Macroprudential regulation--the missing policy pillar.
Davis, E. Philip ; Karim, Dilruba
The recent Sub-Prime crisis has prompted a close focus on the
causes of financial instability as well as the issue of whether it can
be prevented. There is a growing realisation that the Sub-Prime crisis,
although having some important unique features, also had a number of
generic aspects in common with earlier financial crises, of which a
large number have been seen in recent decades. Accordingly, the crisis
has prompted a debate about macroprudential policy, which focuses on the
financial system as a whole, treating aggregate risk as endogenous with
regard to collective behaviour of institutions. Our survey shows that a
great deal of progress has been made in 'macroprudential
surveillance' and related research on causes and predictors of
crises. Much less progress has been made in 'macroprudential
regulation', the design and implementation of policies to prevent
or mitigate threatened crises.
Keywords: Financial crises; macroprudential policy; financial
regulation
JEL Classifications: G28; E44
I. Introduction
The current financial crisis has led to an increased focus on
financial instability, but also a realisation that similar events have
been extremely common in recent decades. (1) We define financial
instability, or systemic risk, as entailing heightened risk of a
financial crisis--"a major collapse of the financial system,
involving an inability to provide payments services or to allocate
credit". Two main sources of such systemic risk can be discerned.
First is the tendency for financial and nonfinancial firms and
households to overexpose themselves to risk in the upturn of the credit
cycle, and then become risk averse in the downturn. This may relate to
credit, liquidity or market risk. Second is the tendency of financial
firms to ignore spillover effects of their behaviour on the rest of the
financial system (Bank of England, 2009).
Macroprudential policy aims to counteract threats to financial
instability. Consistent with the above, such macroprudential policy can
be defined as that which focuses on the financial system as a whole, and
also treats aggregate risk as endogenous with regard to collective
behaviour of institutions. It aims to limit system wide distress so as
to offer a stable provision of financial services to the economy and
thus avoid output costs associated with financial instability (Borio,
2009). Although ultimately leading to efficient allocations of
productive capital, in common with microprudential policy,
macroprudential policy is likely to impose short-term costs on the
financial sector and hence reduce availability of credit to some
households and companies. These costs need to be weighed against
benefits of greater financial stability. (2)
This article seeks to assess the need for a macroprudential policy
pillar and the degree to which progress has been made in instituting
one, viewed in the light of lessons learnt in the field of financial
stability over the past decade. During this period there have been
numerous crises, coinciding with considerable research and developments
in policy and culminating in the lessons of the current crisis. A major
impetus to these have been a growing realisation of the costs of crises,
which can be over 20 per cent of GDP (Hoggarth and Sapporta, 2001). A
further stimulus is the realisation that such crises have related to
shared exposure to macroeconomic risks and not solely the failure of a
single large institution. Many central banks have obtained a mandate to
pursue financial stability (Das et al., 2004). A key policy development
has been Macroprudential Surveillance, although as highlighted, there
remain some unanswered questions as to its use in practice in full-blown
Macroprudential Regulation.
2. Why we need macroprudential regulation--developments in the
understanding of the process of financial instability
A generic approach
A primary issue, and background for the rest of our article, is a
growing realisation of the generic nature of financial crises. In other
words, they are not disparate random events but share key common
features. As highlighted in the table below, there are both exogenous
and endogenous aspects.
The process often starts with a primary shock to the economy and
financial system that is favourable to growth and investment. But this
leads to a process of propagation, whereby there is a build-up of
vulnerability in the economy and financial system, associated with
overextension of balance sheets and build-up of financial imbalances.
Price based measures of asset values rise and price based measures of
risk fall, while risk appetites increase. Balance sheets grow (including
off balance sheet exposures), short-term funding increases and leverage
rises. Hence there is increased aggregate exposure to credit risk
(leverage), liquidity risk (short-term funding) and market risk (size
and volatility of balance sheets). (3) Firms may also become more
interconnected, increasing network risk, unless regulation penalises
such links.
The aggregate risks exacerbate the boom, leading to a crisis when a
secondary (adverse) shock hits a vulnerable financial system. This
causes asset prices and market liquidity to fall, and defaults to
increase, leading to a sharp rise in risk aversion and a credit
contraction. In turn, there is further propagation in a crisis period
(systemic risk), as for example failure of interconnected firms may lead
to major spillovers. This typically prompts policy reactions if the
crisis is sufficiently severe, and considerable adverse economic
consequences (the 'costs of instability').
Types of crisis
Whereas traditional banking crises remain a major manifestation of
financial instability, especially in emerging market economies,
awareness has grown in the past two decades that there are alternative
forms of crisis that may equally lead to systemic consequences. These
are related to the ongoing securitisation of financial systems. One is
extreme market price volatility after a shift in expectations (see
Davis, 2002). Whereas violent price movements may in themselves not have
systemic implications, (4) these may emerge when such movements threaten
institutions that have taken leveraged positions on the current levels
of asset prices. Currency crises, a subset of these, may sharply affect
banking systems, giving rise to "twin crises" (Kaminsky and
Reinhart, 1999) as in Asia in 1997 and Argentina in 2001.
There may instead be protracted (5) collapses of debt or
derivatives market liquidity and issuance. These are analogous to bank
runs in that asymmetric information and uncertainty generate liquidity
collapses via panic sales of the asset concerned (see Davis, 1994). The
risks are acute not only for those holding positions in the market but
also for those relying on the market for debt finance or
liquidity--which increasingly include banks. The Russia/LTCM crisis of
1998 and, particularly, the US Sub-Prime crisis which began in 2007,
showed that these market-liquidity crises are recurrent features of
modern financial systems (Davis, 2009a) given the structure of the
modern financial system they can shift rapidly across borders. The
Sub-Prime crisis has shown that interbank market liquidity can be highly
vulnerable as well as that of securitised debt markets. Periodic
collapse has been a feature of international interbank markets (Bernard
and Bisignano, 2000) but had hitherto been less common in domestic
interbank markets.
Lessons from traditional theory
The traditional theories of financial instability are set out in
Davis (1995, 1999, 2002). Rather than repeating them here, we highlight
some aspects shown to be of particular relevance to the macroprudential
approach. The 'financial fragility' view (6) (Kindleberger,
1978; Minsky, 1977) has been repeatedly vindicated by recurrence of
credit and asset price booms, followed by crises, as in Asia 1997 and in
the US Sub-Prime episode. The overall structure of the 'generic
crisis' set out in the table links closely to this approach.
Secondly, the relevance of the 'uncertainty' approach (7)
has been shown by repeated problems with institutions' exposures to
financial innovations, whose properties are not yet tested over a full
cycle and are thus subject to uncertainty. The recent bank exposures to
Asset Backed Securities (ABS) entailing credit risk transfer is a case
in point. Equally, the 'disaster myopia' theory (8) is
illustrated by the apparent short memories of instability once a period
of calm has been observed. Disaster myopia highlights incentives leading
to underpricing of risk and these may in turn reflect expectations of
safety net provision and regulatory arbitrage, both of which have been
seen in the Sub-Prime crisis.
Recent theoretical research findings
Selected recent research findings are highlighted here, again for
the light they cast on the macroprudential channels of transmission of
financial instability.
Allen (2005) (9) models links between asset price bubbles and
financial fragility. Central to bubble creation are principal-agent
conflicts since bank managers' upside-risk payoffs increase in risk
whereas limited financial liability ensures restricted downside-risk
losses. (10) With intermediation, investors place borrowed funds (11)
into risky assets such as commercial property and transfer default risk
onto lenders. This motivates borrowers to bid-up asset prices above
their fundamental (12) values creating a bubble. Moreover, bubbles are
propagated by investors' expectations of higher future credit
availability and credit volatility, since this allows higher asset
returns via risk transfer. Hence macroprudential focus should be on
incentives and bubble detection, inter alia.
