Prospects for the UK economy.
Kirby, Simon ; Barrell, Ray ; Whitworth, Rachel 等
Introduction
The performance of the UK economy was surprisingly weak in the
final three months of 2010. The Office for National Statistics (ONS)
preliminary estimate of GDP suggests the economy contracted by 0.5 per
cent in the quarter. Much of this can be attributed to the exceptionally
bad weather in the weeks before the Christmas holidays. But even when
this effect is excluded UK economic growth is estimated to have stalled.
It is important to gauge the signal in this slowdown, because if it is
continued it will affect Bank of England decision making and strengthen
the case for restructuring and retiming the fiscal consolidation that is
underway. The composition of growth is important in this re-evaluation
of prospects. While one would expect the construction sector to be
hampered by adverse weather, the contraction in services output was more
surprising.
The National Institute's estimate of monthly GDP in January suggested that growth would be positive in the fourth quarter. The 1.0
percentage point error in this case is large. The poor performance of
the monthly model reflects its dependence on data for the industrial
production side of the economy, which are more timely than estimates for
the service sector. The ONS's preliminary estimate is based on
little data for the final month of last year (which is when the adverse
weather struck) and the estimate will undergo some revision as more
information becomes available. However, it is unlikely that this
contraction will disappear in future data revisions.
It remains to be seen how much of the lost output due to adverse
weather is recovered in the first quarter of this year. In the absence
of further adverse weather, we expect to see a return to growth in the
first quarter of this year (see figure 1), with the majority of the
temporary loss being recovered. This rebound is liable to flatter the
'underlying' economic performance of the UK. Indeed the
magnitude of the effect of the weather at the end of last year
significantly reduces the probability of the UK economy recording a
further contraction in the first quarter of this year, although the
average rate of growth across the two quarters is expected to be a
little over 0.1 per cent per quarter.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The outlook for economic growth over the next couple of years is
relatively subdued, due to weak domestic demand growth. Falling real
incomes and falling real house prices are expected to keep consumer
spending depressed. The Office for Budget Responsibility in November 2010 (and based on Spending Review 2010), suggested that a significant
retrenchment would start this year. Gross fixed capital formation will,
however, support domestic demand growth in the next couple of years. The
government's plan suggests that government investment will fall
sharply over the coming years. Alongside this, the turnaround in the
stock cycle has already been surprisingly fast, suggesting that
stockbuilding will add little to the growth in demand this year. Private
sector investment is expected to raise overall domestic demand over the
next couple of years. Overall, we expect domestic demand to grow by 0.4
per cent per annum this year and next. GDP growth is expected to be much
higher, at 1.5 per cent this year and 1.8 per cent in 2012, with a
strong contribution from net exports.
Our forecast for GDP growth in 2011 involves a downward revision
from our October Review (down from 1.6 per cent). This reflects in part
the base effect from the contraction in GDP at the end of last year.
However, more recent events have also shifted the outlook for economic
growth. Oil prices are around $18 a barrel higher than in our October
forecast. Forecasts based on futures markets suggest the shift in the
price of oil is permanent. As discussed in Barrell and Kirby (2008), a
permanent rise in oil prices depresses GDP growth and raises inflation
in oil consuming countries. Simulations using our global econometric
model NiGEM (reported in Barrell, Delannoy and Holland in this Review)
suggest that the recent shift in oil prices will depress GDP growth by
around 0.1 percentage point per annum over the next five years, with
perhaps twice the average effect appearing in 2011. As a consequence of
the rise in oil prices, the rate of inflation is expected to increase by
over 1/2 percentage point this year, with more modest effects in 2012
and 2013. The fall in the sterling- dollar exchange rate means the oil
price has almost returned to its 2008 peak in sterling terms.
The recent performance of the UK labour market has been
'better' than in previous downturns. Holland et al. (2009) and
(2010) suggest that this has much to do with the downward adjustment of
real wages as unemployment rose. Indeed, between the end of 2009 and
October 2010, over 200,000 jobs, net, have been created. Over 97 per
cent of the jobs that have been created are part-time. The proportion of
those employed who are working part-time because they cannot obtain
full-time work has reached a record of 4 per cent (1.16 million people).
As a consequence average hours worked in the economy fell sharply over
the course of the recession and through the course of the recovery to
date. Going forward we assume that employers will raise their demand for
labour through increases in the working hours of those currently
employed, rather than for further net job creation. We expect
unemployment to rise through much of 2011, peaking at 8.8 per cent or
2.8 million in the third quarter of the year. We do expect the
unemployment rate to fall back over the period from 2012 but, as Barrell
and Kirby discuss in this Review, we expect the rate of unemployment to
settle around 1 percentage point higher than in the preceding decade.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Future exchange rates are assumed to follow the path implied by
uncovered interest rate parity. Given the global nature of the projected
monetary policy tightening, a noticeable appreciation in sterling over
the next five years is unlikely. By 2015 the average sterling effective
exchange rate is still expected to be around 20 per cent below the level
of 2007. Recent concerns about inflation have prompted financial markets
to expect earlier increases in interest rates than had previously been
expected, putting some upward pressure on sterling at the turn of the
year. We assume that this modest shift in the UK monetary stance relative to the US and Euro Area has been fully priced into currency
markets.
