A comparison of labour market responses to the global downturn.
Holland, Dawn ; Kirby, Simon ; Whitworth, Rachel 等
The global economic downturn has led to a crisis in labour markets,
with an estimated 15.2 million job losses across the OECD economies,
equivalent to a rise in the OECD unemployment rate from 5.5 to 8.9 per
cent. Initially, the rise in unemployment appeared lower than expected.
In Holland, Kirby and Whitworth (2009) we demonstrated a simple rule of
thumb between output growth and the unemployment rate in the OECD as a
whole, based on Okun's approach. Using a dataset that spans the
period 1988-2008, regression analysis suggests that on average a 1 per
cent decline in output is associated with a rise of 0.6 percentage
points in the unemployment rate across the OECD economies. Between the
first quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009, output in the OECD
economies declined by 4.8 per cent. The unemployment rate rose by 1.9
points over this period, as compared to 2.9 per cent given by the rule
of thumb. However, the labour market tends to lag production. While most
of the major economies started to grow again in the second or third
quarters of 2009, OECD unemployment continued to rise into the final
quarter of the year, with a cumulative increase in the OECD unemployment
rate of 3.4 percentage points--even higher than that suggested by our
rule of thumb.
The peak in the OECD unemployment rate may already be behind us, as
unemployment rates have stabilised in Canada, Germany, Hungary and
Finland and even started to decline in Japan. This note delves more
deeply into the response of OECD labour markets to the global economic
downturn. While at the aggregate OECD level labour input has declined
more or less in line with expectations given the decline in output, we
have seen stark differences in the labour market responses of individual
economies. We will highlight some of these key differences and identify
those countries where labour market prospects are expected to continue
to deteriorate this year.
Figure 1 illustrates the cumulative output loss between the first
quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009 against the rise in the
unemployment rate to the end of 2009 in a selection of OECD economies.
Countries that lie below the OECD regression line, such as Germany,
Japan and Italy, have exhibited a relatively small rise in the
unemployment rate given their output loss, whereas those that lie above
the regression line estimated by Holland, Kirby and Whitworth (2009)
have exhibited a greater rise in unemployment than expected. Notably,
Spain, Ireland and the US have all experienced what might be considered
excessive increases in unemployment given their output declines.
The unemployment rate measures the proportion of the labour force
that is not currently in work, and a rise in the unemployment rate can
either indicate job losses, or it can reflect new entrants into the
labour force who have yet to find employment. The two have very
different implications for the productive capacity of the economy. While
the unemployment rate is a useful indicator of wage pressures in the
economy, a more direct measure of labour input can give deeper insight
into the implications for production. Total labour input is given by
total employment multiplied by the average hours worked per employed
person. Any adjustment in working time has important implications for
output but will not be reflected in a change in the unemployment rate.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 2 plots the loss of output against the decline in labour
input since the start of the downturn in a selection of OECD countries.
Those countries that lie above the regression line have seen a greater
decline in labour input than expected, based on the simple rule of
thumb, while those below the regression line have seen a smaller decline
in labour input than expected. Spain, the US and Ireland all lie above
the regression line as they do in figure 1. However, it is interesting
to note that Sweden also lies above the regression line rather than
below it, the opposite of what is seen in figure 1. Another interesting
development is shown by the positions of Germany and Japan, which lie on
the regression line rather than well below the line as shown in figure
1, suggesting that labour input has declined by more than the shift in
the unemployment rate suggests.
In a downturn, firms bring in lower levels of revenue, and if they
cannot find a way to reduce costs many will go bankrupt. There are three
routes through which firms can reduce their labour costs: reducing
employment levels, reducing average hours worked per employee, and
reducing average wages. All three have no doubt been at work to varying
degrees in all the major economies. Cultural, regulatory and bargaining
differences will determine the individual country responses to some
degree. In figure 3 we decompose the change in labour input illustrated
in figure 2 into the change in employment and the change in average
hours worked. Average hours have declined by more than employment in the
US, Germany, Sweden, Japan, the UK and Australia, whereas the decline in
labour input in Spain and Finland is entirely down to a reduction of
employment. Italy, France and Australia have experienced very little in
the way of labour input loss. This is particularly surprising in the
case of Italy, where output declined by more than 6 per cent between the
first quarter of 2008 and the second quarter of 2009.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Another interesting distinction across countries is the extent to
which declines in employment reflect job losses by employees or job
losses by the self-employed. Those made redundant may become
self-employed, reducing the impact on total labour input and potential
output. At the same time, in a banking crisis we may find many small
firms and family businesses going bankrupt, leading to a reduction in
self-employment. In countries where employment protection is strong, we
may see a smaller decline in employee jobs, but sharper declines in
self-employment, which tends to have little in the way of social
protection. Where labour market regulation is relatively weak, we may be
more likely to see employee job losses. Figure 4 illustrates the change
in self-employment and the change in employees between the first quarter
of 2008 and the third quarter of 2009. Self-employment has increased in
the US, Finland, Canada and most notably France since the onset of the
downturn, partially offsetting the decline in employment. In Ireland,
the self-employed and employees have suffered about equally, whereas the
self-employed in Spain, Sweden, Japan and Italy have experienced
relatively higher rates of job losses.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Employment levels may also be maintained if employees are willing
to accept wage cuts as an alternative to layoffs. Figure 5 illustrates
average annual real wage growth in the selected group of countries
between 2000 and 2006, compared to the real wage growth observed since
the beginning of 2008 on an annualised basis. Real wage growth has been
weaker than average in France and the UK, which helps to explain why
these countries have not suffered as sharp a decline in labour input as
countries like the US and Spain, where real wage growth has soared due
to the unexpected drop in inflation. Real wages have declined sharply in
Italy, which can explain much of the resilience of employment in Italy.