Theoretical and empirical models of contagion--noted above as
central to the macroprudential approach--are extensively reviewed by De
Bandt and Hartmann (2000). Freixas and Parigi (1998) and Freixas et al.
(2000) focus on direct bank linkages and suggest borrowing arrangements
between banks cause a domino effect if one bank is unable to meet its
obligations, sometimes due to depositors withdrawing funds from a single
bank in fear of deposit withdrawals from others. (13) Resulting
externalities which explain 'rational herding' are modelled by
Chen (1999).
Empirical work has shown contagion to be a valid concept.
Autocorrelation between bank failures indicates concentrations of
failures i.e. contagion (De Bandt and Hartmann, 2002). Abnormal bank
stock price behaviour alongside 'bad news' of banks'
performance (tested by event studies) also shows contagion, as does
depositors' behaviour in response to bad news. Calomiris and Mason
(2000) identified abnormally high withdrawals during the Great
Depression. Jayanti and Whyte (1996) find significant increases in UK
and Canadian banks' Certificate of Deposit rates after the
Continental Illinois failure (1984), indicating international contagion.
As regards fundamental-driven contagion, most banking crisis
prediction models (such as Demirguc Kunt and Detragiache, 2005) employ
purely domestic variables, albeit often capturing cross-border impacts
(such as terms of trade and the exchange rate). Santor (2003) finds
crises are more likely following the occurrence of crises in countries
in the same income group--a result he attributes to information rather
than fundamental driven contagion. On the other hand Barrell et al.
(2010) found that weighted (14) occurrence of a crisis in an OECD country affects crisis probabilities elsewhere in that group. This may
be attributable to a variety of contagion channels.
Aspachs et al. (2007) suggest two components should define
financial fragility, usable in macroprudential analysis, namely, reduced
bank profitability and increased default probability. The advantage is
that such indicators can be applied at a firm or aggregate level
(Goodhart et al., 2006). The combination is used because neither
component alone implies fragility; lower profitability could arise
through recession and excessive risk taking could raise defaults without
instability. Heterogeneous agents with a distribution of risk appetites
are used to link fragility with welfare changes; Aspachs et al. (2007)
show an exogenous banking system shock increases aggregate defaults,
decreases profits and reduces agents' welfare. These theoretical
predictions are calibrated against UK data.
Shin (2008) suggests that by holding assets which are claims
against other borrowers and by holding claims against each other,
financial institutions generate complex webs of risk exposures; relative
asset and liability values, credit availability and asset prices become
interdependent. Resulting externalities mean shocks to financial systems
are amplified, causing spillovers onto many balance sheets. (15) The
author models a system of interlocking balance sheets to solve for asset
prices which depend on the creditworthiness of other institutions in the
system. He shows this fixed point problem has a well defined solution;
each claim can be uniquely priced in terms of parameters describing the
underlying financial system (current prices of underlying assets, debt
levels and structure, and the profile of balance sheet inter-linkages),
which are hence areas requiring focus.
Recent research has also focussed on regulators' incentives.
Kocherlakota and Shim (2006) suggest the regulator's response to
instability is conditioned on the ex-ante probability of asset price
collapse; if this is high, remedial action is optimal, otherwise the
regulator shows forbearance towards instability. Principal-agent and
political motives explain why regulators show forbearance (instead of
'prompt corrective action') towards instability. (16)
Degennaro and Thompson (1996) suggest regulators who act as
utility-maximising agents view forbearance as an attractive gambling
strategy where taxpayers bear the costs for losing the gamble as has
occurred already to some extent in the sub-prime context.
The sub-prime crisis has led to further advances in the
understanding of financial instability relevant for macroprudential
purposes. For example, Adrian and Shin (2008) suggest that contagion
during the current crisis differed, in quite specific ways, from that in
traditional liquidity crisis models. The traditional view is that credit
risk leads to contagion, either via direct exposures or uncertainty over
opaque balance sheets. In the current world, Adrian and Shin argue that
contagion occurs via changes in market prices, according to the way that
risks are measured and the mark-to-market practices of financial
institutions. Financial institutions are seen to manage balance sheets
actively in response to price changes and measured risk. Moreover, this
appears to have led to a positive relation between changes in leverage
of commercial banks and balance sheet size, as they have taken on
behaviour patterns hitherto more typical of investment banks.
A helpful complementary paradigm of funding liquidity that
encompasses some of the events of the 2007 and 2008 crisis is provided
by Freixas et al. (2000). According to this model, liquidity may dry up
for a solvent bank in the interbank market if there is imperfect
information, or if there is market tension which reduces the lending
banks' excess liquidity and reduces its scope to diversify. The
interbank market as a whole may face liquidity problems if each bank
refuses to lend to others because it cannot be confident of its own
ability to borrow, a form of liquidity crisis akin to the Diamond-Dybvig
(1983) model.
Brunnermeier (2009) talks of four mechanisms by which small shocks
are amplified, leading to a loss of liquidity. These are first,
borrowers' balance sheet effects comprising a loss spiral (as an
initial loss on a leveraged balance sheet leads to a decline in net
worth, sales and price movements, further reducing net worth) and a
margin spiral (as increased margins lead to deleveraging and sales,
leading to lower prices, further increasing margins). Second is a
lending channel effect (notably precautionary hoarding of liquidity).
Third are runs on institutions and markets (including the interbank,
ABCP and investment bank repo markets). Fourth are network effects, for
example, when Goldman Sachs expressed concerns about exposures to Bear
Stearns via swap netting arrangement, hedge funds avoided Bear Stearns
as a prime broker thereby helping to bring about its demise.
Finally, off-balance sheet risks are a new feature of the current
crisis, a manifestation of the increasing deregulation and innovation
within the OECD financial markets as noted recently by Acharya and
Richardson (2009). They argue that the post-2000 explosion of asset
backed security issuance was driven by banks' desire to avoid
holding costly capital against their assets. (17) This regulatory
arbitrage is what the authors cite as the main cause of the Sub-Prime
episode.
Farhi and Tirole (2009) suggest that the maturity mismatch within
special investment vehicles (SIVs) and conduits (between long-term
mortgage backed assets and the short term commercial paper used to
finance them) was a structural feature of the business models of most
banks who displayed strategic complementarities with their peers. When
authorities use monetary (or fiscal) policy to bail out failing banks,
society incurs a fixed cost which is only justified if sufficient banks
need bailing out. Therefore each individual bank correlates its risk
exposure with other banks such that OBS risks can become systemically
high. This highlights the need for macroprudential surveillance to
recognise risks arising from innovations in banking.
3. Progress with the macroprudential pillar--the development of
macroprudential oversight
Definition
Owing to costs of crisis, it has been realised that there is an
immense premium on timely warnings regarding systemic risks as an input
to policy decisions as well as to strategies and market behaviour of
financial institutions. There is also a realisation following the theory
and experience outlined above that forms of aggregate risk which pervade in periods of vulnerability are easily missed by regulators focussed on
individual institutions, since risks depend on institutions'
collective behaviour (Bank of England, 2009). (18) Equally, network risk
depends on the scale of interconnection between firms that requires an
overall view of such links. Both can give rise to credit and liquidity
risks. Accordingly, in the past decade 'macroprudential
surveillance'--defined as monitoring of conjunctural and structural
trends in financial markets so as to give warning of the approach of
financial instability--has become a core activity for many central
banks. We summarise progress here before highlighting below that such
surveillance is necessary but not sufficient to provide an alternative
policy pillar.