The rate of CPI Inflation reached 3.7 per cent per annum in
December 2010, around 0.4 percentage point higher than anticipated three
months previously. In the near term we expect to see the rate of
inflation rise even further (see figure 2). As noted above, much of the
increase in our forecast for inflation this year is due to movements in
the oil price. Given the announcement of the increase in VAT this year
in June's Emergency Budget, the rate of inflation this year was
always going to be significantly above target. Our forecast for
inflation assumes 100 per cent pass-through for the standard rate of
VAT. While evidence (Pike et al., 2009) suggests that the temporary
reduction in December 2008 was only partially passed on, it does not
follow that we should assume a symmetric response when VAT increases
permanently. (1) Indeed, evidence from the Bank of England's Agents
Summary of Business Conditions for this January suggests that 84 per
cent of respondents expect to fully pass on the increase in VAT, with a
further 11 per cent expecting to pass on much of the increase.
As figure 2 shows, we expect the rate of inflation to fall back
sharply next year as the upward pressure of these temporary factors
drops out of the inflation rate calculation and spare capacity. Figure 2
presents the 80, 85 and 90 per cent confidence intervals around our
forecast for CPI inflation. These bounds have been derived from
stochastic simulations on our global econometric model, NiGEM. By the
middle of 2011 there is a 10 per cent chance that the rate of inflation
will be at 5 per cent or higher. The chance of inflation moving below 3
per cent this year is less than 1 in 10. Given that the rate of
inflation is expected to fall below target in 2012, the weight of
probability is that the inflation rate will be below target throughout
2012.
Prior to the release of the preliminary estimate of GDP, yield
curves implied that financial markets expected three increases in Bank
Rate by the end of this year. The January 2011 and October 2010 yield
curves are plotted in figure 3. We assume two rather than three
increases in Bank Rate by the end of this year as output growth looks
weak. The difference between the yield curves of 17 January and the one
used in our October forecast is 25 basis points by the end of this year,
rising to 125 basis points by the end of next year. Even when assuming a
forward-looking world the effect on the economy from this difference is
relatively muted. In our current forecast the rate of inflation is
approximately 0.2 percentage point lower this year than it would have
been with the yield curve from October, offsetting one third of the
increase in inflation induced by oil price changes. Additionally, GDP
growth is approximately 0.1 percentage points lower than it otherwise
would have been. Given that it takes up to two years for the full
effects of interest rates to feed through the economy, aggressively
raising interest rates in the near term might be unwise.
A case for a tighter monetary stance could be made if inflation
expectations suggested their anchor had become dislodged. While
household inflation expectations have risen throughout the course of
last year (see figure A1), wage growth remains muted (see figure 4),
with real wages continuing to fall. Currently, inflation expectations in
financial markets seem to be contained. In the most recent minutes of
their monthly meeting, the MPC have already indicated that the prospect
of drifting inflation expectations is a concern, with two members
calling for a quarter point rise. However, we would expect the MPC to
maintain the monetary policy status quo until it is clear that growth
has resumed.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Earnings and prices
The latest inflation figures show the annual rate of CPI inflation
rose to 3.7 per cent in December 2010, up from 3.3 per cent in November.
For the whole of 2010 the rate of CPI inflation was a percentage point
or more above the target of 2 per cent. The Office for National
Statistics (ONS) notes that the December increase in CPI is chiefly
attributable to rising energy and food prices, as well as an increase in
air transport fares (an indirect effect of rising energy prices, but
with a small weight). These are cost-push inflationary pressures in
contrast to the demand-pull factors which are currently exerting
downward pressure on price inflation due to the amount of spare capacity
in the economy. However, much of the upward pressure on consumer price
inflation last year was due to the increase in VAT at the start of last
year.
Excluding indirect taxes from the calculation of inflation gives a
rate between 1.4-2 per cent per annum for the whole of 2010. While the
assumption of 100 per cent pass-through from the VAT increase might not
be valid at the start of the year, we would expect the pass-through to
come close to this as the year progressed. In other words, underlying
inflationary pressures were significantly less than the headline figures
suggested.
However, even excluding indirect taxes, inflation picked up at the
end of last year. Excluding indirect taxes, the rate of inflation
increased from 1.4 per cent per annum in July to 2 per cent in December
2010. Oil in particular may explain much of the upward trend in
inflation at the end of 2010, as the soaring prices of crude oil will
have fed into the UK inflation rate through oil derivative products such
as gas and petrol. Such products constitute a large proportion of the
costs in two of the categories noted above--air transport and
energy--but will also increase costs of other transportation, motoring
expenditure, and fuels used for household energy consumption. Liquid
fuels prices, for instance, saw an increase of 48.7 per cent from a year
ago. Oil prices have been trending upwards steeply for the past couple
of months and passed $90 per barrel in December-- prices not seen since
2008. As these are spot prices, their feed-through into inflation
figures is lagged. Oil prices have continued to rise in December and
January, which will exert upward pressure on inflation into January and
February this year.
