migration opportunities, particularly in economies with low-skilled emigration rates, stimulate investment in education due to higher expected returns to education and thus increase human capital stock. They also find that this beneficial brain effect of migration dominates the drain effect owing to the emigration of some workers. In contrast, Marchiori et al. (2009) show that for countries with high-skilled emigration rates, the brain drain effect dominates the brain gain effect as reduced-skilled workers would hamper innovation activities or technology adaptation in the sending country on top of the reduced capacity in domestic production. This concurs with our results (see section 5.2).

4. A theory of growth, migration and skills

We first need to model the process by which innovation and other economic processes affect longer-term rates of growth. This has been the subject of a burgeoning theoretical and empirical literature in recent years. In contrast with the earlier neoclassical theory developed by Solow, which invoked exogenous technical change to explain sustained growth, the focus of this new endogenous growth theory is on how the consumption and savings decisions of households, the investment decisions of firms and public policy determine growth. Positive externalities from R&D expenditure and investment in physical or human capital figure prominently in this theory and indeed can provide the engine for sustained growth, providing a potential role for governments to raise growth by providing subsidies to private investment, R&D, training and education.

The endogenous growth literature can usefully be divided into two broad strands. The first is closer to the Solow tradition and emphasises capital accumulation as the engine of growth, with capital broadly defined to include human and physical components. In the Solow model growth cannot be sustained in the long run without the presence of exogenous technical change because capital accumulation is accompanied by a fall in the marginal product of capital. Income from investment and therefore savings also fall to a point where the latter only replace worn-out equipment and plant. The economy then only grows in the long run if there is labour or capital augmenting technical change. Various mechanisms have been suggested by which the tendency of the marginal product to fall can be offset, allowing investment to generate sustained growth. The introduction of human capital accumulation or capital externalities can in principle prevent the marginal product of physical capital diminishing as the latter accumulates and long-run growth emerges, driven ultimately by the determinants of investment. The complete story is not as straightforward as all this implies; the contribution of the human and physical capital externality must be sufficient to prevent growth petering out, but at the same time these effects must not be excessive, otherwise a balanced growth path is not achieved. Rather restrictive theoretical conditions are needed to ensure that this is so, which may not hold true in the real world.

The model to be developed here draws upon a second broad strand of the literature in which the discovery of new goods and processes provides the engine of growth. R&D activity provides blueprints for these innovations and in turn requires the input from what Grossman and Helpman (1991) refer to as knowledge capital, by which they mean a body of scientific knowledge and techniques not specific to any one production process. Knowledge capital has two important characteristics that drive growth. First, it is a public good. It is non-rival (ie one firm's consumption of knowledge does not reduce the amount available to others) and it is non-excludable. Second, corresponding to the idea of learning by doing in Arrow (1962), knowledge capital increases with the cumulative R&D experience and therefore with the total stock of new goods in the economy. These two assumptions regarding knowledge capital can be used to explain the idea of a capital externality in the previous strand of growth theories. For the R&D strand of growth theory one question remains: what drives R&D investment? Schumpeter (1942) argued that it is driven by the expected profitability of the new product reflecting conditions in the relevant factor and product markets that determines the amount invested in R&D and with it the pace and direction of industrial innovation. Monopoly profits from the sale of new goods play a central role, another Schumpeterian idea, and this departure from perfect competition is a further feature that distinguishes the R&D-led view of economic growth. Translated into formal theory, an investment in a new blueprint will be undertaken if the expected net present value from the future stream of monopoly profits (taking into account the possibility of losing the monopoly position through an erosion of patent rights) equals the initial outlay on R&D. The resulting growth of the aggregate economy will depend on the interaction between firms producing distinctive goods and earning monopoly profits, the same or different firms engaging in R&D activity to invent new blueprints and consumers making savings and consumption decisions and supplying labour.

Globalisation of economies adds a further dimension to the theory of growth. Trade, borrowing and lending in world financial markets and the international mobility of factors of production can all contribute to growth on a world scale. Knowledge capital now becomes a public good on an international scale. Every country can benefit from the emergence of new scientific knowledge and techniques in any single country. Countries that are best equipped both to absorb these spillovers as well as generate new ideas themselves will outperform others.

