Monetary policy under labour.
Besley, Timothy ; Sheedy, Kevin
This paper analyses Labour's record on monetary policy and the
record of the MPC which it created. The paper begins by discussing the
conceptual framework and institutions behind inflation targeting as it
operates in the UK. We then discuss the successes that it enjoyed up to
2007 and debate the lessons that are being learned as a consequence of
the experience since then. We then raise some of the formidable
challenges that UK monetary policy must now face up to including
maintaining the credibility of the inflation targeting regime in the
face of greater interdependence between monetary and fiscal policy, and
between monetary policy and support to the banking system and financial
markets.
Keywords: Monetary policy; inflation targeting; UK macroeconomic
policy
Introduction
By 2006, monetary policy in the UK was approaching its 'end of
history' moment. The arrangements that had evolved to target
inflation after 1992, culminating in Bank of England independence and
the creation of the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) in 1997, had not
only slain the inflationary dragon but appeared to have delivered
wholesale macroeconomic stability. Gordon Brown's claim to have
found the ingredients to end boom and bust seemed credible and central
bank independence as a means of securing this stood as a proud monument
to Labour's economic achievements.
But the more recent global economic chaos has tarnished this record
and is now leading to global debates about the proper conduct of
monetary policy, in particular the right mandate to give to central
banks and the framework that is needed to deliver it. Thus, despite the
achievements, a legacy of monetary policy under Labour will be in the
form of some unanswered questions.
In this paper, we will go through Labour's record (and the
record of the MPC). We will discuss the successes that it enjoyed tip to
2007 and debate the lessons that are being learned as a consequence of
the experience since then. The first ten years of Labour saw a
remarkable period of stability whether benchmarked against the UK's
historical record or against global experience. This was a period that
was dubbed the great moderation and much has been written about its
causes--good luck, good policy, and structural change being the three
main candidates. Throughout this period, inflation remained within 1 per
cent of the Government's target and interest rates moved in small
steps (typically 25 basis points).
Since late 2008, the story has been quite different. Following the
failure of Lehman Brothers, a period of global economic turmoil ensued
with the UK experiencing a 6 per cent fall in GDP. This led to a
dramatic loosening in monetary policy and, from March 2009, a series of
unconventional policy measures frequently referred to as
'quantitative easing'. The cornerstone of this has been
purchases of almost 200 [pounds sterling] billion of government debt via
the creation of central bank reserves.
We write this paper at a point, therefore, when some of the
conventional wisdom on monetary policy is being debated again after a
significant period of consensus on its broad goals. Unlike fiscal
policy, Labour's record on monetary policy is not an election
issue. Indeed, all major political parties in the UK now accept the
broad notion that monetary policy is best conducted independently and
technocratically. Back in 1997 when the Bank of England was granted
independence, it was not greeted with universal acclaim though--it was
strongly opposed by the Conservatives (the policy was supported by the
Liberal Democrats, who had put forward a proposal to make the Bank
independent in their 1992 election manifesto). Conservative opposition
to Bank of England independence was finally reversed in 2000. However,
the recent financial crisis and subsequent recession have taken the
gloss off the current Government's claim to have provided an end to
boom and bust, for which independent monetary policy was often given
star billing.
In what follows, we will discuss the lessons from the past thirteen
years and the debates about how lessons can be learned for the future
conduct of policy and institutional change.
The policy framework
The story of monetary policy under Labour actually begins five
years earlier with the UK's exit from the ERM on Black Wednesday in
September 1992. The idea of using monetary policy to target the exchange
rate was roundly discredited and the subsequent focus moved towards
inflation targeting--focusing monetary policy on meeting a numerically
specified target for inflation. The then Governor of the Bank of
England, Robin Leigh-Pemberton, saw this as "an opportunity to
demolish the image of the United Kingdom as a second-rate
inflation-prone economy". (1)
We will first discuss the intellectual rationale for inflation
targeting and then discuss how it has been implemented in the UK.
Inflation targeting in theory
Inflation targeting was born out of an era of macroeconomic
instability and inflation volatility in developed economies in the 1970s
and early 1980s. (2) Some of this was put down to inflation bias--with
governments having incentives to create surprise inflation to gain a
temporary reduction in unemployment ahead of elections and to increase
seigniorage. Thus, the watchword of monetary policy increasingly became
credibility in the face of such incentives. One way to achieve this was
to have a clearly defined goal and a conservative central bank,
insulated from political influence, to implement it. (3)
To establish the credibility of an inflation target, the central
bank could be thought of as implementing a policy rule underpinned by a
systematic response of interest rates to inflation, one that satisfied
the Taylor principle. This enshrined the idea that monetary policy
should lean against the wind, raising interest rates by more than
one-for-one with inflation. This would increase real interest rates,
reducing total demand and thus inflationary pressure. This idea was
often formalised in macroeconomic models with a Taylor rule. By acting
in this way, the central bank could persuade agents that they should
rationally expect inflation at target in the future, as deviations from
target would eventually call forth sufficiently large changes in
interest rates to offset them. Small changes in policy could then steer
the economy by affecting expectations. Central bank credibility rested
on agents' beliefs that the bank was following the Taylor principle
and would raise and lower rates in accordance with it. This way the
inflation target would provide a nominal anchor for the economy.
However, unlike the Taylor rule, which laid down a specific
numerical response of interest rates to inflation, inflation targeting
was not a policy rule in this strict sense. On the one hand, there was a
specific numerical target for inflation. But as precise control of
inflation is not feasible, it is not possible for the public to observe
whether the rule is being followed just by looking at the central
bank's actions. Furthermore, inflation targeting gives the central
bank freedom to meet the goal of getting inflation to target in any way
it thinks best. So inflation targeting actually grants much discretion
to the central bank. In particular, there is no intermediate target such
as narrow money growth or exchange rates that it is obliged to meet.
Strategies with intermediate targets are closer to being rules. The idea
is that the central bank has more direct control over the intermediate
target, and can be judged accordingly, although experience suggests that
this is questionable in the case of targeting monetary aggregates.
Inflation targeting could be said to make the inflation forecast the
intermediate target, but the construction of this forecast itself
requires some subjective judgement so the forecast is not objective data
unlike other intermediate targets.
This is where the other features of inflation targeting, beyond the
numerical target, come to the fore. The' framework of independence
of the central bank, transparency of the central bank's
decision-making, and accountability to the public, are the means by
which discretion is constrained and inflation targeting moves closer to
being a policy rule that can have credibility with the public.
In this framework, central bank independence takes monetary policy
decisions out of the hands of elected politicians who would be tempted
to put other objectives before meeting the inflation target.
Transparency allows the public to judge whether the independent
policymakers are acting reasonably given the target that should be met
and the available data and analysis. Accountability compels the
policymakers to justify breaches of the target and persuade the public
that these do not constitute a de facto change in what is being
targeted.
This way of thinking solved the problem that had dogged fiat money
systems which lacked a credible way of pinning down nominal variables.
By delegating the task to central banks, one degree of uncertainty is
eliminated--the willingness of politicians to make tough decisions if
they arose at the wrong point in the electoral cycle.
The move towards inflation targeting with an independent central
bank was part of an emerging international trend. The system adopted in
the UK was thus part of an international shift in thinking about
macroeconomic policy management more generally. While nobody seriously
believed that stabilising inflation alone could stabilise the economy in
its entirety, a divine coincidence was frequently invoked to suggest
that even if policymakers did not care directly about output volatility,
targeting inflation would be the best way to achieve that end.
Just how narrowly central banks in general followed their inflation
targeting mandate has been a subject of debate. In their overview of
international practice, Blanchard et al. (2010) discuss this issue in
the following terms:
"In practice, the rhetoric exceeded the reality. Few central
banks, if any, cared only about inflation. Most of them mentioned
'flexible inflation targeting', the return to a stable target,
not right away, but over some horizon. Most of them allowed shifts in
headline inflation, such as those caused by rising oil prices, provided
inflation expectations remained well anchored. And many of them paid
attention to asset prices ... beyond their effects on inflation and
showed concern about external sustainability and the risks associated
with balance-sheet effects. But they did so with some unease, and often
with strong public denial."