Reflecting the energy and food price trends, our CPI inflation
forecasts have been revised upwards. We expect the rate of inflation to
increase from 3.3 per cent in 2010 to 3.8 per cent in 2011. As figure 2
shows, there is a risk that inflation could rise even further than this.
Certainly, further increases in the oil price above what we currently
expect would push the rate of inflation even higher. However, the rate
of inflation will be kept higher due to the increase in VAT at the start
of this year. With no plans for further increases in VAT, the rate of
inflation is expected to fall sharply next year. We forecast annual CPI
inflation to fall to 1.8 per cent in 2012 and to around the 2 per cent
target in the medium term.
Despite the recent inflationary pressures, there is no suggestion
of a resulting wage-price spiral and, indeed, the downward pressure on
real wages seen up to the summer of 2010 has remained a key factor in
softening the impact of the recession on unemployment (Holland et al.,
2009). Figure 4 shows public and private sector (regular) pay from the
Average Weekly Earnings series. Since the start of 2009, public sector
pay was more robust than private sector pay, which plummeted over this
period. This difference may be partly related to the multi-year pay
settlements in the public sector. However the decline in public sector
pay, though more gradual, was sustained for longer, and has only started
to rise again in recent months. Part of the government's fiscal
consolidation plan includes a public sector pay freeze, which should, in
theory, reduce the growth rate of public sector pay. However, Bird
(2010) suggests that numerous factors affecting Average Weekly Earnings
are actually likely to place upward pressure on public sector pay
growth. Such factors include the 250 [pounds sterling] annual pay rise
for those earning less than 21,000 [pounds sterling], multi-year pay
deals, inclusion of banks in the public sector, and changes in the
composition of public sector employment.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Demand
Domestic demand was robust through the first half of 2010, and this
continued into quarter three as growth remained at around 0.8 per cent.
However, using the ONS's preliminary estimate of GDP, we estimate
that domestic demand declined by 0.5 per cent in the final quarter of
last year.
We can look at the components of GDP in order to understand what is
driving these dynamics. The basic GDP accounting identity, comprising
consumption, capital expenditure, government expenditure and net
exports, can be roughly equated to domestic plus external demand. Figure
5 illustrates these different components in levels terms since the
pre-recession peak in GDP, in the first quarter of 2008. Government
consumption increased until mid-2010, reflecting efforts to boost the
economy through fiscal stimulus, but began to decline through the second
half of that year. Private consumption clearly fell throughout 2008 and
2009, but began to recover thereafter. Consumer spending remains well
below its pre-recession peak in 2008Q1. Our forecast is for consumption
to remain at around this level throughout 2011, and only in 2014 will it
reach its pre-recession peak.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Gross fixed investment declined steeply throughout 2008 and 2009,
but began to recover gradually from the end of 2009. However, the volume
of gross fixed investment remains 20 per cent below its pre-crisis peak.
The plans for the volume of government investment, as laid out in the
Office for Budget Responsibility's November Forecast, suggest that
government investment will decline over the next five years. With regard
to private sector investment, we would expect these volumes to expand
over the coming years. Indeed business investment is still 15 per cent
below its pre-crisis level (as defined by the peak in GDP). However, the
current environment is not as conducive to investment growth as the
period prior to the recession, due to the re-pricing of risk and
corresponding rise in the user cost of capital. We expect business
investment to reach its pre-crisis levels in 2014, and housing
investment in 2015. In the short term a lack of bank credit, especially
for SMEs, poses a downside risk for business investment growth.
The contribution of net trade to GDP growth was negative in the
third quarter of last year. Trade data for the period to November 2010
suggests that strengthening exports have meant that net trade provided a
positive contribution to growth in the final quarter of last year. Such
a view is supported by the strong performance of the manufacturing
sector, with the ONS estimating that manufacturing expanded by 1.4 per
cent in this quarter. The volume of manufacturing output has now
expanded by I per cent or more in every quarter since the final quarter
of 2009.
Despite this robust performance in the months to November 2010 the
trade deficit continued to widen. The goods and services trade deficit
widened by 0.1 billion [pounds sterling], which is wholly attributable
to trade in goods. Further, of this widening a large part was in trade
with EU countries, for which the UK deficit widened by 0.2 billion
[pounds sterling], whereas the deficit from trade with non-EU countries
improved slightly. However, much of these movements in trade could be
accounted for by erratic food and oil trade. Excluding these items,
total export volumes grew by 3.4 per cent and import volumes by only 0.3
per cent between October and November.