It is necessary at this stage to distinguish between two products of R&D. The first we have discussed and is described as knowledge capital. To recap, this is not specific to any particular new product but is a public good consisting of a stock of general scientific and technical ideas which will prove useful to the next generation of innovators. The second product is a private good protected, albeit imperfectly, by patent laws and consists of a blueprint for a new good or industrial process. Firms will undertake R&D if the expected value of future monopoly profits exceeds the initial fixed costs.

By introducing migration into the picture, asymmetries between sending and host regions now become a central feature. Following Parente and Prescott (2000) we assume that both East and West have access to the same common technologies, but the ability of firms to avail themselves of the best technology differ in the two blocs, leading to different total factor productivities (TFPs). Estimates from Hall and Jones (1999) suggest that TFP levels are far lower in the new EU10 than the old EUI5. Since our focus is on long-run growth, the question arises as to whether large TFP differences will persist for long in the transitional economies. Estimates of TFP growth and labour productivity for Eastern and Western Germany in the 1990s from Burda and Hunt (2001) show that in the first half of the decade convergence was rapid, but in the second half it slowed down considerably, leaving Eastern labour productivity almost frozen at around two-thirds of that in the West. This suggests that in the transitional economies we may expect some rapid convergence at first, but that some significant East-West TFP productivity difference will persist for some considerable time. This is what we assume in the model we set out below. The remaining differences between East and West are the factor endowments of skilled and unskilled labour and initial capital which are both higher in the West.

The questions that remain are: given that there may well be a skill-bias if anything, what is the effect of immigration on receiving economies in the West such as the UK? Is the effect beneficial or adverse for growth? Does emigration have brain drain effects on sending economies? How differently would skilled (or unskilled) migration affect both receiving and sending economies? What factors would contribute to immigration/ emigration benefits/costs and economic growth driven by migration? Who are the winners and losers in both the sending and host regions?

4.1 The model

To answer these questions, we use a formal two-bloc endogenous growth model, based on the work of Currie et al. (1999), Chui et al. (2001)and Levine et al. (2010) which in turn builds on the work of Grossman and Helpman (1991). The model has two blocs, 'East' and 'West' with the following features in each bloc:

* There are three factors of production: skilled labour, unskilled labour and physical capital.

* In the absence of specialisation there are four sectors: a high-technology manufacturing sector producing an expanding variety of differentiated goods; a traditional traded sector producing a single traded homogeneous good (e.g., food, steel); a traditional non-traded sector produces another homogeneous good (e.g., construction, services) and an R&D innovative sector producing blueprints for new manufactured goods.

* As well as producing blueprints for new goods, R&D generates knowledge capital which is a public good within and between the two regions.

* The ranking of unskilled-skilled labour intensiveness is: traditional non-traded, traditional traded, manufacturing and R&D.

* The assumed market structures for outputs are competitive for the traditional and R&D sectors and monopolistic for manufacturing.

* Labour markets are assumed to clear and there are no free public services.

* In the basic model there is no labour mobility between East and West and this is subsequently compared with the case where migration between these blocs occurs.

* Migration of skilled workers from East to West reduces the size of the R&D and high-tech sectors in the East and increases it in the West. This is the sectoral reallocation effect of migration. Potentially with a sufficient exodus of this category of workers the East can be left with an economy specialising in low-tech activity.

* Since TFP is higher in the West there is an efficiency effect of East-West migration from workers with any skill level and capital being more effectively employed.

A solution to the model constitutes a general equilibrium involving the interaction of financial, product and labour markets. Using formal mathematical models such as this has a number of advantages over simple descriptive analysis. Often mathematical modelling confirms the initial intuition of more descriptive models and therefore provides an invaluable check on the coherence of the argument. Sometimes formal models provide surprises and further insights which either explain stylised facts or provide the basis for empirical investigation.

4.2 The immigration and emigration surpluses

The 'immigration surplus' according to Borjas (1995) is the increase in income of the indigenous population of the host country following immigration. The simplest model to assess the magnitude of the immigration surplus is as follows. Consider two economies, 'East' and 'West' where wages are perfectly flexible. Capital of both the physical and human variety is fixed and higher in the West. Both average and marginal output per worker is therefore higher in the West. In addition, following the recent literature on income differences between countries (10) we assume that total factor productivity is higher in the West, which creates a further outward shift in the Western marginal product of labour curve relative to the East.

