Real house prices in the UK.
Barrell, Ray ; Kirby, Simon ; Whitworth, Rachel 等
Introduction
The housing market plays a fundamental role in the economy, and its
functioning affects both consumer welfare and economic stability, as the
recent crisis has made clear. Research by Barrell et al. (2010) shows
that house prices are a key determinant of financial crisis
probabilities in OECD economies, and contribute significantly towards
systemic banking risk. This must lead the regulator to assess carefully
the role of the housing market in this relationship, and if necessary
impose regulatory restrictions on the market so as to ensure it
functions in a way that reflects the best interests of the economy. In
this note we look at the evolution of real house prices in the UK,
noting that they have a strong cyclical pattern, we then look at the
factors that might affect the evolution of real house prices, and we
estimate a dynamic equation describing those prices. After considering a
wide set of factors, we demonstrate that there is little role for the
supply of housing relative to the number of households. This may be
because the ratio of these two variables has been relatively constant
over the past thirty years. We show that real borrowing costs, real
incomes and the loan-to-income ratio are significant factors determining
the long-run path of real house prices, and that front loading problems
from high short-term nominal interest rates affect the path of
adjustment. Overvaluations can persist for years, and we would judge
that real house prices are currently fundamentally overvalued by around
10 per cent. If loan-to-income ratios are reduced then the fundamental
overvaluation will increase, and such a policy will put further downward
pressure on real house prices.
House prices in the UK
Figure 1 illustrates real house prices since 1964, using a
seasonally-adjusted version of the Department for Communities and Local
Government (DCLG) mix-adjusted house price index (deflated using the
National Accounts consumption expenditure deflator). The series has
clearly been following an upward trajectory throughout the period
illustrated, and this trajectory has steepened notably since the start
of 1996 but has seen a steep correction following the crisis. House
prices have fluctuated a great deal around what might be described as an
upward trend.
One possible explanation for much of these dynamics could be
movements in the general rate of inflation of all goods and assets
prices, which is used in the calculation of real house prices. Figure 2
plots the quarterly annualised percentage change in real and nominal
house prices and the consumer expenditure deflator separately.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The chart illustrates that, historically, spikes in the growth
rates of real and nominal house prices have been followed by periods of
readjustment, often necessitating declining real house prices for
several years. The most notable readjustment took place following the
1973 oil price shock which induced a period of high inflation and
negative real interest rates. However, in the recent period (aside from
the crisis) real house prices have tracked nominal prices more closely
and the volatile dynamics seen in the history of both series have been
replaced by a period of more persistent and accelerating growth. Over
this more recent phase, inflation has been markedly lower and more
stable than previously; the Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation rate
has largely remained in the region around the 2 per cent target
following the independence of the central bank in 1997. This reveals
that in the presence of nominal rigidity; high inflation is needed to
induce a readjustment in real house prices, and it is therefore more
difficult to achieve an adjustment to equilibrium in periods of low
inflation. The remit of the Bank of England is to keep the rate of
inflation at the 2 per cent target rate. In the absence of an adjustment
to the remit to 'lean against the wind', some additional
policy instrument is needed to induce these necessary readjustments.
The two relevant policy questions are (i) whether actual real house
prices reflect their equilibrium values, and (ii) if not, what policy
instrument could be used (besides monetary policy) to mitigate problems
caused by a disequilibrium growth path? We address both these questions.