Methods of surveillance
Typically, central banks institute regular Financial Stability
Reviews to assess the outlook for financial stability. Already by
end-2005, 50 central banks had done so (Cihak, 2006), often prompted by
IMF/World Bank Financial Sector Assessment Programmes (FSAPs).
Data needs (Davis, 1999) include macroeconomic and financial data
for assessing conjunctural conditions, non-financial sector debt,
leverage and asset prices for considering vulnerability of borrowers,
and in the light of these, bank balance sheets and income and
expenditure for considering robustness of banks. Risk measures derived
from financial prices complement leverage and income indicators. Stress
tests and forecasts of indicators and derived stability indicators such
as defaults and bankruptcies, including risks to the central projection,
are needed to tell a full story.
As discussed in Davis (1999), key lesson learnt in surveillance
practice for these data include the importance of economy in the number
of variables to tell a coherent story, and derivation of data needs from
theory and experience. Furthermore, there is a need to use qualitative
aspects; surveillance cannot be purely numerical and unlike inflation is
not easily summarised in a single index. Changes in regulation and
competition, and innovation, are among key qualitative inputs. Equally,
there is a need to develop benchmarks and norms for the economy and
financial system to assess deviations, while remaining aware that these
can change (e.g. during financial liberalisation). Cross-border as well
as domestic influences need to be taken into account, not least given
the internationalisation of banking. Also new players such as hedge
funds need to be incorporated when they become relevant.
There is a need for observation of overall patterns in the light of
past occurrences of financial instability, both at home and abroad,
developments in theory and the generic view set out in table 1. Viewed
in the light of that table, data can show either shocks (e.g. triggering
boom or crisis) or propagation mechanisms (showing whether a boom is
underway with heightened vulnerability). But since shocks are random,
the vulnerabilities are the main focus. Then there is a need for a
judgmental approach in drawing conclusions, using again a conceptual
framework derived from theory such as that of table 1 (how vulnerable is
the system--what shocks could take place?). Fell and Schinasi (2005)
suggest the use of an implicit corridor of financial stability, akin to
an exchange rate target, with judgements made as to whether the system
is inside the corridor, approaching the edge, just outside or
systematically outside, which will imply different policy
recommendations.
As an example of a procedure, the ECB undertake a 7-point
vulnerabilities exercise, first identifying vulnerabilities and
imbalances, then translating them into potential risk scenarios,
identifying triggers (shocks) for the scenarios, assessing the
likelihood of scenarios arising, estimating the costs for the financial
system, assessing robustness to such shocks and then ranking the risk.
They note the need to include endogenous sources of risk (within
institutions, markets and infrastructure) as well as exogenous risks
from the macroeconomy. Fell and Schinasi (2005) give a check list of
criteria for sound analysis including: Is the process systematic? Are
the risks identified plausible? Are the risks identified systemically
relevant? Can linkages and transmission (or contagion) channels be
identified? Have risks and linkages been cross-checked? Has the
identification of risks been time consistent?
Tools for macroprudential analysis
'Distance to Default' (DtD) (19) measures credit risk by
expressing a firm's net worth as a proportion of asset price
volatility; (20) the higher this ratio, the lower the likelihood of
default. Looking at all banks, one can take a view of collective risks
to the banking sector. (21) Any asset with a liquid secondary market
(22) can be used because assuming market efficiency, prices should
incorporate markets' forward looking expectations of firm default
(Chan-Lau, 2006). However, when applied to banking distress, DtD ignores
the likelihood of regulators intervening well before default. Hence
Chan-Lau and Sy (2007) suggest banking DtD measures should reflect
regulatory capital requirements, in line with the Basel Committee.
For a given confidence interval and time span, Value at Risk (VAR),
a market risk measure, indicates the maximum expected portfolio loss
under normal market conditions (Benninga and Weiner, 1998). Again these
may be aggregated for macroprudential purposes. Basel sets a 99 per cent
confidence interval and a 10-day horizon, based on at least twelve
months' historic data. (23) Banks must hold at least three times
this VAR amount in capital. Criticisms arise because means, variances
and correlations of asset returns are based on assumed probability
distributions. Also, quantifying actual portfolio positions requires
detailed knowledge of all asset risks by banks.
Stress tests quantify portfolio movements for unlikely but feasible
events (see BIS, 2000 and 2001 for more detail). Scenario tests
simultaneously vary several risks in one direction, emulating historic
events or hypothetical scenarios. Sensitivity tests shock individual
risks symmetrically. (24) Limitations arise because probabilities of
shocks materialising are not computed. Also, risk parameters are at
times subjectively chosen by managers and impose high computational
costs on institutions.
Bubble (25) detection searches for bubble premia, excess volatility
and cointegration between dividends and prices (Brooks and Katsaris,
2003). In older models, bubble components exploded over time, whereas
recent, more realistic models allow prices to return to fundamentals via
crashes (Raymond Feingold, 2001). This makes detection by cointegration
harder due to bias and kurtosis (Evans, 1991), hence correction for
these will improve bubble detection (Raymond Feingold, 2001).
Early Warning Systems (EWS) generate out-of-sample probabilities of
crisis using historic data. Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (1997)
developed a parametric EWS for banking crises using a multinomial logit
model with macroeconomic, financial and structural variables as inputs.
Logistic models are appropriate for explaining binary banking crisis
observations in panel data. Davis and Karim (2008a) improved prediction
by introducing more countries, crises (26) and dynamics in the macro
variables; over 90 per cent of in-sample crises were correctly
identified. More recently, Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze (2009) have
shown that heterogeneous country samples are inadequate for EWS design
since, for the OECD at least, crisis determinants are entirely different
from other countries; in the OECD, banking liquidity, leverage and real
house price growth supersede the traditional macroeconomic factors
significant in global models (27) as the main predictors of banking
crises.
Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) developed a nonparametric signal
extraction EWS which tracks individual time series for abnormal
behaviour that has previously been associated with crises. If a variable
subsequently behaves abnormally, a crisis probability can be computed.
Davis and Karim (2008a) improve signal extraction for banking crisis
prediction by creating composites of indicators weighted by their
signalling quality.
Difficulties in identifying systemic crises compromise the EWS
dependent variable. Also, predictive accuracy varies according to the
cut-off threshold subjectively chosen by the policymaker. Nevertheless,
logistic and signal extraction techniques provide a computationally easy
way to predict banking crises using global and country-specific data
respectively and are thus useful tools to complement macroprudential
surveillance.
A recent development is the binary recursive tree technique, which
can be used to answer the question "which non-linear variable
interactions make an economy more vulnerable to crisis than
others?" It can be argued that liquidity, credit and market risks
are all potentially non-linear (e.g. once a threshold level of credit
risk is surpassed, a decline in GDP may have a heightened impact on the
probability of a crisis). The estimator identifies the single most
important discriminator between crisis and non-crisis episodes across
the entire sample, thereby creating two nodes. These nodes are further
split into sub-nodes based on the behaviour of splitter variables'
non-linear interactions with previous splitter variables. This generates
nodal crisis probabilities and the associated splitter threshold values.
This is an innovative approach used mainly in medical research to date.
The technique has been applied to systemic banking crises by Duttagupta
and Cashin (2008) and Davis and Karim (2008b). The key indicators found
to be most useful in these studies include real interest rates, GDP
growth, inflation and credit variables.