While (as far as we are aware) they did not intend this description
to apply to the Bank of England, in particular, we will argue below that
this characterises very well how the inflation targeting approach has
been applied pragmatically in the UK since 1997. The Monetary Policy
Committee made frequent references to concerns beyond its narrow remit
including house prices, exchange rate movements, and more general
macroeconomic trends.
Inflation targeting in practice
Inflation targeting in the UK is often associated with
Labour's decision to grant the Bank of England independence in May
1997--one of the first announcements of the incoming Government. But
granting the Bank independence could also be seen as the culmination of
a series of reforms begun by the Conservatives, starting from their
first tentative experiment with inflation targeting in October 1992. A
number of key features of the UK's monetary policy strategy thus
predate the Labour Government. This section reviews the evolution of
inflation targeting, stressing the differences between the post-1997
Labour version and the earlier Conservative version. (4)
Beginning in 1992, the UK was one of the pioneers of inflation
targeting (with only New Zealand and Canada having begun earlier). With
this approach to monetary policy being novel, many of the features that
have subsequently become an accepted part of any inflation targeting
system had yet to develop. There was no off-the-peg tried-and-tested
inflation targeting regime to mimic, so many elements of the strategy
were added piecemeal along the way.
The most basic requirement of inflation targeting is of course a
numerical target for inflation. The Conservative Government announced a
target range for RPIX (the retail price index excluding mortgage
interest payments) inflation of between 1 per cent and 4 per cent in
October 1992, with the aim of bringing inflation down below the midpoint
of the range (2.5 per cent) by the end of the Parliament. This
particular inflation target was not intended to be perpetual--subsequent
Parliaments could renew or change it. By 1995, the Government was
describing its inflation target as a point target of 2.5 per cent with
no surrounding range.
Importantly, and in contrast to the route taken by the other
pioneers of inflation targeting, the Chancellor of the Exchequer
retained the power to set interest rates. The Governor of the Bank of
England was to act as the Chancellor's adviser on the best course
for interest rates, and regular monthly meetings between the two were
arranged to this end. In addition to the advice offered by the Governor,
the Chancellor received counsel from a panel of six 'wise
men', a precursor of the external members of the Monetary Policy
Committee. Importantly, the Bank of England's new role allowed for
it to speak out publicly on monetary policy strategy. Disagreements
between the Governor and the Chancellor were not unknown at the time.
In 1993, the Inflation Report made its debut. This was a document
setting out the Bank's projections for inflation tinder the
currently prevailing monetary policy stance. The report was an extensive
discussion of the factors currently relevant for inflation and the risks
and uncertainties clouding the forecast. This was an important exercise
in increasing the transparency of monetary policy. The report should
help independent observers come to a judgement about whether the current
stance of monetary policy was reasonable given the stated inflation
target. The forecasts in the report could be scrutinised and judged in
relation to those produced by independent forecasters, with the report
as a whole providing a focal point for the debate.
Another big step towards greater transparency was taken in 1994
with the publication of the minutes of the meeting between the
Chancellor and the Governor. The minutes were published with a six-week
lag. These provided a means for the Governor to put the Bank's view
on record, and also forced the Chancellor to offer arguments supporting
his chosen decision that could be scrutinised by the public.
Thus some of the features of inflation targeting now taken for
granted were already in place by 1997. However, one important ingredient
was missing. Under the Conservatives' version of inflation
targeting, the Bank of England's role was merely that of a mentor
to the Chancellor, one that could publicly offer an assessment of the
likely consequences for inflation of the Chancellor's actions. The
Bank was the 'conscience' of inflation targeting, but had no
formal power. Labour's key reform was to grant the Bank
independence. Although the Chancellor continued to set the goals of
monetary policy, including the precise inflation target, the Bank had
operational independence to try to meet this target in the way it
thought best. In the language of the literature, the Bank had instrument
independence, but not goal independence. (5) At the time the new
arrangements were announced, the Chancellor did not make any significant
change to the goal. The inflation target continued to be 2.5 per cent.
The job of setting interest rates was now delegated to an
independent body, the Monetary Policy Committee, made up of the
Governor, four senior officials of the Bank, and four external members.
(6) But little in the way of detail was in place. Looking back in 2007
on these events, the current Governor of the Bank recalls how much hard
work needed to be done to put the detailed procedures together:
"(T)he new arrangements were designed and put in place in not
much more than three weeks. They included the arrangements for briefing
the Committee, the pre-MPC meetings, the format of the decision-making
meetings of the MPC, practical matters such as the ordering of a sound
system so that, in a break with tradition, it was actually possible to
boar what was said in the Bank's older meeting rooms, and
rehearsals of the meetings and voting procedures with staff members
playing the roles of the MPC members. So short was the time available
that some of the dress rehearsals came after the first night of other
parts of the policy process. Such was the adrenaline flow that at one
rehearsal a row broke out about how a decision would be reached if the
Committee split three-ways in equal numbers ... But all was resolved and
the show opened on Wednesday 4 June. At that first meeting the MPC
raised interest rates by 25 basis points, as it did at its two
subsequent meetings." (King, 2007)
After a brief period of establishing norms and procedures, the
arrangements have now become firmly cemented and have changed little
since the inception of the MPC. The committee meets to be briefed by
Bank of England staff before each decision. Its policy meeting begins on
a Wednesday afternoon and concludes on a Thursday morning with a policy
decision announced at noon. Only twice has practice diverged from this
with an emergency meeting following the events of September 1 I, 2001
and an unscheduled meeting so that the Bank of England could join in
coordinated cuts in interest rates with other leading central banks in
October 2008 in the teeth of the financial crisis. Extra meetings are
scheduled to prepare the forecast and the inflation report on a
quarterly basis.
The membership of the committee from the start has included four
independent members appointed by the Chancellor. The Treasury is present
at MPC meetings only to observe the decisions. The decisions of the
committee are reported in monthly minutes, which also report
individuals' votes. These minutes are not verbatim accounts--they
are attempts to summarise the broad thrust of the discussion, the key
points of agreement and disagreement and their implications for the
policy outlook. From October 1998 the publication delay for the minutes
was shortened from six to two weeks.
It was quickly established that the MPC would air its disagreements
openly and dissent has been common the Governor has voted in a minority
on three occasions to date. Members of the MPC are free to express their
views in public. They appear regularly before the House of Commons
Treasury Select Committee, and occasionally this has brought out further
differences of views on the committee. Members of the committee also
regularly make speeches and give newspaper interviews. The extensive
network of agencies run by the Bank of England affords the MPC regular
opportunities to travel around the UK and to meet with business and
other audiences.
Although appointed by the Chancellor, the external members served
three-year terms and acted independently once in post. Some did argue
that their independence might be jeopardised by being able to seek
reappointment, which would require the Chancellor's consent. Many
members served only one term though. (7) Since 2009, there has been open
advertising of vacancies.
Central bank independence in the UK has created a more prominent
role for economists at the heart of the policy process for the first
time. It has also created a division of labour in which the Treasury has
stayed out of monetary policy. And membership of the committee has been
dominated by economists. This has included some academics, but also
business and city economists. The membership from among the bank staff
is also geared heavily towards technical and policy expertise.
Given the effective transfer of power from Chancellor to MPC, some
extra accountability mechanisms were thought appropriate. If inflation
fell outside a new 1 per cent corridor either side of the central target
then the Governor was obliged to write an open letter to the Chancellor
spelling out why this had happened and what steps were being taken to
rectify it. In addition, the MPC was made formally accountable to
Parliament through the Treasury Select Committee, which also scrutinised
new appointments.