The recent strength in net exports can perhaps be explained by
movements in the effective exchange rate and price competitiveness. It
was widely anticipated that the depreciation of sterling from the end of
2007 would boost exports in 2009 and 2010. However the gains from the
exchange rate fall were channelled into profits rather than into a
reduction in prices. We presume that markets work and we therefore
expect price competitiveness to improve and the gains to feed through
into demand for UK exports, and we appear to be beginning to see that
happening. We expect export volume growth to be a major source of
economic expansion over the coming years. The volume of manufacturing
output is still around 9 per cent below its pre-recession peak,
suggesting that there is still a significant amount of spare capacity in
this sector to support export volume growth in the UK. We expect the
growth rate of export volumes to accelerate from 5.4 per cent in 2010 to
around 6 1/2 per cent per annum in 2011. The depreciation of sterling
also improves the price competitiveness of domestic firms who compete
directly with imports. With these price adjustments and a period of weak
domestic demand we expect import growth to weaken from 7.9 per cent in
2010 to 2.1 per cent in this year and 0.8 per cent next year. Taken
together, the net trade is expected to be the major source of economic
growth over the next couple of years.
Household sector
Real disposable income growth was robust throughout 2008 and 2009,
despite the economy contracting over much of this period. In part this
was induced by policy. The temporary reduction in the standard rate of
VAT pushed down the rate of inflation by up to 1 percentage point. The
financial crisis may have impaired the monetary transmission mechanism,
but the interest rates on financial products were reduced dramatically
as Bank Rate was cut to its lowest level since the Bank of
England's founding in 1694. UK households have a significant level
of net and gross debt. Prior to the onset of recession, the debt to
income ratio of households was 1.7, the highest in the G7 and, unlike
households in Germany and France, for instance, their gross wealth is
not heavily biased towards interest earning deposits. A consequence of
this is that the sharp reduction in mortgage and unsecured borrowing
rates, along with similar declines in deposit rates, significantly
reduced the net interest payments of households, providing a positive
boost to income growth.
However, real disposable income growth contracted by 1 per cent in
2010. Several factors contributed to this fall, in particular weak
nominal wage growth and high and rising inflation, partly induced by the
return of the standard rate of VAT to 17.5 per cent. Through a
combination of a weak labour market constraining employment, real wage
cuts because of the recession, high consumer price inflation due to the
increase in the standard rate of VAT to 20 per cent and rapid increases
in commodity prices, together with the planned increases in direct taxes
(mainly in the form of increased National Insurance Contributions}, we
expect real disposable incomes to shrink by around 3/4 per cent this
year as well. Real compensation per person hour for employees in
employment will fall by 1 per cent or more in 2011 after a similar fall
in 2010. By the end of 2011 employment incomes will be back to the level
seen in 2006. The decline is as sharp as that seen between 1975 and
1979.
We can view movements in average income by examining per capita real disposable income. Figure 6 plots the annual rate of growth of both
aggregate and per capita real disposable incomes. Unsurprisingly, given
a rising population, the per capita disposable income growth rate has
been consistently lower than the aggregate income growth rate. The
declines of 2010 and 2011 are exacerbated by the continued expansion of
the population. At the end of 2010 per capita real disposable income is
estimated to have been 3.7 per cent below the recent peak in the fourth
quarter of 2008. By the end of this year we expect per capita real
disposable income to be 4 per cent below this recent peak.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
We expect much of the loss in real disposable incomes to be
permanent. The majority is the result of the scar to output caused by
the financial crisis discussion in Barrell and Kirby in this Review.
Output per person hour is likely to be around 3 per cent lower than it
would otherwise have been, and hence incomes will fall by a similar
amount. Wages may fall by more as an increase in the cost of capital
increases its share in income when the elasticity of substitution is
less than one. The rest is the consequence and the recent rise in oil
prices discussed in Barrell, Delannoy and Holland in this Review. The
combination of the effects of higher oil prices on trend output and on
the terms of trade will reduce real incomes by about 1 per cent, with
equal contributions from both sources. We do expect per capita incomes
to rise as the recovery takes hold and conditions in the labour market
improve from 2012 onwards. We expect aggregate real disposable income
growth to rise to around 2 per cent in 2012 and then 2 1/2 per cent per
annum in the medium term as unemployment declines. In per capita terms,
this translates to an expectation of around 2 per cent real income
growth in the medium term. It is only in 2014 that we expect the 2008
peak in per capita incomes to be recovered.
The volume of retail sales continued to grow in the fourth quarter,
albeit at a very modest pace. But retail sales account for only a third
of consumer spending. The components of the preliminary estimate of GDP
show total services declining by 0.5 per cent on the quarter. In
particular, distribution, hotels and restaurants, which includes the
retail sector, declined by 0.5 per cent, suggesting that overall
consumer spending contracted in the final quarter of last year.
Retail sales volumes were unchanged between December 2010 and
December 2009. Breaking this down into food and non-food items, it is
clear that much of this stagnation in retail sales is due to the two
components netting each other out; the ONS estimates that -1.2
percentage points of the change in total retail sales came from
predominantly food stores, 1.3 percentage points from predominantly
non-food stores, 0.8 percentage points from non-store retail and -0.9
from automotive fuel.