The limits of macroprudential oversight--an evaluation for the
subprime crisis
Davis and Karim (2008b) show that the US sub-prime crisis was only
partly foreseen by the policy community. Looking at reports from the
BIS, IMF, ECB and Bank of England they found that, although all had
important insights in their headline sections, none of the reports
highlighted the conduits and SIVs that were a key feature of the crisis.
Equally, none foresaw the collapse of the interbank market or the
overall magnitude of the effects from the sub-prime crisis alone. None
considered possible links from financial instability to the real economy
on the scale seen in 2008-9.
Davis and Karim argued that the BIS had the most forward looking
analysis of events and possible policy responses, reflecting its
longer-term concern over the build-up of debt, risks in structured
products and rising asset prices. Even they failed to see some of the
consequences of the crisis, notably the seizing up of interbank markets.
They also saw limits in the use of macroprudential tools. Among
global early warning systems calibrated for the US and UK, the logit
performed best but was still only marginally able to help predict the
crisis (although the BRT model had a higher average crisis prediction
score). These results to some extent show that the subprime crisis had
specific features that were not typical of the average banking crisis in
both advanced and emerging economies. However, their contention was
that, rather than rejecting such models, the results show they should be
better adapted for the specific features of advanced countries, that may
also include aspects of securities market instability.
As noted, progress on this in Barrell, Davis, Karim and Liadze
(2009) estimating logit models shows indeed that there are different
determinants of OECD crises from EMEs, namely bank capital, bank
liquidity and house price growth. This model was able to predict the
crisis for a number of countries, albeit not the US itself. Equally,
they maintain that a generic features checklist would also be useful
complement for such analysis. Nevertheless, it is important to
acknowledge the ongoing limitations of knowledge and ability to predict
crises using macroprudential surveillance tools. Hence qualitative
analysis and judgement remain essential to such surveillance.
4. Policy issues--making macroprudential regulation operational
The broad issue
The initial two policy objectives of macroprudential regulation are
early identification of potential vulnerabilities and, through their
public reporting, to encourage financial institutions to do stress
testing. And these can be achieved by the surveillance highlighted
above. The more difficult policy decision is what to do if there are
macroprudential warnings, given the third objective is to promote
preventative and remedial policies to prevent financial instability.
Surveillance should also help to resolve instabilities (crisis
resolution), when preventative and remedial measures fail, but this is
not the desirable scenario.
Moral suasion and intensified supervision are obvious preventative
measures but may not be sufficient. Or equally, the question arises
whether monetary policy can deal with asset price bubbles--many central
bankers seem to oppose the idea that monetary policy should aim to
deflate nascent bubbles, arguing that the interest rate is best devoted
to control of general price inflation. Bank of England (2009), for
example, argues that both the real economy and inflation expectations
could have been destabilised by a policy tightening in response to the
credit/asset price bubble of 2003-7, while the required tightening is
itself hard to calibrate given shifting risk premia. Rather, both theory
and experience suggest there is a need for variation or adjustment in
prudential parameters, which we explore in this section.
Bear in mind that the whole rationale of macroprudential regulation
is that relying on individual bank supervision at a micro level is
necessary but not sufficient for financial stability. Clearly higher
capital adequacy makes banks individually less vulnerable to failure,
but equally, the past decade has also shown the adverse incentive
effects of capital adequacy. These include maximising risk in the
buckets, setting up avenues of disintermediation via subsidiaries, and
also banks skimping liquidity protection. More recently, opportunities
for regulatory arbitrage have created incentives for managers to avoid
holding risk-weighted capital off-balance sheet by selling 364-day
commercial paper. The procyclicality of the financial system, which is
already apparent with Basel 1, seems set to worsen with Basel 2
(Goodhart, 2005). For example Basel 2 prompts banks to seek to sell
assets in a recession due to rating downgrades and higher capital
charges. This not only can become cumulative but also worsens borrower
solvency further and may spread credit rationing to other markets
(Warwick Commission, 2009). Even lacking such regulation, in trying to
make themselves safer, for example selling an asset when the price of
risk rises, banks may collectively act in a way that generates systemic
risk.
It is widely argued that the most desirable means of preventing
financial crises is to implement standards which automatically act to
prevent 'financial fragility' from arising. One part of this
will be tightened microprudential standards on which the Basel Committee
is already working, (28) but another is macroprudential surveillance, as
discussed below. There remains the further issue of how to link
macroprudential and microprudential regulation more effectively (Barrell
and Davis, 2008). One aspect is the appropriate design of a
countercyclical regulatory framework (the time series dimension). It
also includes increasing risk weights for risks that are common across
institutions rather than idiosyncratic, or which can spillover from core
institutions (the cross section dimension). It is vital that regulation
of both types remains effective in the sense of ensuring that risky
activities do not migrate either internationally or to less-regulated
financial institutions such as hedge funds (Goodhart, 2008). The
structure of regulation more broadly may need to be reconsidered.
Countercyclical regulation
As noted, there is an ongoing debate about whether Basel 2 has been
made the financial system more or less procyclical. Through-the-cycle
ratings should tend to dampen the procyclical forces previously at work
(Bank of England, 2009). The requirement for stress testing for a
downturn under Pillar 2 should act also against procyclicality by making
banks consider the range of risks that can occur during a cycle or even
a long period of time. Tougher liquidity standards being introduced
since the crisis will help to reduce procyclicality, especially if they
reduce the ability for banks to expand balance sheets rapidly using
wholesale funding rather than solely raising the volume of liquid
assets. However, the increased use of marking-to-market and banks'
own assessment of risk may lead banks hit by falling credit quality to
raise capital or contract balance sheets in downturns (since raising
capital is difficult in such conditions) and thereby exacerbate the
underlying weakness (Goodhart, 2005).
There is limited international experience with operation of
regulatory standards that act against credit and asset-price cycles, for
example by increasing minimum capital ratios to dampen lending growth,
ensuring banks have buffers to draw on in the downturn. Dynamic
provisioning, as in Spain, is a rule requiring banks to build up general
loss reserves in good times consistent with the long-run average default
performance of the relevant loans, to cope with losses in bad times
(Fernandez de Lis and Herrero, 2009). In other countries, including the
UK, by contrast, banks did not build up extra provisions in the upturn;
the UK nonperforming loans/total loan ratio fell from 2.5 per cent in
2003 to 1 per cent in 2006, while the ratio of provisions to
non-performing loans fell from 70 per cent to 54.6 per cent. Potential
conflicts with tax rules and with accounting standards would need to be
addressed if the Spanish approach is to be implemented elsewhere.
Equally, it should be noted that Spain did not avoid a credit boom,
rather, its banks were better able to withstand the eventual downturn.
Furthermore, the dynamic provisioning regime only applies to the
'banking book' and not the 'trading book' exposures
which have also been a cause for concern.
A number of other national authorities are considering explicit
countercyclical regulation (Bank of England, 2008, 2009). These could
include an overall leverage ratio of capital to unadjusted (rather than
risk-weighted) assets. This limits the scope under Basel 2 arrangements
for banks to assess their own risk by providing a one-size-fits-all
ceiling. It may also be helpful in making regulation more transparent,
although it is essential that the ceiling applies to all relevant assets
and does not encourage banks to use off-balance sheet structures to
escape the ceiling.
Time varying capital requirements related to lending growth are
also under consideration, alongside the purchase of catastrophe capital
insurance (Kashyap et al., 2008). Goodhart (2005) suggests relating the
capital requirement on bank lending to the rate of change of asset
prices, while another alternative is to limit individual bank asset
growth to a rate consistent with an inflation target (Warwick
Commission, 2009). Bank of England (2009) recommends a capital surcharge
for all banks linked to estimates of aggregate credit risk derived from
macroprudential surveillance and related stress tests, or on sectoral
lending exposures in a similar manner. They note that similar changes
could be applied to underpriced liquidity risk (e.g. of rollover or
market liquidity).