First, we consider which variables drive house prices. Given a set of
possible components, we then proceed to estimate a structural error
correction house price equation. We use the long-run properties of our
estimated equation to derive the equilibrium trend, which in turn
permits calculation of the extent of disequilibrium in the housing
market. Second, among the components we tested, we consider contenders
for policy instruments, namely the loan-to-value and loan-to-income
ratios. We find that the loan-to-income ratio is a significant driver of
house prices, and use our estimated model to show that this could be an
effective policy instrument for regulating house prices and therefore
addressing the role of the housing market in contributing to systemic
banking risk.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Driving factors
We consider several demand-side variables as factors that may have
driven the recent house price dynamics: firstly, the long-run borrowing
rate and the short-run nominal interest rate, which have both been
steadily falling since the 1980s reflecting the process of financial
liberalisation that took place since this period. Both series are
plotted in figure 3. The borrowing rate equals the sum of the Bank of
England's policy rate and the spread between household borrowing
and deposit rates adjusted for the rate of inflation. This reflects
mortgage interest rates, and as such proxies the real cost of borrowing
that would be used in a net present value calculation based on the
expected future (implicit) rental value of the house. The other series
plotted is the 3-month nominal interest rate, as defined by the
interbank rate, which feeds into mortgage contracts and therefore
represents front-loading of mortgage costs. That is, it will determine
the timing of housing purchase decisions in the short run, as a rise in
short-term rates will raise mortgage repayments as a per cent of total
incomes, even when the real interest rate is constant. Both have an
inverse relationship with demand for houses and thus as both series have
been falling, they would theoretically cause upward movements in house
prices.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In previous literature, real income has been found to affect demand
for housing significantly; Holly and Jones (1997) found this to be the
single most important determinant of real house prices, using a dataset
that extended back to 1939. We consider real disposable income, which is
real personal income net of tax and is thus the part of consumers'
total income that is available to spend on servicing debts from house
purchases. The higher real disposable income, the higher demand (though
the magnitude of the increase will depend on the income-elasticity of
demand for houses). Figure 4 plots real disposable income per capita.
There appears to be a slight trend in the growth of the series over
time, which could reflect population dynamics, though in the past decade
or so it has levelled off to a plateau. Thus, though disposable income
is (at least theoretically) a driver of house demand and prices, it is
not visibly accountable for the surge in house price growth since the
late 1990s.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Our two contenders for policy instruments are the ratios of the
total value of new buyers' mortgage loans to the incomes of those
households and to the total value of the property purchased by those
buyers, respectively, and these represent loans issued at the margin.
These variables directly affect the purchasing power of consumers.
Availability of credit in general usually affects liquidity constrained
consumers the most. But as house prices tend to be multiplicative
functions of buyers' total incomes, loan availability affects the
majority of new buyers. Throughout the period over which house prices
have experienced more persistent growth, the loan-to-income ratio has
also experienced a dramatic upward swing, as depicted in figure 5. This
illustrates that the past two decades or so have seen not only falling
costs of borrowing for consumers but also rising availability of loans,
both of which have boosted consumer demand. The loan-to-value ratio
however does not seem to corroborate this story. Nevertheless, it is
important to note that the relationships between house prices and the
loan-to-income and loan-to-value ratios are not necessarily
unidirectional. Loans secured on the value of houses would rise as do
house prices, indicating that there could be some endogeneity between
the series.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
We also consider the number of households and the housing stock,
and the ratio of the two (plotted in figure 6). If the stock of housing
were to rise, we would expect house prices to weaken as supply would
have risen relative to demand. According to a recent OECD report (2011),
since the mid-1990s land use planning policy has been excessively
restrictive, hampering the responsiveness of supply to demand,
'contributing to creating housing shortages and reducing
affordability'. However; figure 6 illustrates that, although the
ratio of households to housing stock grew from a shortfall in demand of
around 15 per cent in the first part of our sample, since the 1980s the
ratio has remained at around 0.98, indicating that the rising number of
households over this period has been met by growth in the housing stock
almost one-to-one. Nevertheless, we should test for the impact of these
supply-side factors in our regression.