Decomposing the retail figures in this manner gives clues that the
weak consumer spending from the end of 2010 was due to domestic and
external factors. The substantial decline in food consumption, for
instance, is likely to be due to a combination of falling real personal
income and higher food prices. These factors represent both income and
substitution effects at work; rising food prices reduce spending power so consumers' incomes do not stretch as far, and simultaneously consumers may be substituting their consumption choices from luxury or
higher priced goods to cheaper alternatives. By contrast, the decline in
sales of automotive fuel is possibly a result of the bad weather
conditions in December.
In our econometric model, consumer spending is determined by
movements in real incomes and real financial and housing wealth. The
continued fall in real incomes is expected to lead to a decline in
consumer spending this year. We expect the decline to be 0.1 percentage
point due to a fall-back in the household saving ratio as households
attempt to smooth their consumption. This reduction in the saving ratio
is expected to be temporary, as we expect real house prices will
continue to fall, as figure 7 shows. The saving ratio will rise over the
period 2012-15, reaching 7 3/4 per cent in 2015.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Our preferred measure of house prices, a seasonally adjusted version of the Department for Communities and Local Government (DCLG)
mix-adjusted index, suggests that the average level of house prices
increased by around 7 per cent in 2010. However, by the end of 2010
house prices were around 6 per cent below the peak of the first quarter
of 2008. The DCLG index measures house prices at the completion stage of
a house purchase. The other major house price indices, the Nationwide
and Halifax indices, measure house prices at the mortgage approval stage
and as such are leading indicators of the DCLG measure. Both indices
suggest that the housing market has weakened. The Halifax house price
index suggests that house prices declined by 3.4 per cent per annum at
the end of 2010. The Nationwide house price index reports moderation in
house price inflation from 10.5 per cent in April 2010 to 0.4 per cent
at the end of 2010.
We expect house prices to decline through much of this year.
However, the average for this year is expected to be constant in
comparison to 2009. With regard to the impact on the economy via
consumer spending, it is real house prices that are important. After
adjusting for inflation, real house prices increased in 2010 by 2.8 per
cent (see figure 7). With the continued surge in inflation this year and
a weakening housing market, we expect real house prices to fall by an
average of 2 per cent in each of the next five year.
Public finances
The public finances continue to improve. The latest figures suggest
that for the period April-December 2010 public sector net borrowing was
10.6 billion [pounds sterling] lower than for the same period in 2009.
The return of economic growth and the reversal of the temporary VAT cut
have raised tax revenues, but this has almost entirely been offset by
rising current expenditure. The main factor that has lowered government
borrowing in the UK over the past nine months has been the 32 per cent
cut in investment. The scaling back of investment, and the increase in
the rate of VAT, reflect the ending of the previous government's
temporary stimulus package. We can therefore view much of the
improvement in the public finances this fiscal year as structural rather
than cyclical. In their November Economic and Fiscal Outlook, the OBR
predicts that the ending of fiscal stimulus would result in a 1.2 per
cent of GDP improvement in the cyclically adjusted public sector net
borrowing between 2009-10 and 2010-11.
Fiscal policy has been modified since our October forecast was
published. The Comprehensive Spending Review (CSR) 2010 adjusted the
components of the government's fiscal consolidation plan rather
than the plan in aggregate. The Chancellor announced the reversal of
some of the additional cuts to Resource Departmental expenditure Limits
(RDELs) that had been planned in the Emergency Budget. (2) According to the OBR's Economic and Fiscal Outlook, spending plans over the
parliamentary term have been revised up to more closely match the
'hypothesised' plans of the previous administration. This
shift in spending plans is presented in figure 8. On the basis of the
OBR's projections, this boost to government consumption would have
eroded the headroom that the government has in meeting their Fiscal
Mandate. (3) However, the government introduced further discretionary
policy changes for Annually Managed Expenditure (AME) to maintain the
scale of the package. Notable policy changes announced include the
abolition of child benefit for higher rate tax payers which is expected
to save 0.6 billion [pounds sterling] in 2012-13, rising to 2 1/2
billion [pounds sterling] in each fiscal year 2013-14 to 2015-164 and an
increase in public sector employee pension contributions raising 1.8
billion [pounds sterling] by 2014-15. The OBR estimates that the
additional AME measures will yield the Exchequer 0.7 billion [pounds
sterling] in 2011-12, rising to 9.9 billion [pounds sterling] in
2015-16.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Our forecast for the public finances is presented in table A8. We
have assumed that spending on goods and services, as set out in the
Economic and Fiscal Outlook, are met over the period to 2015-16. We
assume the government's capital expenditure plans are broadly met,
with net investment falling to 1.4 per cent of GDP by 2014-15, where it
stabilises. The other components of expenditure are endogenously determined within our global econometric model, NiGEM.