Figure 6 shows what happens when migration from East to West occurs. The Eastern workforce (fully employed by assumption) falls from OA by an amount HA increasing the Western workforce by the same amount AB = HA. The area under the marginal product of labour (MPL) curves gives total output and the MPL (West) is higher than its Eastern counterpart MPL (East) because physical and human capital is higher in the West. Ignore for the moment human capital differences; then one unit of Eastern labour is equivalent to one unit of Western labour. Output then rises by an amount KDBA in the West and falls by an amount FJAH = ECBA in the East. The net increase in world output is therefore given by the region KDCE. The real wage falls in the West and rises in the East. If there are costs associated with migration and migrants maximise income net of costs, migration will cease before wages are equalised. Figure 6 shows the case of factor price equalisation where migration costs are zero and migration leads to equal wage rates. Migrants gain by an amount EDCJ; non-migrants in the East see total output fall by an amount FJG. The original Western population gains by the shaded amount KDE--the immigration surplus. This constitutes a total gain of [w.sub.w] [KD.sub.w] for Western capital and a loss of [w.sub.w] [KE.sub.w] for Western workers. Similarly the non-migrants in the East lose by an amount F GJ = EJC; wF [Gw.sub.E] is a gain for Eastern workers and wF [Jw.sub.E] is a loss for Eastern capitalists. Thus the losers are the original Western workers and Eastern capitalists; the winners are the migrants and Western capitalists.

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

This simple analysis does not differentiate between different types of labour but Borjas (1995) does go on to discuss the importance of the skill composition of immigrants. This is because the skill level of immigrants will determine the degree to which immigrants will be competing with natives for jobs and hence what impact they will have on their wages as well as establishing the relationship between these different skill groups and capital. Borjas (1995) suggests that as the complementarity of skilled labour and capital rises (Hamermesh, 1993), the immigration surplus can increase substantially if immigration consists mainly of skilled workers, although this will depend on the original mix of unskilled and skilled workers in the population. Therefore, the key issue to establish is whether immigrants and natives are substitutes or complements in the production process and, as a result, a relatively large literature has emerged on estimating the extent of the substitutability/complementarity between native and immigrant workers. (11)

The welfare gain (or loss) in the East, the Emigration Surplus and the World Surplus are assessed in a similar fashion. In the numerical results both are measured in utility terms as the percentage equivalent permanent consumption change relative to the balanced-growth steady state.

5. Simulation results

The properties of the general equilibrium solution obtained numerically and the calibration used are set out in detail in Levine et al. (2010). Here we provide a summary of the main findings.

The impact of migration in the host and in the receiving country is a result of counteracting forces. Some authors focus on the impact on wages and on labour market conditions in general, as in Borjas (1995). Others, such as Lundborg and Segerstrom (2000, 2002) look at the negative impact on the asset value of equity issued to finance R&D. In our general equilibrium framework the factors that contribute to the immigration/emigration surplus/deficit are: technological complementarities, terms of trade, change in asset prices, efficiency and sectoral reallocation effects. The static and dynamic effects often have a counteracting impact on economic welfare at home and abroad.

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

We consider the case where the East is relatively less endowed with skilled labour and total factor productivity (TFP) is lower in the East. With this particular pattern of skill-labour endowments and TFP in the two regions, we examine the effect of East-West migration with different skill compositions. Though all the effects are present in our simulations, by concentrating on migration with and without skill bias, keeping the other parameters fixed, we focus our analysis on the efficiency and the sectoral reallocation effects of international migration highlighted above.

5.1 Migration with no skill bias

Figure 7 shows the effect of a 10 per cent increase in the Western population from immigration with no skill bias in its composition. An increase in growth now occurs of 0.25 per cent which is almost entirely the result of a movement of workers from a country with a low TFP to one with a high TFP (the efficiency effect). All sectors in the West grow as they absorb the immigrant workers. The transfer of workers from a less to a more efficient R&D sector sees the Western share of new products rise and world growth rises. The consequent increase in demand for high-skill labour causes the relative skill-unskilled wage in both blocs to rise. There is a small rise in the Western R&D share and a small decrease in the corresponding share in the East. The world surplus is worked out as the equivalent percentage permanent change in consumption for a representative household consisting of skilled and unskilled workers, in the East and in the West, weighted according to post-migration proportions. There is a maximum world surplus of 9 per cent when migration reaches 10 per cent of the Western workforce. The details of the effect of these changes on welfare is summarised in panels (b) to (d) of figure 7. The world surplus breaks down into 1 per cent for Western skilled workers and about 0.5 per cent for native unskilled workers, giving an immigration surplus of around 0.85 per cent for the representative Western native household (figure 7b). For those remaining in the East, skilled workers gain by over 0.75 per cent, unskilled workers lose by -1.35 per cent, giving an emigration deficit for the representative Eastern nonmigrant of about -1.2 per cent (figure 7c). Finally, figure 7(d) shows that the representative migrant gains by a substantial 200 per cent. In summary, with our parameter values, the positive efficiency effect comes to dominate the potential static negative effects highlighted in the literature. Winners in order of the size of gain are migrants, overwhelmingly, followed by skilled workers in the West, unskilled workers in the West and skilled workers in the East. The only losers are unskilled workers in the East.