The purpose of the new corridor around the inflation target was
two-fold. First, to allow some flexibility in not having to meet the
target in the short term. Given the long and variable lags in
controlling inflation, such precise stabilisation of inflation would be
neither possible nor desirable--to attempt it would likely destabilise
the real economy. It thus had to be made clear that the MPC was not
expected to achieve the impossible, and that there should be no stain on
its reputation if inflation was not exactly at 2.5 per cent. Second, the
letters written at the thresholds strengthened accountability; there was
a specific point where the drift of inflation away from target had to be
justified explicitly. The idea was not that the letters should be seen
as the MPC's justification of its failure to meet the target, but
more as a description of the special factors (for example, supply
shocks) that made it difficult or unwise to seek too rapid a return of
inflation to target.
One consequence of gaining independence was a refocusing of the
Bank of England. The Monetary Analysis side of the bank recruited and
retained a number of economists focused on supporting the MPC's
monthly decisions. Throughout the inflation targeting period, the Bank
has been heavily influenced by the (by now) standard New Keynesian
framework where constant inflation was the optimal policy at a zero
output gap. This led to the development of a variety of DSGE models
which could be used as a guide to policy. The Bank of England has never
gone the whole way on the latter. But it did refashion its model in this
direction with the introduction of the Bank of England Quarterly Model
(BEQM) in 2003. However, aware of the fact that stylised versions of
such models do a poor job at capturing many features of the data, its
core model was supplemented with a variety of non-core nonstructural
equations.
As part of the institutional reform, the Labour Government set tip
a financial regulator which pulled together a variety of previously
separate bodies. The task of banking supervision was taken away from the
Bank of England. The Bank, however; retained its responsibility for
financial stability with a wing set tip and a Deputy Governor to oversee
it. The Bank has since published its Financial Stability Report to
provide commentary on these issues. However, crucially, the Bank has had
few (if any) powers to regulate the financial system. Part of the
arrangements included a tripartite committee comprising the Chancellor,
the head of the FSA and the Governor of the Bank of England to oversee
events of a systemic nature.
Where the MPC has generally remained more reserved has been on
questions of fiscal policy. It takes the Government's fiscal
projections and policies as given in reaching its policy judgements and
has not chosen to comment publicly on these, although the Governor has
occasionally ruffled feathers. Equally, the Treasury has refrained
throughout the period since 1997 from commenting on the Bank's
policy decisions in public. Thus, the separation of monetary and fiscal
policy has remained a core element of the (informal) institutional
arrangements and the subsequent experience.
Labour cannot take the credit for introducing inflation targeting.
However, the reforms in 1997 made a significant contribution towards
strengthening the framework and institutionalising a transparent and
accountable system of policymaking. The fact that there is now broad
political consensus on the need to maintain an independent monetary
policy process is perhaps the greatest indication of the potency of
these reforms.
The experience
We divide our discussion of the experience into two parts. First,
we begin by discussing the first ten years of the experience where the
economy was stable. We then look at the post-2007 period and the
adoption of unconventional policy measures by the Bank.
It should also be added that in addition to the independence of the
Bank of England and the actions of the MPC, the Labour Government took
two other crucial monetary policy decisions in 1997 and 2003. These were
its assessment of the so-called 'Five Economic Tests' for
joining European Monetary Union. While the Government's policy was
that it favoured membership in principle, it argued that there needed to
be evidence of sufficient convergence and flexibility as a practical
matter before joining could be contemplated. The Treasury published
assessments of the Five Economic Tests in October 1997 and June 2003. In
both cases it was concluded that further progress was needed before the
Government could recommend joining. We will not rehearse the well-known
arguments in favour of and against joining a monetary union, but will
instead assess the record of the independent monetary policy the Labour
Government chose to retain.
The first ten years
Before the 1990s the UK could hardly be held up as a paragon of
macroeconomic management. In this context, the period 1997-2007 was a
period of remarkable stability in inflation and output growth compared
with the UK's past history. Indeed the UK went from being one of
the most volatile major economies to being one of the most stable.
Tables 1 and 2 document the experience for different decades (table I)
and different governments (table 2). Inflation has been both lower and
more stable tinder Labour than in any period since the 1950s and 1960s.
This time has also been a period of stability in both inflation and
growth across much of the world, often dubbed the 'great
moderation'. While this ten-year period was one of macroeconomic
stability, the global environment was not always benign. Even before
2007, there were financial crises and large swings in asset prices
around the world. House prices and commodity prices were also volatile.
Furthermore, this period was also punctuated by wars and terrorism. This
section briefly discusses how the MPC navigated these choppy waters. (8)
The MPC met for the first time in June 1997, and its first decision
was to increase interest rates by 0.25 per cent, taking Bank Rate to 6.5
per cent. A further two 0.25 per cent rises followed in the next two
meetings. At the time, inflation was close to the target, but the
committee thought that domestic demand pressures called for tighter
monetary policy to ensure that inflation was forecast to be at target in
two years time. (See figure 1 for growth rates of GDE Figure 2 shows
subsequent estimates of the output gap, with figure 9 providing
estimates based on data available at the time.) (In the other hand, the
appreciation of sterling was offsetting these risks to some extent. By
June 1998, there had been two further 0.25 per cent rises in Bank Rate
taking it to 7.5 per cent, tile highest it has so far reached since
independence (figure 3). This was against a background of rising wage
growth and headline inflation (figure 5), leading to some fears about
second-round effects on wages.
By October 1998, interest rates were on a falling trajectory. The
Asian financial crisis, the Russian default, and the collapse of Long
Term Capital Management led to a deterioration in world economic
activity that was expected to affect Britain. Furthermore, inflation was
already falling. In light of this, a series of 0.25 per cent interest
rate cuts followed, and the pace was quickened in February 1999 with a
0.5 per cent cut. Interest rates bottomed out at 5.0 per cent in June
1999 as forward-looking indicators showed improvement.
Bank Rate was not to stay down for long, though, with a new
tightening cycle following shortly afterwards. Initially, the risks were
finely balanced, so tile first increase had the flavour of a preemptive
response to signals that the UK and tile world economy were in better
condition than previously thought. Further rises followed, taking Bank
Rate to 6.0 per cent by February 2000. At the time, inflation was
subdued, but the strength of domestic demand meant that the Bank's
forecasts were for inflation to rise over the next two years. Large
rises in house prices were also apparent at the time (figure 8). The MPC
erred on the side of caution and continued to raise rates.
Two debates that were an ongoing feature of this time period were
whether there had been a permanent favourable shift in the UK's
terms of trade, and whether there had been a rise in the trend rate of
productivity growth. Both of these debates made judgements about
long-term inflationary pressures harder to reach. Tile task of
estimating the output gap became more difficult, and it was hard to know
how much of the appreciation of sterling was temporary. Figure 10 shows
the relative occurrence of words in the Inflation Report relating to
"domestic supply factors" relative to "domestic demand
factors" increased during the early years of the MPC.
During 2000, stock markets began to fall and the US economy
weakened, though it was not yet clear whether a 'soft landing'
would be achieved. At this time of uncertainty, the MPC chose to keep
Bank Rate stable. As the falls in asset prices continued into 2001 and
the outlook for the US and world economy deteriorated, the MPC began to
ease policy. A succession of interest rate cuts followed, with Bank Rate
falling to 5.0 per cent by the time of tile MPC's regular meeting
in September 2001. Tile next week brought the 9/1l terrorist attacks,
and the consequent fears of a collapse in confidence. A special meeting
of the MPC was convened on 18 September to consider the risks to tile UK
economy. While there was debate about whether a large cut was needed, in
the end tile committee considered that a large movement of interest
rates might itself be destabilising at such a time. A more modest
reduction of 25 basis points was chosen.