In our forecast, presented in table A8, tax revenues are endogenous for the whole of the forecast horizon. They are determined by the size
and composition of output and expenditure over the future. We include
any announced discretionary policy changes as well as an assumption
allowing for further fiscal drag. The OBR classifies adjustments to tax
credits and public sector pension contributions on the spending side of
the public sector income and expenditure account; in the National
Accounts they are classified on the revenue side. It is these
discretionary policy changes that account for over half the upward
increase in revenues in our current projections by 2015-16 as compared
to those made in October 2010. The tax take is expected to increase by
1/2 per cent of GDP this fiscal year, driven by the increase in the
standard rate of VAT in January in both 2010 and 2011. The tax take is
expected to continue to rise due to further changes in discretionary
policy, most notably the increase in National Insurance Contributions in
April 2011. However, there is a cyclical component as a more robust
economic recovery takes hold in future years. The scale of the cyclical
recovery in the tax take is dependent on the structure of the recovery.
An export-led recovery, such as the one we are expecting to experience,
is likely to be tax poor. (6)
The OBR expects the current budget balance to move from a deficit
of 7.6 per cent of GDP in 2009-10 to a surplus of 0.3 per cent in
2015-16. Public sector net borrowing is expected to be cut more
aggressively, from 11.1 per cent of GDP in 2009-10 to 1 per cent in
2015-16. We are not as optimistic about the outlook for the public
finances. We expect the current budget to have a deficit of 1.7 per cent
of GDP (30.3 billion [pounds sterling]) in 2015-16. While we expect
public sector net borrowing also to be cut aggressively over the course
of the next five years, we expect borrowing still to be about 3 per cent
of GDP in 2015-16 (55.2 billion [pounds sterling]). Given that the
Chancellor has five years within which to announce further consolidation
measures, we expect the Fiscal Mandate to be met. Our forecast
highlights the fact that the planned consolidation is currently not
large enough to achieve this and taxes will eventually have to rise. We
would not argue for further consolidation immediately, and we have
consistently argued for consolidation only when the economy can support
it; our view remains that this will not be the case in 2011.
Public sector spending is higher in our forecast than in that of
the OBR, and this is predominantly due to different projections for
government interest payments. In the Economic and Fiscal Outlook, the
OBR highlights the sensitivity of the public finance projections to
shifts in the cost of funding faced by the government. The difference in
government interest payments is, to a large extent, due to the rise in
the yield curve. Yield curves imply that, over the next five years, long
rates in the UK will be around 0.6 percentage points higher than in our
October forecast. Our calculations suggest that this raises government
interest payments by around a 1/4 per cent of GDP by 2015-16. However,
the implications of a rise in the yield curve for the debt stock as a
per cent of GDP depend upon why interest rates have risen. If inflation
expectations and outturns increase, then long rates go up but real
interest rates do not. Hence on newly issued debt the interest payment
will include a constant real rate of return and an increased level of
compensation for inflation. The latter component of debt interest is a
repayment of principal, and it causes the debt stock to decline as a per
cent of GDP. If inflation rises there will also be a small temporary
'inflation based wealth tax' on existing bond holders.
Public sector net borrowing is expected to tighten significantly
over the next few years, halving over the period 2009-10 and 2013-14
(from 11 per cent of GDP to 4.9 per cent of GDP). This still implies a
significant amount of debt accumulation. Including expected net
financial transactions over the coming years implies that public sector
net debt as a per cent of GDP will continue to rise in each year
presented in table AS. We expect public sector net debt to rise from
61.2 per cent of GDP at the end of this fiscal year to over 74 per cent
in 2015-16. The government's supplementary fiscal target is for
public sector net debt as a per cent of GDP to be lower in 2015-16 than
in 2014-15. Our forecast suggests that, on the basis of the current
fiscal consolidation plan, this target will be missed, albeit by less
than 1/2 per cent of GDP. If taxes have to rise in order for the primary
target of the Fiscal Mandate to be met, this would also be enough to
meet the supplementary target. Of course an alternative approach to this
secondary target would be to use the proceeds from the sale of the
government's stake in the nationalised banking chains to lower the
debt stock.
The policy mix in the short term The UK economy faces slowing
growth and rising inflation in the short term. Fiscal policy is slowing
growth and the recent rise in oil prices will do the same as well as
boost inflation. If interest rates have to rise to contain inflation
expectations, risks from the financial sector will increase. Although
the financial crisis has subsided, the financial system remains fagile,
and further banking sector problems remain possible. Hence interest
rates have been a major factor behind the ability of banks to rebuild
their capital.
Policy has to be set with long-run benefits and objectives and
short-run costs in mind. Fiscal policy needs to be tightened in the
medium term with the deficit being reduced sufficiently to stop the debt
stock growing. This will slow growth. The financial system needs to hold
more capital, and better quality capital raising borrowing costs. This
will slow growth. Interest rates need to rise in order to reduce
inflation expectations and maintain the credibility of monetary policy.