[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]

5.2 Migration with skill bias

We now show the impact in our model of a 10 per cent increase in the Western population from immigration with skill bias. A change in the composition of labour will have an impact on the way resources are allocated between the different sectors (sectoral reallocation effect) with a positive or negative impact on growth depending on the type of migration we are considering. In this framework with biased migration, the manufacturing and R&D sectors play an important role. Our next set of simulations in figure 8 looks at the effect of a 10 per cent increase in the Western population consisting of skilled workers. Now there are substantial reallocation effects in both blocs, towards high-tech activity in the West and the opposite in the East, arising from the changes in the proportions of skilled to unskilled workers. Indeed skilled migration of over 5 per cent of the Western workforce sees the R&D and high-tech sectors disappear altogether in the East.

Taken together with the efficiency effect of a movement from a less to a more efficient economy, growth now rises by over 0.5 per cent (figure 8a). The world surplus now rises to 11 per cent. The immigration surplus is almost 12 per cent for unskilled natives, -2.5 per cent for skilled natives averaging at almost 6 per cent (figure 8b). The emigration surplus is 17 per cent for skilled, -50 per cent for unskilled averaging at -10 per cent (figure 8c), but both skilled and unskilled migrants gain substantially again (figure 8d). Winners, again in order of gain, are migrants, unskilled workers in the West and skilled workers in the East. The losers are skilled workers in the West and unskilled workers in the East. So the distributional effect of skilled migration is to reduce inequality in the West, but do the opposite in the East.

5.3 Unskilled migration

We now look at the impact of a 10 per cent increase in the Western population consisting of unskilled migration. This seems to be the least relevant case according to our assessment of migration trends in section 2. Unskilled migration now has a negative impact on the world growth rate. (12) From figure 9, in comparison with skilled migration, we now have an opposite symmetrical sectoral reallocation effect owing to a change in the opposite direction of the proportion of skilled and unskilled workers in the West, but there is still a positive efficiency effect due to a movement of workers from a country with a low TFP to one with a high TFP. The world surplus is now a modest 0.4 per cent. The emigration surplus is 13 per cent for unskilled and -12 per cent for skilled while the immigration surplus is 5 per cent for skilled natives and -16 per cent for unskilled natives. Winners, once again in order of gain, are migrants, unskilled workers in the East and skilled workers in the West. The losers are unskilled workers in the West and skilled workers in the East. So now the distributional effect of unskilled migration is to increase inequality in the West, but do the opposite in the East.

5.4 Summary

The main result that emerges is that while unskilled migration decreases growth, migration of no-skill bias and skilled migration from a low to a high TFP region of the world increases growth, but in the absence of some distribution mechanism there are winners and losers, with remaining non-migrants in the latter category. The reason is that the East sees a reduction in its share of high-tech goods which involve a price mark-up over marginal cost, and the relative wage of the unskilled workers falls. Distributional effects are summarised in table 1.

One possible distribution mechanism is through remittances from migrants to their families remaining in the East. In Levine et al. (2010) we examine the effects of skilled migrants remitting a given percentage of their income ranging between 0 per cent and 50 per cent. Assuming that families are either entirely skilled or unskilled, these remittances will end up in the pockets of skilled households in the East. This group were winners in the absence of remittances so remittances in themselves do not mitigate the distributional effects of migration. However if we assume that intra-country distributional mechanisms exist, or that households are of a mixed skilled type, then we can focus on the representative household in both blocs. Then we can show that, at any remittance rate above around 35 per cent, migrants remain substantial winners, and the Eastern representative household begins to emerge as a winner. These welfare effects with remittances are summarised in table 2.