Although UK economic growth proved fairly resilient over this
period, at the time there were worries that the recession in the US and
the fallout from 9/l1 would lead to a slowdown. Given the balance of
risks, further Bank Rate reductions followed, including a 0.5 per cent
cut in November 2001. By December, interest rates had reached a trough
of 4 per cent, where they were to remain for the whole of 2002.
In the middle of 2002 there was a noticeable dip in inflation
associated with falls in seasonal food prices and the price of oil
(figure 6). Inflation almost fell below 1.5 per cent, which would have
triggered the first letter from tile Governor to the Chancellor.
However, the MPC perceived that these factors supporting low inflation
would only be temporary, so decided not to cut rates. But by February
2003, further impetus for rate cuts was provided by weakness in the
world economy in the light of geopolitical uncertainty from the likely
war in Iraq. Stock markets were also continuing to fall markedly around
the world. But RPIX inflation, however, was now robust. Nonetheless, the
MPC chose to reduce Bank Rate to 3.75 per cent, and followed this with a
further 0.25 per cent cut in July.
The negative trends of early 2003 had gone into reverse by the end
of tile year, with stronger growth in tile US and a strong rebound in
stock markets. Furthermore, house price inflation continued to help push
RPIX inflation above target, and was also believed by some to be
contributing to the strength of consumption growth. Tile MPC changed
course, and started raising rates in November. Inflationary pressure
remained strong though, partly owing to the beginning of a trend that
was to cause increasing concern over the coming years: the rise in
commodity prices. This was first felt in oil prices, which staged a
significant rise in the second half of 2004. By August 2004, the MPC had
raised Bank Rate to 4.75 per cent.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
One notable event of this time was the Chancellor's decision
to change the inflation target in December 2003. The use of RPIX
inflation was abandoned and the new CPI (Consumer Price Index) was
adopted. The CPI is comparable in construction to the Euro Area's
Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP), leading some to speculate
whether this move was a step toward joining the euro. However, the real
rationale for this shift was less clear since the Treasury had ruled in
June 2003 that the Five Economic Tests for euro membership had not yet
been met. The arguments offered in support of the change were largely
technical: that CPI better accounted for consumers' substitution
away from goods experiencing large price rises, and that the way it was
constructed was more in accord with the national accounts. Furthermore,
it could also facilitate international comparisons. Because of
differences in the construction of the RPIX and CPI indices, the
inflation target was simultaneously changed from 2.5 per cent to 2.0 per
cent (maintaining the l per cent band either side beyond which an open
letter would be triggered).
Putting aside the technical merits of CPI, most public debate at
the time of the changeover centred around the different composition of
tile indices. The RPI (and RPIX) includes various measures of housing
costs (including a measure of housing depreciation, which is affected by
house prices) which are excluded from the CPI (which does though include
an index of rents). The CPI also excluded council tax, which is part of
RPIX. These exclusions sometimes open up a large difference between CPI
and RPIX inflation (see figure 6). And in 2003, with double-digit rises
in house prices and double-digit increases in council tax, the gap
between RPIX and CPI was especially large. While part of the gap (around
0.5 per cent) can be explained as a result of the technical details of
the two indices and is expected to be a permanent component of the
difference, (9) for much of 2003 RPIX inflation was around l-l.5 per
cent higher than CPI inflation.
Although the inflation target was adjusted downwards to reflect the
likely permanent difference between RPIX and CPI, the special factors at
the time made the transition particularly challenging. With RPIX
inflation much more than 0.5 per cent higher than CPI inflation, it
might appear to the public that the inflation target was being relaxed.
One of the Bank's Deputy Governors famously remarked in commenting
on this change that, "when defending a free kick from David
Beckham, you don't expect somebody to move the goalposts".
Both of the special factors accounting for the difference between RPIX
and CPI had attracted much media attention that year. There was clearly
a risk of jeopardising public confidence in the inflation target. The
benefits of the changeover on the other hand seemed modest compared with
the risks.
These risks were magnified by the Chancellor's decision to
retain the use of RPI inflation for all other official calculations of
inflation, except the Bank's inflation target. Social security
benefits are indexed to RPI. Tax bands are revised annually in line with
RPI, as are tax credits. Even inflation-protected gilts are still
indexed to RPI. The case of index-linked gilts is especially surprising
given that one advantage of such assets is in providing a market-based
measure of inflation expectations {albeit an imperfect one given
liquidity premia). Such information is potentially very useful to the
MPC in addition to surveys of inflation expectations, but is made less
helpful when the expectations are of a different inflation rate from the
one it is targeting. If CPI inflation always moved in line with RPI
inflation then these issues would be a minor nuisance. Experience shows
that RPI inflation and CPI inflation do not always move together and
there is no reason to suppose that such episodes will not recur in the
future.
The continuing official use of RPI in the tax and social-security
system has also made this index a focal point for both private- and
public-sector wage negotiations. Most wage settlements that include an
indexation provision make use of RPI inflation, not the CPI. So RPI
remains the public's benchmark for inflation in many situations.
The media continue to report the RPI statistics alongside CPI. The very
existence of two parallel but sometimes divergent official inflation
statistics has led some in the media to call into question (rightly or
wrongly) the fairness of the CPI inflation rate and, in particular, make
the argument that it is biased against certain groups in society. By
making the calculation of inflation a contentious issue, the continued
existence of the CPI and the RPI creates a public-relations problem for
inflation targeting, as well as making the job of the MPC more
difficult.
The environment facing the MPC in 2005 contained both upside and
downside risks to inflation. On the one hand, oil prices were rising
significantly but, on the other, rises in house prices had faded and
consumption growth had begun to slow. Developments in world financial
markets were also proving difficult to interpret. The low level of
long-term real interest rates was frequently remarked on, though
analyses diverged about the reasons ('global savings glut'
versus 'excess liquidity', for example) and the consequent
implications for monetary policy. The MPC kept Bank Rate constant at
4.75 per cent for much of the year, but in a finely balanced decision,
resolved on a 0.25 per cent cut in August 2005.
By 2006, long-term real interest rates were continuing to fall,
share prices were rising, and UK house prices had returned to
significant growth. This was against a backdrop of accelerating growth
in the broad money supply and rises in energy prices. Though CPI
inflation had remained stable and close to target for the first half of
the year, there were clearly upside risks building up. With continued
firm economic growth and tentative signs of a rise in inflation
expectations as indicated by the spread between conventional and
index-linked gilts (figure 7), the MPC took action, raising Bank Rate by
0.25 per cent in August and November 2006. By December, CPI inflation
had reached 3.0 per cent, the maximum before a letter was triggered. One
debate among the MPC members was whether this rise in inflation was
simply a temporary blip, or whether it was the first manifestation of
greater underlying inflationary pressure. On the one hand, there was
rapid growth in money and credit, output growth was close to estimates
of trend, and survey measures of inflation expectations were beginning
to rise (figure 7). On the other hand, wage growth had not picked up
significantly. As can be seen in figure 10, discussions of the extent of
spare capacity were increasingly prominent in the Inflation Report.
Given the balance of risks, the MPC decided upon another 0.25 per cent
rate rise in January 2007, taking Bank Rate to 5.25 per cent.
The next year brought the MPC its most difficult challenge thus
far. By 2007, conditions in the US housing market were deteriorating
rapidly and this was expected to exert a drag on US growth. However,
global economic activity remained robust and there were significant
rises in commodity and food prices during the year. In the UK, money and
credit growth were still worryingly high, along with producer price
inflation. Balancing this, growth in wages and employment was still
weak. After falling back slightly in the first few months of the year,
CPI inflation rose again and breached the 3 per cent threshold in March.
When these data were released in April, they triggered the first
open letter from the Governor to the Chancellor. In his letter, the
Governor stressed the special circumstances that had led to inflation
rising above 3 per cent. These were the abnormal rises in food and
energy prices, which were expected to be reversed. However, these
factors did not account for all of the build-up in inflation; strong
domestic demand and rises in firms' markups had also contributed.