We also test various dummy variables, to account for housing market
responses to various legislation changes over our sample period. These
include the surge in housing demand that preceded the ending of the
double mortgage interest tax relief in 1988, the impact of the change in
monetary policy at the end of 1989 when the UK joined the Exchange Rate
Mechanism, the introduction of Right-to-Buy schemes in 1979 and
Buy-to-Let mortgages in the 1990s, as well as the stamp duty
'holiday' in 2009. Some were excluded because they were not
significant in the long-run equation.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Estimation of real house price equation
To estimate our equation for real house prices, we build on the
model developed in Barrell et al. (2004). Their model took a reduced
form demand equation of the form derived by Meen (2002) and estimated it
as an error correction equation. Our set of variables comprises real
house prices (rpb), the real borrowing rate (brr), the 3-month nominal
interest rate (r3m), the loan-to-income ratio (lty), the loan-to-value
ratio, per capita real disposable income (pcdi), the ratio of the number
of households to the housing stock (blobs), the number of households
(hh) and our set of legislation dummies. Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests
for the stationarity of the variables indicated that most are integrated
of order one (in both levels and logs), as illustrated in table 1. When
tested separately, the number of households was integrated of order
zero, and the housing stock was I(1) at the 5 per cent level, which
means that only the latter should be included in an equation that
cointegrates in the long run. However the ratio of the two is I(1).
We include all our variables except the short-run nominal interest
rate and the dummies in an Engle-Granger cointegrating relationship
(1987), estimating a linear equation using ordinary least squares with
log real house prices as the dependent variable. Our resulting long-run
equation contains log per capita real disposable income, the ratio of
households to housing stock, the loan-to-income ratio, and the borrowing
rate, and we also estimated a regression that included the log of the
housing stock as an alternative to the ratio of households to housing
stock. An ADF test on the estimated residuals from the first long-run
equation leads to the rejection of the null hypothesis that a unit root
is present at the 5 per cent level, indicating that the long-run
equation cointegrates. 'The equation including the log of the
housing stock did not cointegrate, and the housing stock had a positive
sign, which would not be expected. The ratio of the number of households
to the housing stock was also wrongly signed. However, we also found
that a more parsimonious specification of the long-run equation which
omits the households--housing stock ratio also cointegrates, as we can
see from table 2 below. According to Davidson (1998), this suggests that
the households-housing stock ratio contains no significant relevant
information in the long-run equation. He notes that, given the choice
between two cointegrating sets, the more parsimonious model is the
better one. We therefore consider this adequate justification for their
exclusion from the final model. It is possible that a regional model of
house prices would be able to capture supply-side factors such as the
housing stock-to-household ratio.
We then embed the preferred specification of the long-run equation
into an error correction equation, adding in dynamic terms including two
lags of changes in the dependent variable as well as the change in the
three-month nominal interest rate and the legislation dummies. The final
specification, excluding dummies, is reported in table 3 below. (1)
Our final model contains only demand-side variables, and as such
represents an inverse demand function, as in Barrell et al. (2004). The
model suggests that house prices are chiefly driven by per capita real
disposable income, the loan-to-income ratio, and negatively by the real
borrowing rate. Recent research by the OECD indicates that the key
drivers of the recent surge in house price growth are 'higher
income and an increase in the number of households', and though
lower mortgage rates have also contributed to increased house price
growth, they find their contribution relatively modest (2011, p. 63).
The importance of household income is well-established in literature on
house prices, and on this aspect our model is in accordance with
tradition. However, the absence of demographic variables (other than
income) and the importance of the loan-to-income ratio in our model
contrasts with the OECD research. They estimate a similar error
correction model which places a much higher emphasis on the shortfall of
housing supply in meeting demand, whereas our model emphasises those
variables that affect households' liquidity constraints and
purchasing power.
The error correction term suggests real house prices adjust slowly
and, therefore, given their oscillatory nature, on average real house
prices would deviate away from equilibrium for a period of five years
before gradually self-correcting over a further five-year period.
Notably, real disposable income per capita has almost a unit
coefficient. Though the loan-to-income ratio (which has stabilised at
around 3.1 since 2004) would theoretically seem more important as loans
fund the lion's share of house purchases, it only has a
semi-elasticity of around 0.4. It is notable that we found no clear
evidence of Granger causality between real house prices and the
loan-to-income ratio in either direction. Nevertheless, we consider this
to be unimportant, primarily on the grounds that Granger causality,
tests determine statistical but not economic causality, and secondly the
ratio was significant in our regressions. That either series is not
statistically useful for forecasting the other does not mean that an
underlying economic relationship is not present.