6. Conclusions and policy implications

In this section we summarise our results and attempt to formulate their policy implications. The East-West European migration that followed the 2004 and 2007 enlargements has created one of the most interesting migration-policy 'laboratories' in the world. In light of the main results that emerge in section 5 it is useful to summarise the nature of European migration flows since World War II. Periods of labour shortages such as in the 1960s induced active recruitment policies in some European countries. This openness was followed by a period of restrained migration. Since the fall of the Berlin wall, all CEECs now grant their citizens the right to migrate and from that time East-West migration started to gain particular attention. However some EU countries still maintained barriers to immigration.

Following recent enlargements, much East to West migration was anticipated. The UK did not initially impose any transitional restrictions on labour mobility and has clearly experienced an increase in the number of immigrants, particularly from the East. A well-known result shown in the migration literature, namely the prediction that benefits and losses from integration will be distributed unevenly among the individual factors of production, deserves special attention.

In a static economic analysis of labour markets, migration could decrease wages or the probability of being employed of workers who directly compete with immigrants. In our general equilibrium framework we look at the overall picture and we focus on the dynamic long-run aspect of migration. Section 5 shows that migration, in general, is beneficial to the receiving country and increases the world growth rate. The only exception is in the case of unskilled migration which can actually have a detrimental impact on the world growth rate. This possibility however seems to be unlikely from our examination of migration trends in section 2 which suggests that, if anything, the skill composition of immigrants is biased towards skilled workers. (13)

The debate which has focused on the role of institutions and governments as mechanisms that can regulate migration and its composition as well as mitigate the potential negative impact of immigration on the receiving countries, poses many controversial questions. Here we focus on an aspect that can capture them all: what are the dynamic consequences of migration in the host and in the sending economy? To summarise the main result of our theoretical framework, the dynamic aspect magnifies the role of high-skilled migration. Depending on the skill group, some workers in the East and West lose even if overall the receiving and the sending economies gain.

How does this translate in terms of policy recommendations? First of all, given the potential benefits of migration for the long-term growth rate, especially if migrants are high-skilled, an overly restrictive migration policy may constrain the overall growth in both regions. However our analysis gives strong support to policies supported by all mainstream parties in the UK to restrict immigration from non-EU countries to skilled workers. Second, whether the resulting immigration and emigration surpluses are significant or not, winners and losers remain and this suggests that compensating redistributive policies can mitigate the distributional effect of migration. We have examined one such mechanism--remittances--but clearly there is a role for policy that, as well as encouraging these flows, needs to ensure that overall economic gains are more equally distributed through measures using the tax system, welfare-to-work and the provision of public services. Finally, our analysis points to a greater need to integrate immigrants in order to reduce the gap between post-migration and premigration distribution of immigrants' occupations. While part of this gap can be explained in terms of the temporary nature of migration, particularly for A8 migrants, we believe there is scope for improving migrants' integration (i.e language effective training, advice from employment services etc). We think that migrants' skill depreciation due to limited integration can pose a severe limit to their economic contribution and requires special attention.

Clearly, our investigation of the macroeconomic impact of migration is not exhaustive. For example, we do not look at the impact of migration on unemployment. While short-run effects on unemployment in the host country are not excluded, Ortega (2000) offers a theoretical explanation of why immigration can be beneficial to the native worker, while Borjas' (2001) 'greasing the wheels' argument (14) provides another optimistic view of the labour market impact of migration in the host economy. The impact of migration can also be analysed from a different perspective. For example, an important question concerns the role that migrants can have in mitigating the fiscal burden associated with the phenomenon of an aging population. A strand of research, using a general equilibrium overlapping generations framework, looks at the net fiscal impact of migration. The answer to this is in part related to the skill composition of the migrant (Ortega, 2005, Cohen and Razin, 2009, and Cohen et al., 2009).

Concerns over skilled migration have been raised by the literature on the 'brain drain' in the source economies. We have seen from a theoretical perspective that, as high-skilled migrants move to the country with a higher TFP, world growth increases, but results in a decrease in the size of the 'modern' manufacturing and R&D sectors in the sending economy. Although not formalised in our framework, migration can increase the overall level of human capital in the source economy by increasing investment in human capital (Beine et al., 2008). Remittances, which in our model have only the function of a redistributive device, can provide important benefits by increasing human and physical capital investment. Clearly, different policy recommendations in the sending economy are dependant on whether it perceives either a brain drain or brain gain.

doi: 10.1177/0027950110380321

REFERENCES

Arrow, K.J. (1962), 'The economic implications of learning by doing', Review of Economic Studies, 29, 3, pp. 155-73.