The Governor stressed that the MPC had already taken action through a
series of rate rises to head off this rise in inflation being factored
into future expectations. Tile Bank's central projection showed
that inflation was forecast to return to target given tile policy
tightening, and that given the "long lags" in controlling
inflation it made sense for the MPC to "look through the short-term
volatility in inflation" and set interest rates "to keep
inflation on track to meet the 2 per cent target in the medium
term". At its May meeting, the MPC was unanimous in agreeing a 0.25
per cent rare rise, but was careful to point out that this was not a
direct response to the recent inflation data, but was considered the
appropriate adjustment of interest rates to bring inflation back to
target in the medium term. In the following months, inflation fell back
rapidly towards the 2 per cent target.
Just as the MPC had passed this test, by June and July the first
tentative signs of stress were appearing in global financial markets.
Though not immediately apparent at the time, this was to herald the
onset of a new era of volatility and new and unfamiliar challenges for
monetary policy.
Taking stock of the ten-year period from June 1997 to May 2007,
Labour's independent Bank of England and its MPC achieved some
remarkable successes. These successes were not so much in reducing
inflation--the heavy lifting had already been done in the 1980s and
early 1990s (figure 5), before even the Conservatives' introduction
of inflation targeting--but rather in keeping inflation very stable and
cementing expectations that it would remain low in the future. The
historically low volatility of inflation can be seen in table 1, and by
the fact that the MPC almost passed its first ten years without the
Governor ever having to write to the Chancellor to explain why inflation
had moved more than 1 per cent away from target. Back in 1997, a
prediction that ten years would elapse before the first letter would
have been met with derision from most commentators. (10)
The effect of Labour's new monetary policy framework can be
seen even more starkly in terms of what inflation premia were demanded
by bond-market participants, as revealed by the spread between
conventional and index-linked gilts. This reflects both the expected
inflation rate, as well as risk premia associated with uncertainty about
inflation. The record of the Conservatives' inflation targeting
regime between 1992 and 1997 was also one of fairly stable inflation
(figure 5), but it is fair to say that, in spite of this success,
inflation expectations remained stubbornly high (mainly above 4 per
cent), suggesting that the public believed the next upsurge of inflation
was always just around the corner. After the Bank of England became
independent in 1997, measures of inflation expectations exhibited a
significant fall of almost 2 per cent in tile period to 200l (figure 7).
Tile fall in long-term interest rates was even more marked. Long-term
nominal interest rates dropped by 4 per cent in the space of just over
two years (figure 4). The disinflations of the 1980s and 1990s achieved
a similar reduction in long-term rates only over a period of about
fifteen years. While tile Conservatives brought down inflation, Labour
finally convinced the country that it was down for good.
This analysis cannot demonstrate a causal relationship between
Labour's monetary reforms and the stability of the period 1997-2007
with certainty. Many countries were experiencing the great moderation at
this time. However, even a casual glance at figures 4 and 7 does hint at
a structural break around 1997.
The recent experience
From the middle of 2007, world financial markets grew increasingly
volatile. The distress began in credit markets and subsequently spread
more broadly. At the same time, many of the trends from early 2007
continued, namely rises in food and commodity prices. This was coupled
with weakness in sterling and less deflationary pressure than before
from manufactured imports. The MPC continued with its earlier policy of
raising Bank Rate, with a 0.25 per cent increase in July. This turned
out to be the last increase in Bank Rate up to the present time.
Conditions in financial markets worsened further as the year went
on, and the UK experienced its first bank run since 1866 with tile run
on Northern Rock in September. After some prevarication, the Government
was forced to step in and offer a blanket guarantee of deposits at
Northern Rock. To stem contagion, the Government implicitly extended its
guarantee to retail deposits at other banks, even those in excess of the
deposit insurance limit. There were misgivings about the long-run
consequences of such guarantees and, at the time, the Governor of the
Bank of England expressed concerns about their moral hazard
implications.
The MPC was also faced with a pressing problem. Spreads between
Bank Rate and lending rates in the interbank market had surged from
almost negligible levels to more than I per cent on some days. These
problems did not go away, and there were tentative signs that they were
beginning to affect access to credit for agents in the 'real
economy'. Tile MPC resolved that the distress in financial markets
posed a significant downside risk to inflation, one which offset the
remaining upside risks from cost pressures. A 0.25 per cent cut was
unanimously agreed in December 2007.
The story of 2008 was a gradual intensification of the disruption
to the financial system. In the UK, commercial property prices began to
fall and house price growth slowed sharply. There were increasing signs
of a sharp slowdown in domestic demand. However, there was no let-up in
the rise of energy and commodity prices around the world, implying a
significant expected rise in UK inflation as these fed into gas and
electricity prices. This cost-push shock, occurring at the same time as
a fall in demand resulting from the financial crisis, made the trade-off
faced by tile MPC particularly stark. It opted to make a modest
reduction of Bank Rate by 0.25 per cent in February.
By this time, central banks around the world were adapting their
operating procedures so as to inject more liquidity (reserves) into
markets and the banking system. The major central banks launched a
coordinated provision of extra liquidity on 11 March, which for a time
led to some abatement in spreads. However, the fears in financial
markets had moved beyond concerns purely about liquidity and on to
credit risk. This was exemplified by the funding crisis at Bear Stearns,
which led ultimately to a Federal Reserve sponsored bail-out. At its
April meeting, the MPC faced a similar problem to that of February.
There was evidence of falling domestic demand owing to restricted access
to credit, while at the same time inflationary pressure from commodity
prices and a weak exchange rate had not subsided. The committee was
split three ways between those arguing for no cut, a modest 0.25 per
cent cut, and a larger cut of 0.5 per cent. In the end, the 0.25 per
cent cut prevailed, taking Bank Rate to 5.0 per cent.
The Bank's forecast of inflation rising above 3.0 per cent was
confirmed when May's CPI inflation was revealed to be 3.3 per cent.
Another open letter from the Governor was called for. A flurry of
further letters was to follow as CPI inflation surged upwards, reaching
4.7 per cent in August, 5.2 per cent in September, before falling back
to 3.2 per cent in February 2009. During this period, CPI inflation was
consistently more than 1 per cent above target, and moved as much as 3
per cent above its target. While there was only one letter during the
first ten years of the MPC, subsequent events have seen the number of
open letters written reach around 50 per cent of the maximum possible
number {an open letter was only required every three months). The MPC
held Bank Rate at 5.0 per cent in response to the high inflation, though
the committee was at this time split three ways between those arguing
for a reduction in rates, a rise in rates, and a wait-and-see position.
Following the failure of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, the
financial crisis that had first begun in August 2007 now entered a new
phase and threatened to plunge the world economy into a deep depression.
In spite of the elevated level of inflation, the MPC's fear of the
consequences of the collapse in confidence triggered a series of
dramatic unanimously agreed cuts in Bank Rate: 0.5 per cent in October,
1.5 per cent in November, 1.0 per cent in December, and a further series
of 0.5 per cent cuts between January and March. This left Bank Rate at
0.5 per cent by March 2009. The rate had fallen precipitously by 4.5 per
cent in the space of only six months.
During this time, the MPC perceived that a larger stimulus was
going to be required than that which could be delivered through
reductions in Bank Rate alone. Since the cost of storing cash is not
proportionately large, interest rates cannot become negative to any
significant extent. Furthermore, many central banks including the Bank
of England were reluctant to go all the way to zero. The worries about
literally zero interest rates were two-fold: that they would remove
incentives to participate in money markets, and that with deposit rates
already close to zero, further reductions in Bank Rate would put
downward pressure on loan rates, compressing the loan-deposit rate
spread and adversely affecting the profitability of banks and building
societies that were already struggling.