This will slow growth. Perhaps the increase in the interest rates is the
most urgent and the strengthening of capital adequacy requirements in
the banking system the most important. The current policy mix perhaps
has fiscal policy too tight in the short term and monetary policy too
loose. The balance of costs and benefits might suggest that fiscal
consolidation should perhaps be delayed in 2011 to leave space for
monetary policy tightening to deal with the impacts of higher oil prices
on the inflation rate and on inflation expectations.
DOI: 10.1177/0027950111401137
Appendix--Forecast details
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A9 OMITTED]
Table A1. Exchange rates and interest rates
UK exchange rates FTSE
All-share
Effective Dollar Euro index
2005 = 100
2005 100.00 1.82 1.46 2587.6
2006 100.75 1.84 1.47 3022.6
2007 102.89 2.00 1.46 3306.3
2008 90.69 1.85 1.26 2728.0
2009 81.16 1.57 1.12 2326.0
2010 81.00 1.55 1.17 2818.3
2011 82.14 1.58 1.19 3095.0
2012 82.52 1.58 1.20 3129.2
2013 82.72 1.56 1.20 3267.5
2014 82.84 1.55 1.21 3401.0
2015 83.13 1.54 1.22 3530.8
2010 Q1 80.04 1.56 1.13 2778.8
2010 Q2 80.40 1.49 1.17 2765.9
2010 Q3 82.49 1.55 1.20 2744.2
2010 Q4 81.05 1.58 1.16 2984.1
2011 Q1 82.10 1.58 1.19 3112.4
2011 Q2 82.10 1.58 1.19 3082.4
2011 Q3 82.10 1.58 1.19 3085.3
2011 Q4 82.25 1.58 1.20 3099.7
2012 Q1 82.37 1.58 1.20 3108.4
2012 Q2 82.48 1.58 1.20 3113.8
2012 Q3 82.57 1.58 1.20 3130.5
2012 Q4 82.63 1.57 1.20 3164.2
Percentage changes
2005/2004 -1.6 -0.7 -0.9 15.0
2006/2005 0.7 1.3 0.4 16.8
2007/2006 2.1 8.6 -0.4 9.4
2008/2007 -11.9 -7.4 -14.0 -17.5
2009/2008 -10.5 -15.5 -10.6 -14.7
2010/2009 -0.2 -1.2 3.8 21.2
2011/2010 1.4 2.5 2.4 9.8
2012/2011 0.5 -0.5 0.5 1.1
2013/2012 0.2 -0.9 0.4 4.4
2014/2013 0.1 -1.0 0.4 4.1
2015/2014 0.4 -0.6 0.6 3.8
2010Q4/2009Q1 0.3 -3.3 5.2 11.3
2011Q4/2010Q1 1.5 0.3 2.7 3.9
2012Q4/2011Q1 0.5 -0.7 0.5 2.1
Interest rates
3-month Mortgage 10-year World (a) Bank
rates interest gilts Rate (b)
2005 4.7 6.5 4.4 3.1 4.50
2006 4.8 6.5 4.5 4.1 5.00
2007 6.0 7.4 5.0 4.7 5.50
2008 5.5 6.9 4.5 3.5 2.00
2009 1.2 4.0 3.7 1.1 0.50
2010 0.7 4.0 3.6 1.0 0.50
2011 1.0 4.3 3.8 1.3 1.25
2012 1.9 5.1 4.1 1.9 2.25
2013 2.8 5.8 4.4 2.6 3.00
2014 3.3 6.1 4.5 3.3 3.50
2015 3.7 6.3 4.7 3.9 3.75
2010 Q1 0.6 4.1 4.1 1.0 0.50
2010 Q2 0.7 4.0 3.7 1.0 0.50
2010 Q3 0.8 3.9 3.2 1.0 0.50
2010 Q4 0.8 3.9 3.3 1.0 0.50
2011 Q1 0.8 4.1 3.6 1.0 0.50
2011 Q2 1.0 4.3 3.7 1.1 0.75
2011 Q3 0.9 4.4 3.8 1.3 0.75
2011 Q4 1.2 4.6 3.9 1.5 1.25
2012 Q1 1.5 4.8 4.0 1.7 1.50
2012 Q2 1.8 5.0 4.1 1.8 1.75
2012 Q3 2.0 5.2 4.2 2.0 2.00
2012 Q4 2.3 5.5 4.2 2.1 2.25
Percentage changes
2005/2004
2006/2005
2007/2006
2008/2007
2009/2008
2010/2009
2011/2010
2012/2011
2013/2012
2014/2013
2015/2014
2010Q4/2009Q1
2011Q4/2010Q1
2012Q4/2011Q1
Notes: We assume that bilateral exchange rates for the fourth quarter
of this year are the average of the first two weeks of January. We
then assume that bilateral rates remain constant for the next two
quarters of 2011 before moving in-line with the path implied by the
backward-looking uncovered interest rate parity condition based on
interest rate differentials relative to the U5. (a) Weighted average
of central bank intervention rates in OECD economies. (b) End of
period.