Bank balance sheet based countercyclical regulation could be
complemented by regulation of remuneration with the same effect. For
example, supervisors could encourage risk adjustment remuneration to
managers and traders that is based on long-term or realised return and
not short-term book profit (FSA, 2009).
Time-series macroprudential regulation could be based either on
rules or discretion. In general, such countercyclical policies based on
discretion may risk being ineffective as the authorities can easily
share the same excessive optimism as the private sector about future
prospects and risks (disaster myopia). In addition, authorities may face
political pressures if they try to contain the expansionary phase of a
credit cycle, particularly from the financial industry. Regulatory
capture is a risk in this context also. Decision-making would be less
predictable, leading to banks holding higher precautionary buffers, or
at least to react less to policy anticipations.
A rules-based approach to procyclicality, although blunter, would
have the benefit of being transparent. One possible approach is to use
credit growth and asset prices as inputs to such a rule (Borio and
Drehmann, 2009); the Spanish approach to dynamic provisioning itself is
a rules-based approach based on balance sheet growth in excess of
long-term averages. It would be important that such an approach does not
limit the important role of banks' risk management in ensuring the
stability of the financial system. Furthermore, the standard should
ideally not only reduce risk appetite at the peak of the boom but also
ameliorate the credit crunch in the downturn.
Bank of England (2009) argues discretion is necessary to allow
adaptability in the case of structural change or uncertainty, as well as
permitting judgement. They contend that constraints could be built in to
discretion via, for example, setting out details of the process and
analysis underlying decision-making, as well as parliamentary scrutiny
and a fixed timetable.
Borio (2009) notes also that capital adequacy or even banking
regulation generally are only one aspect of the procyclicality problem.
Fair value accounting, for example, increased procyclicality in the
sub-prime crisis. Monetary and fiscal policy as well as the nature of
the safety net may also give rise to incentives. For example, changes in
interest relief on real estate loans may provoke instability as in
Sweden prior to the 1991 crisis. Equally, generous deposit insurance was
a key background for the US Savings and Loans crisis. Hence there is a
need for a holistic approach to the problem.
Cross-sectional regulation
As mentioned, a second aspect of macroprudential regulation is to
allow for cross-sectional risks. A key aspect of this is that not all
institutions give rise to similar systemic risks. Some may be of
particular importance for being large, highly connected with other
institutions and/or with a high propensity for fire sales of assets that
would affect other firms' balance sheets. Such core institutions
are most likely to be judged too big to fail. Developing indicators,
stress tests and models to measure such systemic importance is a key
ongoing task, a good example of which is the Austrian model of interbank
links (Elsinger et al., 2006). However, data for constructing such
models are absent in many countries.
Regulation may then need to impose closer regulation and possibly
higher capital requirements on systemically important institutions (i.e.
those giving rise to high system-wide losses should they fail). Such
capital requirements would also give an incentive to reduce balance
sheet size and interconnections, as well as to develop so-called living
wills which facilitate orderly wind down. It could be complemented by a
shift from 'process driven regulation' which rewards large
banks that are best able to construct credit risk models and systems, to
'results driven regulation' that would be based on better risk
management and would be more size neutral. Penalising large firms (and
other policies such as transactions taxes) would reduce the risk of
regulatory capture and some contend would limit the damage the sector
could inflict on the wider economy (Warwick Commission, 2009). We note
that this is an empirical question which is not resolved at present.
While fiscal losses may indeed link to the size of the financial sector,
wider economic damage can arise from cross-border lending unrelated to
the size of the domestic sector, as in the 1997 Asian crisis and many
other Emerging Market crises.
The fact that many interconnected institutions are cross-border in
nature gives an additional difficulty to their regulation, especially as
the Lehman's failure showed that such firms are 'global in
life but national in death'. As suggested by IMF (2009), this
requires agreement by home and host supervisors that such institutions
act as subsidiaries in local markets where they are systemic in size.
Quite apart from tightly regulating large and interconnected
institutions, the cross-section approach may entail higher capital
charges on behaviour that is typically common across banks relative to
that which is idiosyncratic, even if the risks from the individual
institutions are the same. A focus is needed, in other words, on areas
where banks are susceptible to herding behaviour. So for example there
could be tougher controls on lending to finance real estate, a major
component of collective losses as asset prices fall. (29) These could
include limits to loan-to-value (LTV) ratios for property loans or
restrictions on income gearing.
Also affecting cross-section risk is the degree of bank reliance on
wholesale funds, which have been seen to dry up simultaneously for all
institutions. This could be discouraged by raising capital requirements
for banks that have high wholesale funding ratios, or against the
mismatch in maturity of assets and liabilities, adjusted for liquidity
(e.g. a discount on assets acceptable as collateral by the central
bank), (Brunnermeier et al., 2009). Further benefits in reducing
cross-section risk could be gained by having large liability limits
related to the size of the exposure to the debtor (as opposed to the
creditor in large exposure), structural policies for central
counterparties in liquid markets and separate capitalisation of
different geographical parts of a cross-border firm. More detailed
policies which enforce capital requirements linked to degree of maturity
mismatch could be envisaged (Warwick Commission, 2009). These would
encourage institutional investors rather than banks to hold liquidity
risks--and the opposite for credit risks--that would make the system
more resilient because it allocates risks to those better able to hedge
them.
As argued in Barrell and Davis (2008), macroprudential problems are
actually threefold--bad lending leading to losses giving rise to
liquidity problems, excessive reliance on wholesale markets and complex
instruments leading to confusion. Given the uncertainty problem with
lack of experience of behaviour in downturns, there is a need for
further regulation of complex instruments or an increase in capital held
against them. For if they fail when tested, as have the majority of
asset backed security innovations of the past decade, they can cause
huge damage. Possibly this could be in the form of higher capital
charges until a recession has taken place. Or more radically, there
could be a need to justify innovations before they can be introduced, as
is the case for drug testing.
Changes in the structure of regulation
The boundary problem in regulation arises for all of the above
issues. The basic point, as set out in Goodhart (2008) is to ensure that
regulation which is effective does not merely lead to substitution flows
towards the unregulated sector. He suggests a resolution could be to
ensure that regulation only is effective occasionally, i.e. during the
height of a credit/asset price driven boom. There is also a need for
vigilance by regulators to ensure banks do not set up subsidiaries (e.g.
SIVs) outside the regulatory net for which they are sufficiently
reputationally connected to not allow them to fail. Bank of England
(2009) suggests that the boundary problem could be countered by tight
controls on bank exposures to non-banks or coverage of 'all'
institutions. On the other hand they note that international leakages
would arise for a macroprudential regime, for example due to lending by
foreign branches or direct cross-border lending into the country that is
not subject to the macroprudential capital charges. Coordination among
international regulators may accordingly be needed, as well as a move
from branch to subsidiary-based operation by foreign banks (see also
FSA, 2009, and Warwick Commission, 2009).
Barrell and Davis (2008) argue that one key root cause of the
crisis has been the decision in the 1980s and 1990s to move away from
structural regulation (e.g. limits on competition, prices and scope of
activities for financial institutions) to an almost sole concern with
the efficiency of the financial system. Both should be of concern to
regulators, and the costs and benefits of both should have been
balanced. Efficient financial markets increase welfare, reduce risk
premia and raise sustainable output. However, they also have a tendency
to produce products that become widely adopted before they are stress
tested in a recession, as discussed above, and also unsustainable levels
of competition. Further prudential tightening and even some direct
controls on bank activities may be needed.