Even though short-maturity risk-free interest rates were now as
close to zero as the Bank was comfortable with, this did not exhaust the
scope for further monetary stimulus, albeit of an unconventional nature.
Long-maturity interest rates on government bonds (gilts) were still well
above 3 per cent, and many interest rates faced by risky borrowers were
yet higher still. Monetary policy now had to be exercised in a different
way to gain traction over these other interest rates.
To this end, the Bank of England began a programme of quantitative
easing (QE) in March 2009 at the time of its last rate cut to date. The
groundwork for quantitative easing had in fact already been laid.
Earlier in January, the Chancellor had announced tile creation of an
asset purchase facility (APF) with the aim of lubricating private credit
markets that had seized tip. The APF', although administered by the
Bank, would purchase assets in exchange for Treasury Bills issued by the
Debt Management Office. The arrangements for tile APF were agreed in an
exchange of letters between the Chancellor and the Governor in January
2009. The type of assets the APF was permitted to purchase were
investment-grade commercial paper and corporate bonds, securities issued
under tile Government's Credit Guarantee Scheme (CGS), as well as
syndicated loans and some asset-backed securities (though the APF has
not made purchases in these last three classes to date). An tipper limit
of 50 billion [pounds sterling] was set on the APF's purchases.
The initial operation of the APF could best be described as credit
easing rather than quantitative casing. Although operated by the Bank,
the APF at this stage was essentially a component of fiscal, not
monetary, policy. This was ensured because the Treasury indemnified the
APF against any losses on its portfolio. In spite of the APF's
fiscal origins, it was envisaged at the time of its creation that it
could potentially evolve into a vehicle for quantitative easing if
desired by the MPC.
It was not long before the APF developed into a monetary policy
tool. Even before it had made its first purchases, the February meeting
of the MPC requested that the Governor seek permission from the
Chancellor to use the APF to buy securities with newly created central
bank reserves, rather than Treasury Bills. A new maximum of 150 billion
[pounds sterling] was requested. Since purchases on this scale would be
large in relation to the private credit markets in which the APF could
operate, it was also requested that the APF be allowed to buy
long-maturity government bonds (gilts).
The Chancellor agreed, and after the March 2009 meeting of the MPC,
quantitative easing began. The new arrangements were that the MPC would
vote separately on a Bank Rate decision and then on a decision about the
quantity of purchases to be made through the APE respecting the upper
limit set by the Chancellor. The old maximum limit of 50 billion [pounds
sterling] was retained for private securities. Purchases of government
securities had to be made in the secondary market, rather than directly
from the Treasury itself. The composition of asset purchases was
delegated to the Bank's executive (subject to the tipper limit on
private securities set by the Chancellor). The MPC decided to embark
initially on a 75 billion [pounds sterling] programme of quantitative
easing. Monetary policy now had a new operational target; in addition to
short-term interest rates, a specific quantity of central bank reserves
was also being targeted.
Given the large quantity of government bonds being purchased, it
was important not to create the impression of any link with fiscal
policy. Accordingly, the Debt Management Office was instructed to go on
with its previous issuance strategy for gilts and not to change its
behaviour in response to quantitative easing. It was also reiterated
that the objective of monetary policy would remain the 2 per cent
inflation target, that quantitative easing was just another tool to be
used to help achieve this goal, and that the Bank of England would
remain operationally independent.
Subsequent meetings of the MPC have decided to extend the scale of
the quantitative easing programme in light of the sharp fall in UK
economic activity and inflation in 2009. In May 2009, the target for
asset purchases was increased to 125 billion [pounds sterling]. By
August, it was thought necessary to request a further increase to 175
billion [pounds sterling], and again in November to 200 billion [pounds
sterling].
Has the policy of quantitative easing proved successful? It is far
too early to say, especially when judged in terms of its final objective
of stimulating demand and avoiding deflationary pressure. But on the
narrower question of its success in influencing long-term interest
rates, there is some evidence of a significant effect. Chart 2 in Bean
(2009) shows reactions at 3-year to 20-year maturities in response to
key events. Based on the assumption that market participants did not
foresee the scale of the QE programme announced by the Bank, the
downward movements of yields around the time of the announcement provide
some evidence of its success. Meier (2009) concludes that QE lowered
ten-year yields by approximately 40-100 basis points relative to what
would otherwise have occurred.
Challenges for the future
After a long period of success, UK monetary policy must now face up
to some formidable challenges. First, to learn how to control inflation
and stabilise the economy using previously untried tools. Second, to
maintain the credibility of the inflation targeting regime in the face
of greater interdependence between monetary and fiscal policy, and
between monetary policy and support to tile banking system and financial
markets.
The transmission mechanism of monetary policy is--even in normal
times- famous for its "long and variable lags". Much research
has gone into quantifying the response of inflation and output growth to
changes in interest rates, and the time horizon over which such
responses will occur. Steering inflation and other macroeconomic
variables using quantitative casing is likely to prove an even bigger
challenge owing to the lack of a reliable guide from past experience to
judge how much a given injection of central bank reserves will stimulate
the economy. Money multipliers may be unstable; as may be the velocity
of money itself. The initial injection of 75 billion [pounds sterling]
of reserves was justified by the MPC as an amount sufficient to offset a
5 per cent fall in nominal aggregate demand (which presupposes a
velocity of money of approximately one). However, there is considerable
uncertainty around this estimate. Among economists, there is much
debate, both theoretical and empirical, over how quantitative easing
will actually affect the economy.
In addition to this first technical challenge, there is perhaps the
more fundamental task of redefining what is monetary policy in a world
where the lines between monetary policy, fiscal policy, and the wide
range of policies designed to support banks and financial markets have
become increasingly blurred.
Given the form quantitative easing has taken in the UK, the most
obvious tension is with fiscal policy. The asset purchase facility (APF)
administered by the Bank has purchased 198 billion [pounds sterling] of
government bonds to date. As of writing, the total stock of long-term
government bonds outstanding is 914 billion [pounds sterling].
Quantitative easing has effectively monetised more than 20 per cent of
government debt, and more than the total issuance of new debt since the
scheme began. The Bank of England has returned to its roots as being one
of the Government's largest creditors. On the other hand, purchases
of private assets have been almost negligible in relation to the 50
billion [pounds sterling] limit set for such assets. Only 1.3 billion
[pounds sterling] of corporate bonds and 30 million [pounds sterling] of
commercial paper have been purchased to date.
It has been stated that quantitative easing is not intended to ease
the Government's fiscal problems, and that the Debt Management
Office (DMO) will act independently, and will follow its usual remit.
But there is an obvious link between the success of quantitative
easing--lowering long-term yields--and the ease with which the
Government's deficit can be financed. The DMO's objective
includes the aim "to minimise, over the long term, the costs of
meeting the Government's financing needs". If quantitative
easing is successful at flattening the yield curve, and the DMO follows
its stated objective, then it should take advantage of this by changing
the maturity of the bonds it issues to lower the Government's
borrowing costs.
The challenge for the MPC is in demonstrating to the public that it
remains independent of the Treasury. The MPC's decision about the
quantity of central bank reserves to create is subject to the maximum
level of asset purchases set by the Chancellor. The rationale for the
upper limit is that the Treasury continued to indemnify the APF against
losses even when it was extended as a vehicle for quantitative easing.
But the MPC's actual use of the APF has frequently rubbed up
against the limits set by the Chancellor. In both May and August 2009 it
was necessary for the Governor to request that the Chancellor raise the
upper limit for asset purchases to permit the expansion of quantitative
easing agreed by the MPC. Such permission was sought immediately after
the MPC's meeting in the time before the public announcement of the
policy change. What would happen if the Chancellor refused to go along
with such requests? While this issue is currently moot, it does raise
the broad question of what an operationally independent central bank can
do in the current environment.