Ireland has also seen a sharp slowdown in real wage growth, although
this appears to have done little to sustain employment, while the recent
rise in real wage growth in Canada and the Netherlands has not pushed up
unemployment as much as might be expected. Nonetheless, there is clearly
a relationship between recent real wage growth and the change in labour
input, with a correlation of 52 per cent.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
There are clearly stark differences in individual country labour
market responses to the global downturn. In order to determine whether
employment has declined by more or less than expected, given
country-specific developments in output, average hours worked and real
wages, we run a series of simulations using the National Institute
global econometric model, NiGEM. (1)
The response of the labour market to a decline in output will
depend to some extent on the type of shock driving the decline. For our
diagnostic shocks, we apply a rise in the investment risk premium, which
NIESR has argued has been a driving force behind the global financial
crisis (see for example Barrell, 2009). Figure 6 illustrates the
expected decline in employment in response to a 1 per cent decline in
output in the first year. (2)
Based on the estimated set of NiGEM equations, which reflect
historical dynamic developments in each country, we would expect
employment to decline by slightly more in the UK and the US, and by less
in Italy and Sweden, but in all cases employment is expected to decline
by 0.1-0.6 per cent in response to the 1 per cent decline in output.
While average hours worked per employee show some cyclical response
to the shock, the NiGEM model is structured so that the bulk of labour
input adjustment is effected through employment. In order to assess the
impact of reduced working time, we repeat the diagnostic shock, applying
a 1 per cent decline in average hours worked in each economy. Figure 7
illustrates the offset in terms of employment expected in response to a
1 per cent reduction in average hours worked. Spain and Sweden show
slightly stronger employment responses to working time than Germany and
the US. In all cases, there is some short-run decline in total labour
input associated with a decline in average hours worked.
Our final diagnostic simulation looks at the impact of real wage
developments on employment. We repeat the initial investment risk
premium shock, applying an additional shock to real wages in each
country. Figure 8 illustrates the offset in employment expected from an
additional 1 per cent decline in real wages. Employment in the US, UK
and Germany is more responsive to wages than in the other economies,
while employment in Finland is relatively insensitive to real wage
developments.
As a final step, we calibrate an expected decline in employment in
each country, based on the simulation studies and actual changes in
output, hours and real wages. The estimates are calculated as follows:
[DELTA][E.sup.e] = [[alpha].sub.1][DELTA]GDP +
[[alpha].sub.2][DELTA]H + [[alpha].sub.2][DELTA]RW
where [DELTA][E.sup.2] is the expected change in employment between
2008Q1 and 2009Q3, [DELTA]GDP is the actual change in output between
2008Q1 and 2009Q1, [DELTA]H is the actual change in average hours
between 2008Q1 and 2009Q3, [DELTA]RW is the difference between average
real wage growth 2008Q1-2009Q3 and average real wage growth 2000-2006
(as illustrated in figure 5), and [[alpha].sub.1], [[alpha].sub.2], and
[[alpha].sub.3] are the parameters illustrated in figures 6, 7 and 8,
respectively.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Figure 9 plots our estimates against the actual change in
employment. Those that lie above the line have seen a smaller
fall/larger increase in employment than expected, given actual
developments in output, average hours worked and real wages, while those
that lie below the line have seen excessive declines in employment.
Employment has declined significantly more than expected in Ireland in
particular, but also in Sweden and Spain. Employment developments in the
US, Finland, Canada, France, Italy and Australia are more or less in
line with expectations, while employment in the UK was slightly worse
than expected and employment in Germany has held up better than
expected.
Figure 9 supports the initial conclusion from our simple rule of
thumb. There has clearly been a bias towards underperforming in OECD
employment, with seven of twelve countries experiencing sharper
employment declines than expected and only three countries performing
better than expected. The unemployment rate in Germany, Japan, Finland,
Sweden, Italy and the Netherlands has risen by less than expected, given
their output declines. However, in the case of Germany and Japan, this
masks a decline in average working hours, so that the decline in total
labour input is more closely in line with expectations. Sweden's
labour input decline even appears excessive, given the decline in
output. Italy has seen very little decline in either the unemployment
rate or total labour input, and this is partly a reflection of real wage
developments, with sharp declines since the onset of the crisis. A sharp
rise in real wages in the US and Spain goes some way towards explaining
the excessive rise in unemployment observed in these countries.
In general, developments in output, average hours worked and real
wages can explain much of the country-specific labour market responses
observed since the onset of the crisis. Developments in Ireland, Spain
and Sweden clearly reflect additional factors, which may include a
structural shift out of the construction sector in Ireland and Spain.
The UK labour market has performed slightly worse than expected, and has
underperformed relative to the other G7 economies. In Germany,
employment levels have been maintained despite the sharp loss of output.
Given the relatively strong real wage growth, this must be putting firm
profits under pressure, and there is a strong possibility of a delayed
labour market response, with job losses materialising this year.
REFERENCES
Barrell, R. (2009), 'Long-term scarring from the financial
crisis', National Institute Economic Review, 210, October, pp.
36-8.
Holland, D., Kirby, S. and Whitworth, R. (2009), 'Labour
markets in recession: an international comparison', National
Institute Economic Review, 209, pp. 35-41.
NOTES
(1) For further detail on the structure of the NiGEM model, see the
discussion on pp. 17-21 and on http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk.
(2) For the purposes of this note, we assume a linear response to
the size of shock applied. While NiGEM is not strictly a linear model,
the degree of non-linearity is small and would have little impact on the
results.
Dawn Holland, Simon Kirby and Rachel Whitworth *
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research. E-mail:
[email protected],
[email protected] or
[email protected]