The Obama administration in the United States announced on 21
January 2010 a proposal to limit certain activities by commercial banks
deemed as risky and inappropriately covered by deposit insurance and
access to the discount window. These are proprietary trading of
securities, ownership of hedge funds and of internal private equity
funds. A further aim is to reduce the size of institutions directly,
possibly by limiting market share of non-deposit funding. Some
commentators have seen parallels with the Glass-Steagall regulation in
the 1930s which separated commercial from investment banking and was
only abolished in 1999. In the UK City Minister Lord Myners said the US
proposals were "very much in accordance with the direction we have
been setting", while the UK Conservative Party has declared an
interest in introducing similar legislation, should it win this
year's election. Whereas the Obama proposals may not pass Congress
in their current form, it remains appropriate to evaluate them in the
context of this article as a radical form of structural regulation that
would seek to reduce cross-sectional risks from large and risky
institutions as set out above. Accordingly, a key aim of the legislation
is that commercial banks should be forced to downsize so they do not
become "too big to fail" and subject to moral hazard at
taxpayers' expense, as well as reducing the risk on their balance
sheets, which should reduce the probability of failure. There could well
be benefits from such an approach.
On the other hand, it is not clear that the specific elements
targeted by the legislation were actually the principal causes of the
Sub-Prime crisis. These were more directly linked to excessive
investment by banks in overpriced structured products (Collateralised
Debt Obligations) in off balance sheet subsidiaries, together with
inadequate capital and liquidity to cover risks being incurred, and a
lack of focus on macroprudential risks by market participants and
regulators. Hence, it is essential that such rules should be
supplemented by tighter microprudential and macroprudential regulation
as set out above. Equally, potential costs such as lesser liquidity of
securities markets if proprietary trading and activity of hedge funds
are restricted, as well as weaker corporate governance if private equity
is restrained, should be taken into account. Further issues are whether
pure investment banks would be allowed to operate outside the regulation
if they renounce banking status, and whether authorities outside the US
and UK would fail to adopt similar measures. These would weaken the
global benefits of the proposal and lead to major regulatory arbitrage.
As recommended by Weale (2008), it would be of major benefit if new
prudential regulations could be self-enforcing. For example, if there
are limits on LTV, banks have an incentive to exceed them to gain
custom. However, if the national register of land titles (known as the
Land Registry in the UK) refuses to register mortgages with LTVs over
the limit, then there would be incentive to comply. Or, alternatively,
as in Germany, a limit on LTVs for mortgages eligible to be securitised
would be self-reinforcing (the limit in Germany is 80 per cent). Again,
a tax on credit, if such were considered helpful for macroprudential
purposes, would be self-enforcing if creditors have to show it has been
collected before they can enforce debts.
Geographically, it can be argued that European-wide financial
markets need a single regulatory structure that ensures the solvency as
well as the liquidity of all financial institutions in the European
Economic Area. Macroprudential regulation raises important home/host
issues since, if there is most leverage for the home supervisor, the
scope to take host country macroprudential issues into account will be
limited. Arguably the macroprudential approach calls for host country
supervision to have precedence, which could be enforced by the right of
host authorities to insist on subsidiarisation of branches (Warwick
Commission, 2009).
In this context, a key issue is whether new institutions are
needed, as proposed in the EU and US, to detect macroprudential risks?
Some doubt is justified, in our view, since they may lack both
credibility and leverage over the supervisors and central banks who will
take the relevant decisions. Financial stability reports from such
institutions may thus be disregarded even more readily than those
produced by existing institutions.
More appropriate may be close attention to the development of
macroprudential regulation between the central bank and regulator (if
they are separate) or within the central bank. It can be argued that
regulators outside the central bank are often less focussed on
macroprudential issues than the central bank themselves. One reason may
be greater focus on depositor and investor protection, which leads to a
concentration on individual institutions. Another is that the central
bank is more likely to have to deal with the initial consequences of
systemic risk via the lender of last resort facility. Hence a
rebalancing of responsibilities may be appropriate to ensure sufficient
macroprudential focus.
In the UK for example, under the Banking Reform Act, the Bank of
England has a legal objective "to contribute to protecting and
enhancing the stability of the financial systems of the United
Kingdom" (see Davis, 2009b). The Act formalises the Bank's
role in supervision of payments systems. A Financial Stability Committee
is being set up within the Bank to deal with this objective, reporting
to the Governor (HM Treasury, 2008). An important innovation under the
Act is that the Bank is to be able to request data from banks through
the FSA, whereas at present the FSA can only collect data it needs
itself. Furthermore, these arrangements provide the basis for the Bank
to have a much more detailed understanding of developments in the
banking system.
Conclusion
The past decade has seen an unprecedented focus on financial
instability, its nature and its early detection. Whereas this is clear
progress compared to the blind manner in which many countries
encountered financial instability in the late 1980s, there is still a
long way to go. This was illustrated by the failure of Financial
Stability Reviews (e.g. of the UK, ECB and the IMF) to detect the
liquidity aspect of the Sub-Prime crisis, even though they did give
warnings of the credit risk issues arising. (See Banque de France (2008)
for an assessment of liquidity issues in the wake of the sub-prime
crisis.) Also, the crisis has shown a rich array of adverse incentive
effects on risk taking, often arising from regulation. It is suggested
that the role of incentives is an emerging issue which warrants close
focus (Chai and Johnston, 2000, gave an early approach to it). And even
if vulnerability had been detected, experience has also shown that the
means by which authorities can address macroprudential concerns are
limited. Hence the need for a wider range of macroprudential tools and
particularly those that will tend to limit ex ante the scope of systemic
risk, in time-series and cross-sectional terms.
REFERENCES
Acharya, V. and Richardson, M. (2009), 'Causes of the
financial crisis', Critical Review, 21, pp. 195-210.
Adrian, T. and Shin, H.S. (2008), 'Liquidity and financial
contagion', in Banque de France Financial Stability Review: Special
Issue on Liquidity, No. 11, pp. 1-7.
Allen, F. (2005), 'Modelling financial instability',
National Institute Economic Review, 192, April.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (2000), 'Bubbles and crises',
Economic Journal, 110, pp. 236-55.
Aspachs, O., Goodhart, C.A.E., Tsomocos, D.P. and Zicchino, L.
(2007), 'Towards a measure of financial fragility', Annals of
Finance, 3, pp. 37-74.
Bank of England (2008), Financial Stability Report, October 2008,
London, Bank of England.
--(2009), 'The role of macroprudential policy, a discussion
paper', November, London, Bank of England.
Banque de France (2008), Financial Stability Review, Special Issue
on Liquidity, Paris, Banque de France.
Barrell, R. and Davis, E.P. (2008), 'The evolution of the
financial market crisis in 2008', National Institute Economic
Review, 206, pp. 5-14.
Barrell, R., Davis, E.P., Fic, T., Holland, D., Kirby, S. and
Liadze, I. (2009), 'Optimal regulation of bank capital and
liquidity: how to calibrate new international standards', FSA
Occasional Paper No 38.
Barrell, R., Davis, E.P., Karim, D. and Liadze, I. (2009),
'Bank regulation, property prices and early warning systems for
banking crises in OECD countries', National Institute Discussion
Paper No. 330, and Journal of Banking and Finance (forthcoming).
--(2010), 'Contagious effects of banking crises in OECD
countries', NIESR, mimeo.
Benninga, S. and Weiner, Z. (1998), 'Value at risk
(VaR)', Mathematica in Education and Research, 7, 4, pp. 39-45.