Quantitative easing is currently operating at its agreed upper
limit (200 billion [pounds sterling]). A further expansion will again
require the Chancellor's permission. Even maintaining the current
limit is subject to annual review. These requests for Treasury
endorsement of what are supposed to be monetary policy decisions is
certainly a challenge to the framework and any suspicions of a quid pro
quo need to be avoided. However, given that the Treasury and ultimately
the taxpayer are liable for any losses, placing some limit on the
maximum exposure to risk is not unreasonable, making it hard to avoid
this fiscal oversight of monetary policy.
This problem did not arise in the past because normal monetary
policy operations conducted through short-term repos are not subject to
any significant credit risk, nor the risk of capital losses owing to
price movements since the Bank would not be taking an outright position.
Quantitative easing changes that. The value of a portfolio of long-term
bonds held outright can shift significantly with only modest changes in
interest rates. Furthermore, the purchase of private securities also
exposes the Bank to credit risk. Without the Treasury indemnity, the
Bank could not credibly maintain a commitment to price stability in the
future as it might need to expand its balance sheet, earning income to
rebuild its capital if it were to face significant losses. Tile price of
the indemnity is some loss of independence, whether perceived or actual.
So the separate conduct of monetary and fiscal policy thus raises
challenges. Experience of the past thirteen years may suggest that any
loss of independence is likely to be a temporary phenomenon and that the
customary division of labour between the Treasury and the Bank of
England on fiscal and monetary policy can be resumed. However, given the
current state of the economy and the fiscal challenge that lies ahead,
it may still be some time before this is the case. And this may create a
need for a more joined-up approach, particularly as the path of fiscal
tightening becomes clearer after the election.
The experience of the past few years has cast doubt on the claim
that inflation targeting is sufficient for macroeconomic stability. In
particular, it has not prevented the emergence and spread of a dramatic
financial crisis. For this to be entered on the charge sheet against
inflation targeting it would have to be argued that monetary policy
could have prevented or ameliorated such a crisis had it been conducted
differently.
The goal of inflation targeting is by definition to maintain the
value of money in terms of goods. This raises a fundamental question:
what is this money whose value is being defended? In no economy
practising inflation targeting is money restricted to reserves meaning
those liabilities whose issuance is monopolised by the central bank.
Money encompasses a much broader range of liabilities, most of which are
the creation of commercial banks. To the extent that the public ought to
perceive the various components of money as perfect substitutes for one
another, this suggests a coordination issue between monetary policy in
the strict sense and financial policy and regulation more generally.
What controls should be exercised on the expansion of money and credit
by non-central hank institutions? Recent experience suggests that
downplaying such regulation puts monetary policy in danger of being
diverted from its core objective towards supporting those financial
institutions should they get into difficulties.
It would be possible to envisage a monetary system where banks were
obliged to hold 100 per cent reserves against deposits, so banks had no
control over the money supply at all. In such a situation, bank runs
cannot be systemic problems as each bank can settle its liabilities to
depositors using base money without the need for central bank
intervention. This would reduce the need for bail-outs. In such a world
it would be possible to draw a line between monetary policy and
financial regulation and bank supervision. However, such a narrow
banking system would be a radical departure from current practice, and
is unlikely to be adopted in the foreseeable future.
Without narrow banking, the central bank faces the challenge of
separating liquidity crises from solvency crises. In principle, a
central bank can support financial institutions during a liquidity
crisis without any tension between this and its price stability
objective. This is because the supply of reserves is increasing in line
with demand. On the other hand, in a solvency crisis, an expansion of
reserves may be inflationary because the collateral the central bank
receives in exchange for its support may have a fair value lower than
the value of the reserves it supplies to troubled financial
institutions. Even if the quantity of reserves is not itself perceived
as an inflation risk, central-bank support as lender-of-last-resort to
commercial banks allows the latter to borrow from depositors at low
risk-free rates, enabling such banks to make loans at lower interest
rates. Access to credit at lower interest rates would stimulate demand
and add to inflationary pressure. Since it may be difficult for central
banks to distinguish clearly between liquidity and solvency problems,
this could lead to an in-built tension between price stability and
financial stability.
These problems are not confined to the creation of broad money by
commercial banks. One issue that contributed to the financial crisis was
the reliance of financial institutions on short-term financing of
long-term lending. The 'shadow banking system' would issue and
roll over, for example, short-maturity commercial paper to finance
long-term lending to securitisation vehicles set up by banks and finance
companies. This arrangement, for as long as it lasted, meant that the
prices of inherently illiquid assets were pushed tip, eliminating the
liquidity premium that might otherwise be expected for such assets. The
rise in borrowing costs and yields associated with the financial crisis
reflected in part a return of liquidity premia to illiquid assets.
Many central bank interventions in financial markets have aimed to
reduce such spreads and premia to what are considered 'normal'
levels--those prevailing before the onset of the crisis. They have
attempted to do this through an expansion of lending of central bank
reserves against a much wider pool of eligible collateral than was ever
tolerated by central banks in normal times. Furthermore, central banks
have lent reserves for longer maturities than the usual overnight or
one-week lending periods. For example, the Bank of England's
extended-collateral long-term repo operations and its Special Liquidity
Scheme grant access to liquid reserves for longer durations and against
assets that would be considered illiquid by markets without such
policies in place.
It is not unlikely that there could be tensions between the Bank of
England's policies to support financial markets and commercial
banks and its ultimate goal of price stability, though this tension is
probably latent at the current time. The Bank must come to some
judgement about how much liquid central bank reserves it wants to inject
into the financial system and thus how much it wants to reduce spreads
and liquidity premia. Financial stability may require it to aim for the
spreads that financial-market participants were expecting, or had
previously become accustomed to. Price stability may require it to aim
for spreads that are 'normal' in the sense of not reducing the
cost of borrowing for risky and illiquid lending to the point that it
stimulates demand and inflationary pressure.
Exactly what additional instruments could be added to the monetary
policy portfolio is one of the big issues going forward and coming out
of the current crisis. As Tucker (2009) observes, there will be need for
some element of discretion in the macroprudential instruments needed to
secure financial stability. Whether these are part of the remit of the
MPC is moot. At the heart of that debate lies a question of whether
there really is a separation between monetary policy and credit policy.
In the run-up to the crisis, a number of members of the MPC expressed
concern about the growth of leverage. And it is even possible that there
would have been a consensus to act on this had the instruments been
available to the committee. However, it is clear that, even then, this
would have been hard to justify solely in terms of an inflation
targeting mandate. So, in the end, it may be that these instruments are
thought of as distinct from monetary policy because the goal, securing
financial stability, is distinct. However, there is an irreducible
common issue. The way in which Bank Rate affects the economy is
crucially dependent on the state of the financial system in good times
and bad. Measures to tighten or loosen credit conditions by other means
are therefore likely to have a direct bearing on the conduct of monetary
policy. So there will be a need for policy coordination at least.
As we discussed at the outset, inflation targeting around the world
has been seen as one of the success stories of macroeconomic policy.
However, the earliest experiments with inflation targeting date from the
early 1990s, a time when the great moderation had either arrived or was
imminent in many countries. Inflation targeting simply does not have an
established track record in more turbulent times. This raises the
question of whether its success can be replicated should the great
moderation turn out to be a temporary aberration.
One potential danger in more turbulent times derives from one of
inflation targeting's advantages: its eclecticism. Inflation
targeting recognises that price stability is the ultimate goal of
monetary policy, and then allows central banks great flexibility and
discretion in how to go about achieving that end. While the central bank
would usually have a particular operational target, a short-maturity
interest rate, no other macroeconomic variable receives a privileged
status as an intermediate target. This contrasts sharply with the
monetary-policy strategies of the past, which have usually granted a
special status either to monetary aggregates or exchange rates. But the
many attempts to implement such strategies often demonstrated that the
intermediates were less well connected with price stability than their
advocate believed. Inflation targeting could be said to make the central
bank's inflation forecast its intermediate target, but no
constraints are placed on how inflation should be forecast, nor on the
extent to which the central bank can exercise judgement about the
confidence intervals surrounding its central projection.