Barrell, R., FitzGerald, J. and Riley, R. (2007), 'EU enlargement and migration: assessing the macroeconomic impact', NIESR Discussion Paper 292.

Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1992), 'Regional growth and migration: a Japan-United States comparison', Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 6, pp. 312-46.

--(1995), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill.

Beine, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2001), 'Brain drain and economic growth: theory and evidence', Journal of Development Economics, 64(I), pp. 275-89.

--(2008), 'Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: winners and losers', Economic Journal, 118(528), pp. 631-52.

Borjas, G. (1995), 'The economic benefits from immigration', Journal of Economic literature, 9(2), pp. 3-22.

--(1999), 'The economic analysis of immigration', in Ashenfelter, O.C. and Card, D. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, Amsterdam, North-Holland, pp. 1697-760.

--(2001), 'Does immigration grease the wheels of the labor market?' Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 69-133.

Buch, C.M. and Toubal, F. (2009), 'Openness and growth: the long shadow of the Berlin Wall', Journal of Macroeconomics, 31, pp. 409-22.

Burda, M. and Hunt, J. (2001), 'From reunification to economic integration: productivity and the labour market in Eastern Germany', Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 1-92.

Card, D. (2005), 'Is the new immigration really so bad?', Economic Journal, 115, 507, pp. 300-23.

Chui, M., Levine, P. and Pearlman, J. (2001), 'Winners and losers in a North-South model of growth, innovation and product cycles', Journal of Development Economics, 65, pp. 333-65.

Cohen, A. and Razin, A. (2009), 'Skill composition of migration and the generosity of the welfare state: free vs. policy-controlled migration', mimeo 641, Tel-Aviv University.

Cohen, A., Razin, A., and Sadka, E. (2009), 'The skill composition of migrants and the generosity of the welfare state', CEPR Discussion Paper Series 7185, February.

Currie, D., Levine, P., Pearlman, J. and Chui, M. (1999), 'Phases of imitation and innovation in a North-South endogenous growth model', Oxford Economic Papers, 51 (1), pp. 60-88.

Drinkwater, S. and Clark, K. (2008), 'The labour-market performance of recent migrants', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(3), pp. 495-516.

Drinkwater, S., Levine, P., Lotti, E. and Pearlman, J. (2003), 'The economic impact of migration: a survey', International Journal for Economic Development, 5, 2.

--(2007), 'The immigration surplus revisited in a general equilibrium model with endogenous growth', Journal of Regional Science, 47(3), pp. 569-601.

Dustmann, C., Fabbri, F. and Preston, I. (2005), 'The impact of immigration on the British labour market', Economic Journal 115(507), F324-F341.

Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press.

Hall, R. and Jones, C.I. (1999), 'Why some countries produce so much more output per worker than others', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, pp. 82-116.

Hamermesh, D. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton, Princeton University Press.

Hanson, G.H. (2008), 'The economic consequences of the international migration of labor', NBER Working Paper 14490, November.

Kahanec, M. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2008), 'Migration in an enlarged EU: a challenging solution?', IZA Discussion Paper No. 3913, December.

Kyrdar, M.G. and Saracoulu, D.S. (2008), 'Migration and regional convergence: an empirical investigation for Turkey', Papers in Regional Science, 87(4), pp. 545-566.

Levine, P., Lotti, E., Pearlman, J. and Pierse, R. (2010), 'Growth and welfare effects of world migration', Scottish Journal Of Political Economy (forthcoming).

Lundborg, P. and Segerstrom, P. S. (2000), 'International migration and growth in developed countries: a theoretical analysis', Economica, 67, pp. 579-604.

--(2002), 'The growth and welfare effects of international mass migration ', Journal of International Economics, 56, pp. 177-204.

Manacorda, M., Manning, A. and Wadsworth, J. (2007), 'The impact of immigration on the structure of male wages: theory and evidence from Britain', CEP Discussion Paper No. 754.