Bernard, H. and Bisignano, J. (2000), 'Information, liquidity
and risk in the international interbank market: implicit guarantees and
private credit market failure', BIS Working Paper No. 86.
BIS (2000), Stress Testing by Large Financial Institutions: Current
Practice and Aggregation Issues, Committee on the Global Financial
System, Switzerland, Bank for International Settlements.
--(2001), A Survey of Stress Tests and Current Practice at Major
Financial Institutions, Report by a Task Force Established by the
Committee on the Global Financial System of the Central Banks of the G10
Countries. BIS Publications, Switzerland, Bank for International
Settlements.
Borio, C. (2009), 'The macroprudential approach to regulation
and supervision, What? How Why?', presentation to the Banque de
France and Toulouse School of Economics Conference on the Future of
Financial Regulation, 28 January.
Borio, C. and Drehmann, M. (2009), 'Assessing the risk of
banking crises--revisited', BIS Quarterly Review, March, pp. 29-46.
Brooks, C. and Katsaris, A. (2003), 'Rational speculative
bubbles: an empirical investigation of the London Stock Exchange',
Bulletin of Economic Research, 55, pp. 319-46.
Brunnermeier, M. (2009), 'Deciphering the 2007/8 Liquidity and
Credit crunch', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23, pp. 77-100.
Brunnermeier, M., Crockett, A., Goodhart, C., Persaud, A.D. and
Shin, H. (2009), 'The fundamental principles of financial
regulation', Geneva Reports on the World Economy II, International
Center for Monetary and Banking Studies and Centre for Economic Policy
Research
Calomiris, C.W. and Mason, J.R. (2000), 'Causes of U.S. bank
distress during the depression', NBER Working Papers 7919, National
Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Chai, J. and Johnston, R.B. (2000), 'An incentive approach to
identifying financial system vulnerabilities', IMF Working paper No
WP/00/211.
Chan-Lau, J.A. (2006), 'Market-based estimation of default
probabilities and its application to financial surveillance',
International Monetary Fund Working Paper 06/104, Washington, DC, IMF.
Chan-Lau, J.A. and Sy, A.N.R.(2007), 'Distance-to-default in
banking: a bridge too far?', Journal of Banking Regulation, 9, I,
pp. 14-24, November.
Chen, Y. (1999), 'Banking panics: the role of the first-come,
first-served rule and information externalities', Journal of
Political Economy, 107, pp. 946-68.
Cihak, M. (2006), 'How do central banks write about financial
stability?', IMF Working Paper WP/06/163.
Crosbie, P.J. and Bohn, J.R. (2002), Modelling Credit Risk,
California, KMV LLC.
Das, U., Quintyn, M., Chenard, K. (2004), 'Does regulatory
governance matter for financial system stability?', IMF Working
Paper WP/04/89.
Davis, E.P. (1991), 'Bank credit risk', Working Paper no.
8, London, Bank of England.
--(1994), 'Market liquidity risk', in Fair, D. and
Raymond, R. (eds), The Competitiveness of Financial Institutions and
Centres in Europe, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
--(1995), Debt, Financial Fragility and Systemic Risk, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
--(1999), 'Financial data needs for macroprudential
surveillance: what are the key indicators of risk to domestic financial
stability?' Lecture Series No 2, Centre for Central Banking
Studies, Bank of England.
--(2002), 'A typology of financial instability',
Financial Stability Report, 2, Vienna, Oesterreichische Nationalbank.
--(2009a), 'The lender of last resort and liquidity provision
how much of a departure is the subprime crisis?', paper presented
at the Conference entitled 'Regulatory Response to the Financial
Crisis', London School of Economics, 19th January, and Brunel
Economics and Finance Working Paper No. 09-09.
--(2009b), 'Financial stability in the United Kingdom, banking
on prudence', OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 716.
Davis, E.P. and Karim, D. (2008a), 'Comparing early warning
systems for banking crises', Journal of Financial Stability, 4, pp.
89-120.
--(2008b), 'Could early warning systems have helped to predict
the sub-prime crisis?', National Institute Economic Review, 206,
pp. 35-47.
--(2008c), 'Research in and policy for financial
stability--what have we learnt?', Economics and Finance Working
Paper, No. 08-14, Brunel University.
De Bandt, O. and Hartmann, P. (2000), 'Systemic risk: a
survey', ECB Working Paper No. 35, European Central Bank.
Degennaro, R.P. and Thomson, J.B. (1996), 'Capital forbearance
and thrifts: examining the costs of regulatory gambling, Journal of
Financial Services Research, 10, pp. 199-211.
Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Detragiache, E. (2005), 'Cross-country
empirical studies of systemic bank distress: a survey', IMF Working
Papers 05/96, International Monetary Fund.
--(1997), 'The determinants of banking crises--evidence from
developing and developed countries', IMF Working Papers 97/106,
International Monetary Fund.
Diamond, D.W. and Dybvig, P.H. (1983), 'Bank runs, deposit
insurance, and liquidity', Journal of Political Economy, 9, 3, pp.
401-19.
Duttagupta, R. and Cashin, P. (2008), 'The anatomy of banking
crises', IMF Working paper 08/93.
ECB (2009), EU Banking Sector Stability August 2009, Frankfurt,
European Central Bank.
Elsinger, H., Lehar, A. and Summer, M. (2006), 'Risk
assessment for banking systems', Management Science, 52, pp.
1301-14.
Evans, G.(1991), 'Pitfalls in testing for explosive bubbles in
asset prices', American Economic Review, 81, pp. 922-30.
Farhi, E. and Tirole, J. (2009), 'Collective moral hazard,
maturity mismatch and systemic bailouts', NBER Working Paper, No.
15138.
Fell, J. and Schinasi, G. (2005), 'Assessing financial
stability--exploring the boundaries of analysis', National
Institute Economic Review, 192, pp. 70-85.
Fernandez de Lis, S. and Herrero, A. (2009), 'The Spanish
approach: dynamic provisioning and other tools', in Mayes, D.,
Pringle, R. and Taylor, M. (eds), Towards a New Framework for Financial
Stability, Central Banking Publications.
Freixas, X. and Parigi, B. (1998), 'Contagion and efficiency
in gross and net interbank payment systems', Journal of Financial
Intermediation, 7, pp. 3-31.
Freixas, X., Parigi, B. and Rochet, J.-C. (2000), 'Systemic
risk, interbank relations and liquidity provision by the central
bank', Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32, pp. 611-38.
FSA (2009), The Turner Review. A Regulatory Response to the Global
Financial Crisis, March, London.
Goodhart, C. (2005), 'Financial regulation, credit risk and
financial stability', National Institute Economic Review, 192, pp.
70-79.
--(2008), 'The boundary problem in financial regulation',
National Institute Economic Review, no. 206, January, pp. 48-55.
Goodhart, C., Sunirand, P. and Tsomocos, D. (2006), 'A model
to analyse financial fragility', Economic Theory, Springer, 27, pp.
107-42.
HM Treasury (2008), Financial Stability and Depositor Protection:
Strengthening the Framework, January, London, HM Treasury.
Hoggarth, G. and Sapporta, V. (2001), 'Costs of banking system
instability, some empirical evidence', Financial Stability Review,
Summer, Bank of England.
IMF (2009), Global Financial Stability Report October
2009--Navigating the Financial Challenges Ahead, Washington DC,
International Monetary Fund.
Jayanti, S. and Whyte, A. (1996), 'Global contagion effects of
the continental Illinois failure', Journal of International
Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 6, pp. 87-99.