By lumping together everything that might influence future
inflation in the central bank's inflation forecast, an efficient
outcome can be achieved in that the central bank is not forced to
respond to an intermediate target that it believes is not providing the
right signals about inflationary pressure. Providing the central
bank's forecasts are sufficiently reliable, in that they are not
obviously biased and have a sufficiently small error on average, this
design of policy gives it a significant advantage over its competitors.
But the benefit of an intermediate target may be less to do with its
supposed tight relationship with inflation than the opportunity it gives
the central bank to demonstrate it is actually doing what it says it
will do.
Some intermediate targets such as the monetary base or the exchange
rate have the advantage that the central bank can exercise more direct
control over them than it does for inflation itself. It is widely
believed that the transmission mechanism of monetary policy to inflation
works slowly at best, with the conventional wisdom being that interest
rates affect inflation with a two-year lag. Even then, the relationship
between the two is imperfect. Under these circumstances, it can be hard
for an inflation-targeting central bank to demonstrate commitment to its
stated goals. The public sees only the failures to meet those goals and
not the ultimate reason why: whether it was simply a mistake, or whether
the central bank had decided to pursue goals different from its stated
objectives. While intermediate targets are also not perfectly controlled
by the central bank, the lags are likely to be shorter and the
relationship with monetary policy tighter than for inflation itself.
While such concerns seem less relevant in tranquil times, the Bank
of England has gone from a decade where no letters to the Chancellor
were written to explain inflation deviations of more than 1 per cent
from target to writing six letters in three years, all of which had to
justify inflation being above target.
The trade-off between a monetary policy strategy that uses an
intermediate target and one that does not is then the sacrifice of
efficiency in meeting the ultimate goal for credibility gains. A more
volatile macroeconomic environment, and one where there is more
ambiguity over what ultimate goals monetary policy should be striving to
meet, may make the trade-off swing in favour of intermediate targets in
the future, especially if other factors (monetary/fiscal policy
interactions, support to the financial system) call into question the
primacy of price stability as the goal of central banks and thus
increase the need to demonstrate commitment. Such issues will also be
central to discussions of the right target for macroprudential
instruments and their relationship to the inflation target.
Concluding comment
The record of monetary policy under Labour is closely intertwined
with the record of the independent MPC which it created. As the party
that introduced the current arrangements, it seems fair to allow Labour
to bask in any reflected glory. And the political consensus now lies in
favour of the arrangements that Labour introduced in 1997. Creating this
consensus is an achievment in and of itself.
But, the past three years have thrown up challenges that have yet
to be resolved. The inflation targeting framework as practised in the UK
and elsewhere relied in significant measure on two lines in the sand
that have been washed away by recent events. (11) The first is that
monetary and fiscal policy can be separated--something which is no
longer the case in an era of unconventional policy. Until the Treasury
gets on top of the fiscal deficit the interplay between fiscal and
monetary policy will be crucial. The second is the separation of
monetary policy and banking supervision and financial-market regulation.
It is evident from the period leading to the crisis and afterwards that
there is a need for a more joined-up approach recognising that the
operation of financial markets in the creation of money and credit is
essential for a proper understanding of monetary policy. (12) It may be
that we can hang on and hope that the tide will recede so that the lines
in the sand can be redrawn. But more likely the waters will remain
turbulent, creating a need for a more fundamental rethink of some
aspects of policy. But, whatever happens next, this will be building on
a position of considerable strength in a set of arrangements which have
evolved over nearly two decades.
doi: 10.1177/0027950110372733
REFERENCES
Bank of England, Who sets our interest rates? available at http://
www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/other/monetary/ inside_mpc.pdf.
Bean, C.R. (I 998), 'The new UK monetary arrangements: a view
from the literature', Economic Journal, 108(451), pp. 17951809.
--(2009), 'Quantitative easing: an interim report',
available at http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2009/
speech405.pdf.
Bernanke, B. (2004), 'The Great Moderation', remarks at
the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, DC, 20 February.
Bernanke, B., Laubach, T., Mishkin, F. and Posen, A. ( 1997),
Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Bernanke, B. and Woodford, M. (2005), The Inflation Targeting
Debate, NBER, University of Chicago Press.
Blanchard, O., Dell' Ariccia, G. and Mauro, P. (2010),
'Rethinking macroeconomic policy', available at
http://www.imf.org/ external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1003.pdf.
Fenwick, D. and Roe, D. (2004), 'The new inflation target: the
statistical perspective', Office for National Statistics, Economic
Trends no. 602--http://www.statistics.gov.uk/articles/
economic_trends/ET602Roe.pdf.
King, M. (2002), "The inflation target ten years on',
available at I 0http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/
2002/speech 181 .pdf.
--(2007), 'The MPC ten years on', available at http://
www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2007/ speech309.pdf.
Meier, A. (2009), 'Panacea, curse, or nonevent? Unconventional
monetary policy in the United Kingdom', IMF working paper 09/163
(August)--http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/
imf/imfwp/2009/00009163/00000200/art00001.
Rogoff, K. (1985), 'The optimal degree of commitment to an
intermediate monetary target', Quarterly Journal of Economics,
100(4), pp. I 169-89.
Sargent, T. (2010), 'Uncertainty and ambiguity in American
fiscal and monetary policies', A.W. Phillips Lecture, LSE.
Tucker, P. (2009), 'The debate on the financial system
resilience: macroprudential instruments', available at http://
www.bankofengland.co.uk/pu blications/speeches/2009/ speech407.pdf.
NOTES
(1) Cited in King (2002).
(2) See Bernanke and Woodford (2005) and Bernanke et al. (I 997)
for background discussion.
(3) See, for example, Rogoff (1985).
(4) The description of the pre-1997 inflation targeting regime
draws on Bernanke et al. (1997).
(5) This contrasts, for example, with the US Federal Reserve whose
much vaguer mandate effectively allows it to set its own goals.
(6) See Bank of England for an overview of the workings of the
system.
(7) The longest serving external member has been Kate Barker, who
served three consecutive terms.
(8) The following discussion draws upon the minutes of the MPC
meetings, as published by the Bank of England.
(9) See Fenwick and Roe (2004) for an analysis.
(10) For example, Bean (1998) estimated that, based on the
UK's historical experience, inflation would be likely to diverge
more than I per cent from the target about 40 per cent of the time.
(11) See Sargent (2010) on the importance of these distinctions in
the history of macroeconomic policy.
(12) It is also worth noting that fiscal policy and financial
regulation may also be directly linked in future. In the short term
fiscal instruments could also play an important role in regulating the
use of credit (e.g. by a tax on credit).
Timothy Besley and Kevin Sheedy *
* London School of Economics. e-mail: T.
[email protected]. The
authors would like to thank Paul Tucker and Martin Weale for helpful
comments on an earlier draft and Gianni La Cava for research assistance.
Table 1. Retail price inflation by decade
Decade Mean Standard Deviation
1950s 4.1 2.7
1960s 3.7 1.5
1970s 13.1 5.4
1980s 6.9 4.6
1990s 3.5 2.3
2000s 2.7 1.1
Notes: Calculations based on the (all items) retail price index. As
point of comparison, the (all items) consumer price index grew, on
average, by 3.1 per cent in the 1990s and 1.9 per cent in the 2000s.
Table 2. Retail price inflation by elected government
Government Period Average inflation
rate
Labour Oct 1964 to May 1970 4.7
Conservative Jun 1970 to Jan 1974 9.2
Labour Feb 1974 to Apr 1979 15.5
Conservative May 1979 to Apr 1997 6.0
Labour May 1997+ 2.6
Notes: Calculations based on the retail price index (all items).