Marchiori, L., Shen, I. and Docquier, F. (2009), 'Brain drain in globalization: a GE analysis from the sending countries' perspective', prepared for a Conference at the World Bank.

Maza, A. (2006), 'Migrations and regional convergence: the case of Spain', Jahrbuch fur Regional-wissenschaft, 26, pp. 191-202.

OECD (2009), International Migration Outlook, Paris, OECD.

Ortega, F. (2005), 'Immigration quotas and skill upgrading', Journal of Public Economics, 89, pp. 1841-63.

Ortega, J. (2000), 'Pareto-improving immigration in an economy with equilibrium unemployment', The Economic Journal, 110(460), pp. 92-112.

Parente, S.L. and Prescott, E.C. (2000), Barriers to Riches, Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press.

Perssons, J. (1997), 'Convergence across the Swedish counties', European Economic Review, 41, pp. 1835-52.

Rodrick, D. (2004), 'How to make the trade regime work for development', mimeo, Harvard University.

Schumpeter, J.A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York, Harper.

Toya, H., Hosono, K. and Makino, T. (2004), 'Human capital, migration, and regional income convergence in the Philippines', Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University (Tokyo) Discussion Paper Series, No. 18.

Wadsworth, J. (2010), 'The UK labour market and immigration', National Institute Economic Review, 213, July.

Walmsley, T.L. and Winters, L.A. (2005), 'Relaxing the restrictions on the temporary movement of natural persons: a simulation analysis', Journal of Economic Integration, 20(4), pp. 688-726.

Walmsley, T.L, Winters, L.A. and Ahmed, S.A. (2009), 'Measuring the impact of the movement of labor using a model of bilateral migration flows', paper prepared for a Conference at the World Bank.

Winters, L.A. (2001), 'Assessing the efficiency gain from further liberalization: a comment', in Sauve, P. and Subramanian, A. (eds), Efficiency, Equity and Legitimacy: The Multilateral Trading System and the Millennium, Chicago, Chicago University Press. pp. 106-13.

World Bank (2006), Global Economic Prospects 2006 : Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration, Washington, DC, The World Bank.

Zaiceva, A. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2008), 'Scale, diversity, and determinants of labour migration in Europe', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(3), pp. 427-51.

NOTES

(1) See Wadsworth (2010).

(2) See Barrell et al. (2007) for an earlier analysis of the impact of EU enlargement on various macroeconomic variables in both sending and receiving countries

(3) See Drinkwater and Clark (2008) for more details and issues arising from the inadequacy of migration data.

(4) See OECD (2009).

(5) See Wadsworth (2010).

(6) See Dustmann et al. (2005).

(7) Figures 2 and 3 use pre-migration occupations.

(8) See Wadsworth (2010).

(9) See Perssons (1997), Toya et al. (2004), Maza (2006), Kyrdar and Saracoulu (2008) and Buch and Toubal (2009).

(10) See, for example, Parente and Prescott (2000).

(11) See Borjas (1999) for a summary of early studies.

(12) In Drinkwater et al. (2007) we also investigate the impact of migration on the immigration surplus for different degrees of complementarities and we show that when skilled labour and capital are complements changes in asset prices can have a signicant effect and that the complementarity worsens the impact of unskilled migration.

(13) This is supported by the analysis in Wadsworth (2010).

(14) Immigration injects in the economy a group of highly mobile self-selected individuals, ready to move to exploit economic opportunities in different areas.

Young-Bae Kim,* Paul Levine* and Emanuela Lotti**

* University of Surrey. ** University of Southampton and University of Surrey. E-mail: [email protected]. The authors would like to thank Stephen Drinkwater for very helpful comments.
Table 1. Winners and losers from migration

Migration            No bias   Skilled    Unskilled
group                          bias       bias

Migrant              Winners   Winners    Winners
Western Skilled      Winners   Losers     Winners
Western Unskilled    Winners   Winners    Losers
Eastern Skilled      Winners   Winners    Losers
Eastern Unskilled    Losers    Losers     Winners

Table 2. Growth, immigration surplus (IS), emigration
surplus (ES) of representative households

Type of migration   Growth       IS (%)   ES (%)
                    effect (%)

Unbiased             0.3          0.85    -1.2
Skilled              0.5          5.5     -8.0
Skilled with 50%
  remittances        0.5          5.5      7
Unskilled           -0.35        -0.05    -6
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有