Kaminsky, L.G. and Reinhart, C.M. (1999), 'The twin crises;
the causes of banking and balance-of-payments problems', American
Economic Review, 89, pp. 473-500.
Kane, E. (1992), 'Corporate capital and government
guarantees', Journal of Financial Services Research, 5, pp. 357-68.
Kashyap, A., Rajan, B. and Stein, J. (2008), 'Rethinking
capital regulation', paper presented at the Kansas Fed Symposium at
Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August.
Kindleberger, C.P. (I 978), Manias, Panics and Crashes, A History
of Financial Crises, New York, Basic Books.
Knight, F.H. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Boston, No. 16
in a series of rare texts in economics, republished by the LSE.
Kocherlakota, N. and Shim, I. (2006), 'Forbearance and prompt
corrective action', BIS Working Paper No. 177, Bank of
International Settlements.
Mayes, D., Pringle, R. and Taylor, M. (eds) (2009), Towards a New
Framework for Financial Stability, London, Central Banking Publications.
Minsky, H.P. (1977), 'A theory of systemic fragility' in
Altman, E.I. and Sametz, A.W. (eds), Financial Crises, New York, Wiley.
Raymond Feingold, H. (2001)', Preventing crisis by testing for
bubbles: a comparative study of the financial fragility of Europe
relative to the USA and Japan', EFMA 2001 Lugano Meetings, European
Financial Management Association.
Santor, E. (2003), 'Banking crises and contagion: empirical
evidence', Working Papers 03-1, Bank of Canada.
Shin, H.S. (2008), 'Risk and liquidity in a system
context', Journal of Financial Intermediation, 17, pp. 315-29.
Warwick Commission (2009), The Warwick Commission on International
Financial Reform, in Praise of Unlevel Playing Fields, Warwick
University.
Weale, M. (2008), 'Commentary: the banking crisis and the
economy', National Institute Economic Review, 204, April, p.7.
NOTES
(1) Financial crises, and notably banking crises, were infrequent
during the Bretton Woods period of fixed exchange rates and exchange
controls from the Second World War till the early 1970s. However, this
was an historic anomaly, as witness the high frequency of crises in the
interwar and pre-First World War periods.
(2) See Barrell et al. (2009) for an estimate of costs and benefits
of tighter capital and liquidity regulation in the UK.
(3) Especially when such growth is focussed on securities and/or
there is mark-to-market accounting.
(4) They may, however, lead to resource misallocation and an
increased cost of capital, with deflationary macroeconomic implications.
(5) It is not denied that all sharp asset price changes will tend
to affect market liquidity to a greater or lesser degree.
(6) This suggests that financial crises follow a credit cycle with
an initial positive shock (displacement) provoking rising debt,
mispricing of risk by lenders and an asset bubble, which is punctured by
a negative shock, leading to a banking crisis.
(7) As opposed to risk (in the sense of Knight, 1921), seen as a
key feature of financial instability, in that unlike the cycle, one
cannot apply probability analysis to rare and uncertain events such as
financial crises and policy regime shifts and hence price them
correctly. Innovations are by definition subject to such uncertainty as
probabilities are not yet known over the full cycle.
(8) This suggests that competitive, incentive-based and
psychological mechanisms in the presence of uncertainty lead financial
institutions and regulators to underestimate the risk of financial
instability, accepting concentrated risks at low capital ratios.
(9) The underlying model which also incorporates contagion via
overlapping claims in inter-bank markets, is detailed in Allen and Gale
(2000).
(10) At worst the manager loses her job and possibly reputation.
Allen (2005) suggests that if default is not penalised and if reputation
risk is low, the manager improves her expected return by gambling
depositors' funds.
(11) Repayable at the borrowing rate.
(12) A fundamental asset price is simply its payoff discounted by
the investor's opportunity cost of her own funds.
(13) This is motivated by the 'first come, first served'
process of depositor reimbursement.
(14) Weights are 2005 GDP weights.
(15) Presence of externalities means shocks are amplified
symmetrically; a positive shock generates positive externalities and
bank balance sheets benefit from asset price booms.
(16) Kane (I 992) defines forbearance towards low banking capital
as a situation where "Deposit-institution regulators engage in
capital forbearance when they lower standards for minimum net worth at
de-capitalised institutions", (page 359). Prompt Corrective Action necessitates immediate termination of critically undercapitalised banks
via asset liquidation (Kocherlakota and Shim, 2006).
(17) One way banks did this was by removing assets off the balance
sheet by holding asset backed securities in SIVs and conduits, for which
banks then guaranteed the asset backed commercial paper financing. The
other was holding other banks' AAA ABS tranches on balance sheet.
(18) Consider a phase of vulnerability with growing leverage and
mismatch in funding. Looking at individual firms may miss the
system-wide credit and liquidity risks since they depend on aggregate
lending conditions, other banks' reliance on the same funding
source or diversifying in the same manner. There can also be funding
chains whereby banks lend at nearly-matched maturities but the system as
a whole has a major maturity mismatch.
(19) For a practical guide onto DtD, see Crosbie and Bohn (2002).
(20) Standard deviation of the annual percentage change in asset
value.
(21) See for example ECB (2009), pages 27-28.
(22) Credit default swaps, corporate or sovereign bonds.
(23) Hence this market risk measure is backward looking.
(24) E.g. parallel yield curve shifts.
(25) See part 2, third section.
(26) 105 countries are covered by data spanning 1979-2003 which
yields 72 or 102 systemic banking crises depending on the crisis
definition used.
(27) Such as credit growth, M21FX reserves ratio, the fiscal
balance, GDP growth, real interest rates and inflation.
(28) Besides higher capital per se, proposals include improved
quality of capital, a leverage ratio to complement risk-adjusted capital
adequacy, as well as better quality capital, an international liquidity
standard and proposals to improve risk capture of capital across trading
as well as banking books.
(29) Even for an individual institution, commercial property
lending is risky at an individual level and losses are most highly
correlated with aggregate losses by banks (Davis, 1991).
E. Philip Davis * and Dilruba Karim **
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research and Brunel
University; e-mail:
[email protected]. ** Brunel University;
e-mail:
[email protected]. Parts of this paper are derived from
Davis and Karim (2008c) which also appeared in Mayes et al. (2009). An
earlier version was keynote address at the 6th Euroframe Conference on
Economic Policy Issues in the European Union, 12 June 2009, entitled
'Causes and consequences of the current financial crisis, what
lessons for EU countries?' The authors thank participants in the
Euroframe Conference and at a seminar at HM Treasury in October 2009 for
helpful comments.
Table 1. Generic features of financial instability
Phase of crisis Nature Example of features
Primary Diverse Deregulation, monetary or
(favourable) fiscal easing, productive
shock innovation, change in market
sentiment.
Propagation-- Common--main New entry to financial
build-up of subject of markets, debt accumulation,
vulnerability macroprudential asset price booms, innovation
surveillance. in financial markets,
underpricing of risk, risk
concentration and lower
capital adequacy for banks,
unsustainable macro policy.
Secondary Diverse Monetary, fiscal or regulatory
(adverse) shock tightening, asymmetric trade
shock.
Propagation-- Common Failure of institution or
crisis market leading to failure of
others via direct links or
uncertainty in presence of
asymmetric information--or
generalised failure due to
common shock.
Policy action Common--main Deposit insurance, bank
subject of recapitalisation and
crisis guarantees, lender of last
resolution. resort, general monetary and
fiscal easing.
Economic Common--scope Credit rationing and wider
consequences depends on uncertainty leading to fall in
severity and GDP, notably via investment.
policy action.