Endogenous dynamics are also important in the model as is to be
expected, though the effect dies out over time as the second lag has a
smaller coefficient. In addition, the change in the 3-month nominal
interest rate has a statistically significant effect on real house
prices in the short run. The ERM-related dummies are not significant in
the final equation as it includes the change in the nominal interest
rate and this picks up the effect of the rise in interest rates at this
time, increasing mortgage front loading noticeably.
Equilibrium real house prices
Using our estimated equilibrium house price equation to address the
first of our policy questions outlined above, we take the estimated
equation and use this to measure potential mis-valuation of house prices
as compared to the dynamic steady state equilibrium following Nickell
(1985). Our final equation comprises a long-run trend equation plus some
short-run dynamics, which are not just white noise, but evolve over time
with a non-zero mean. We capture the trends in the short-run dynamics
with 10-year moving averages of the actual data for these variables. We
then calculate the long-run dynamic steady state path of real house
prices, and estimate by how much actual real house prices departed from
this over the period. Figure 7 illustrates the deviations of real house
prices from their equilibrium, which we may call the percentage
overvaluation, and vice versa for deviations below zero.
This shows that in 2007 real house prices were around 20 per cent
higher than their sustainable equilibrium level given the driving
factors. There has been a correction in the housing market since, and as
of 2010 quarter 3 they were only marginally above trend. This is,
however, a slightly misleading figure, due to the abnormally low
interest rates that the Bank has set following the crisis, which has fed
into borrowing rates. As borrowing rates have a negative impact on
equilibrium house prices, lower rates will have inflated our estimate of
the trend, disguising the real extent of the recent overvaluation. If we
consider the trajectory of real prices in a world where real borrowing
rates were at the same levels as they were at the end of 2007 and with
no changes in current real house prices, then the estimated
overvaluation would be higher. This is illustrated by the dotted line in
figure 8. In this case we find that real house prices would in fact be
11 per cent higher than their sustainable equilibrium. Given that real
interest rates will rise over the next few years, we would expect to see
downward pressure of 1 to 2 per cent a year on real house prices over
the next five years or so.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Policy simulations
Our final model includes the loan-to-income ratio as one of the
long-run components of the error correction equation, and we suggest
that this could be used as a policy instrument to regulate the growth of
house prices. In order to investigate its efficacy, we analyse the
effect of using the loan-to-income ratio as a policy instrument with our
in-house global econometric model, NiGEM. We simulate a 20 per cent
permanent reduction in the loan-to-income ratio starting from the first
quarter of 2011, taking the level from 2.95 times income to 2.45 times
income, as was last seen in 2000, as we can see from figure 5 above.
This allows us to gauge what we might have seen in the housing market if
the loan-to-income ratio had not risen so drastically over the past ten
years. The impact of this shock on real house prices is plotted in
figure 8. The results of this simulation suggest that a 20 per cent
shock to the loan-to-income ratio induces house prices to fall by 25 per
cent of their base forecast values by 2015 (responding with almost unit
elasticity to the loan-to-income ratio), narrowing to around 20 per cent
in the longer run. The stock of the mortgage debt of households would be
almost 8 per cent lower than our baseline by 2016 in this scenario.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Conclusion
The loan-to-income ratio for new mortgages may be difficult to
reduce, and it certainly cannot be reduced at the speed suggested here,
but policies to reduce it will almost certainly put downward pressure on
house prices. Our results should be seen as illustrative. It is not
clear from our results that changes in loan-to-value ratios would have
the same impact, and indeed they appear to be caused by house prices,
and are not a cause of them. Clearly major increases in the supply of
housing would be liable to put downward pressure on prices, but changes
in supply over the past thirty years have just about kept pace with
household formation, and hence it is statistically difficult to find a
role for supply-side factors, although common sense as well as economic
theory tell us it should be there.
House price dynamics have been a major factor affecting booms and
recessions in the UK for more than forty years, and policy is now being
set to help stabilise house prices and reduce loan growth. House prices
have been overvalued for much of the past decade, but with current low
borrowing costs they look about right. However borrowing costs are
likely to rise over the next five years as policy rates set by the Bank
of England move from 'crisis' levels near zero to
'normal' levels of around 5 per cent. These increases are
likely to induce real house prices to fall by around 2 per cent a year
for the next five years. This note suggests that the increase in the
loan-to-income ratio for new buyers that took place from 2000 onwards
was a major factor behind the increase in house prices. The note also
illustrates that the loan-to-income ratio would be an effective policy
instrument for regulating the housing market. The loan-to-income ratio
is expected to fall in the near furore, which provides further evidence
that real house price growth will be negative over the next five years.
The OECD proposes housing supply should be made more responsive to
demand. We find that regulation should focus rather on limiting loan
availability such that loans are issued more in line with income.
DOI: 10.1177/0027950111411374
REFERENCES
Barrell, R., Davis, E.P., Karim, D., Liadze, I. (2010), 'Bank
regulation, property prices and early warning systems for banking crises
in OECD countries', Journal of Banking and Finance, 34, pp.
2455-64.
Barrell, R., Kirby, S. and Riley, R. (2004), 'The current
position of UK house prices', National Institute Economic Review
(189), pp. 57-60.
Davidson, J. (1998), 'Structural relations, cointegration and
identification: some simple results and their application', Journal
of Econometrics, 87(1), pp. 87-113.
Engle, R. and Granger, C. (1987), 'Co-integration and error
correction: Representation. estimation and testing', Econometrica,
55(2), pp. 251-76.
Holly, S. and Jones, N. (1997), 'House prices since the 1940s:
cointegration, demography and asymmetries', Economic Modelling,
14(4), pp. 549-65.
Meen, G. (2002), 'The time-series behaviour of house prices: a
transatlantic divide?', Journal of Housing Economics, 11(I), pp.
1-13.
Nickell, S. (1985), 'Error correction, partial adjustment and
all that--an expository note', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, 47, 119.
OECD (March 2011), Economic Surveys: United Kingdom 2011, OECD
Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-gbr-2011-en.
NOTE
(1) We also estimated the error correction model using the first
specification of the long-run equation (including the household-housing
stock ratio), and found that the ratio was not significant at this
stage.
Table 1. Orders of integration
ADF-statistic p-value
l(rph) *-3.42 0.05 I(1)
dl(rph) ***-4.97 0.00
R3m -2.16 0.22 I(1)
d(r3m) ***-10.66 0.00
Brr -2.29 0.18 I(1)
d(brr) ***-12.53 0.00
Lty -0.98 0.76 I(1)
d(lty) ***-7.01 0.00
Ltv -1.72 0.42 I(1)
d(ltv) ***-6.80 0.00
l(pcdi) -1.56 0.80 I(1)
dl(pcdi} ***-18.21 0.00
hhhs -3.17 0.11 I(1)
d(hhhs) ***-6.35 0.00
l(hh) ***-4.34 0.01 I(0)
l(hs) -1.70 0.74 I(1)
dl(hs) ***-6.36 0.00
Notes: sample period: 1963Q4 to 201OQ3. *** significant at the 1%
level; ** significant at the 5% level; * significant at the 10% level.
Table 2. Cointegration of the long-run (ADF tests)
Spec. 1 Spec. 2 Spec. 3
(ratio) (housing stock) Neither
ADF-statistic -4.45 -3.75 -4.14
5% significance level -4.42 -4.42 4.10
Table 3. Error correction equation for house prices
Error Real Loan-to-
correction borrowing rate income
(-1) (-1)
coefficient -0.052 -0.023 0.393
p-value 0.000 0.015 0.006
Log (per cap. dlog (real price dlog (real price
disposable houses houses
income (-1)) (-1)) (-2))
coefficient 0.773 0.559 0.291
p-value 0.003 0.000 0.000
Change in 3-
month interest
rate (-1))
coefficient -0.004
p-value 0.008