Table A2. Price indices
2006=100
Whole-
sale World
Unit price oil
labour Imports Exports index price
costs deflator deflator (a) ($)(b)
2005 97.7 97.1 97.2 98.5 51.8
2006 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 63.4
2007 102.7 100.2 101.6 101.4 70.5
2008 105.1 112.1 113.7 105.1 95.7
2009 111.2 115.8 115.4 107.7 61.8
2010 112.9 120.7 120.4 111.0 78.9
2011 113.8 128.0 125.2 114.6 97.4
2012 116.3 128.7 127.5 118.1 106.5
2013 118.9 129.3 129.5 120.6 115.5
2014 121.3 130.9 131.6 122.7 120.4
2015 123.3 133.0 133.2 124.7 123.3
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.6 3.7 1.0 1.0 44.4
2006/2005 2.4 2.9 2.8 1.5 22.4
2007/2006 2.7 0.2 1.6 1.4 11.2
2008/2007 2.3 12.0 12.0 3.7 35.7
2009/2008 5.8 3.3 1.5 2.5 -35.4
2010/2009 1.5 4.2 4.3 3.1 27.6
2011/2010 0.8 6.0 4.0 3.2 23.5
2012/2011 2.2 0.6 1.8 3.1 9.4
2013/2012 2.2 0.4 1.6 2.1 8.5
2014/2013 2.0 1.3 1.6 1.7 4.2
2015/2014 1.7 1.6 1.2 1.7 2.4
Retail price index
GDP
deflator Excluding Consumer
Consumption (market All mortgage prices
deflator prices) items interest index
2005 97.4 97.0 96.9 97.1 97.7
2006 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
2007 102.9 103.0 104.3 103.2 102.3
2008 106.1 106.1 108.4 107.6 106.0
2009 107.5 107.6 107.9 109.8 108.3
2010 112.0 110.7 112.8 115.0 111.9
2011 116.8 114.4 118.5 120.1 116.2
2012 118.9 116.9 122.0 122.8 118.2
2013 121.0 119.4 125.2 125.6 120.4
2014 123.5 121.9 128.5 128.7 122.8
2015 125.9 124.2 131.9 132.0 125.3
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.4 2.0 2.8 2.3 2.1
2006/2005 2.7 3.0 3.2 2.9 2.3
2007/2006 2.9 3.0 4.3 3.2 2.3
2008/2007 3.1 3.0 4.0 4.3 3.6
2009/2008 1.3 1.4 -0.5 2.0 2.2
2010/2009 4.2 2.9 4.6 4.8 3.3
2011/2010 4.2 3.3 5.0 4.5 3.8
2012/2011 1.8 2.2 2.9 2.2 1.8
2013/2012 1.8 2.2 2.7 2.3 1.8
2014/2013 2.0 2.1 2.6 2.5 2.0
2015/2014 2.0 1.9 2.7 2.5 2.0
Notes: (a) Excluding food, beverages, tobacco and petroleum products.
(b) Per barrel, average of Dubai and Brent spot prices.
Table A3. Gross domestic product and components of expenditure
[pounds sterling] billion, 2006 prices
Final consumption Gross capital
expenditure formation
Households General Gross Changes in
& NPISH (a) gov't fixed in- inventories
vestment (b)
2005 836.6 281.3 213.6 4.6
2006 852.0 285.2 227.2 5.5
2007 870.8 288.8 245.1 7.4
2008 874.5 293.5 232.8 1.4
2009 846.9 296.3 197.0 -14.8
2010 854.9 299.8 202.8 0.3
2011 854.4 297.7 206.5 4.8
2012 858.4 293.9 212.2 4.8
2013 872.9 288.5 221.7 4.8
2014 891.3 281.7 233.9 4.8
2015 911.8 276.9 247.5 4.8
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.2 2.0 2.4
2006/2005 1.8 1.4 6.4
2007/2006 2.2 1.3 7.8
2008/2007 0.4 1.6 -5.0
2009/2008 -3.2 1.0 -15.4
2010/2009 0.9 1.2 3.0
2011/2010 -0.1 -0.7 1.8
2012/2011 0.5 -1.3 2.8
2013/2012 1.7 -1.8 4.4
2014/2013 2.1 -2.4 5.5
2015/2014 2.3 -1.7 5.8
Decomposition of growth in GDP
2005 1.4 0.4 0.4 -0.1
2006 1.2 0.3 1.1 0.1
2007 1.4 0.3 1.3 0.1
2008 0.3 0.3 -0.9 -0.4
2009 -2.0 0.2 -2.6 -1.2
2010 0.6 0.3 0.4 1.2
2011 0.0 -0.2 0.3 0.3
2012 0.3 -0.3 0.4 0.0
2013 1.1 -0.4 0.7 0.0
2014 1.3 -0.5 0.9 0.0
2015 1.4 -0.3 1.0 0.0
Domestic Total Total Total Net
demand exports final imports trade
(c) expendi- (c)
ture
2005 1336.6 340.3 1676.8 384.5 -44.2
2006 1369.9 378.0 1747.9 419.6 -41.5
2007 1412.0 368.3 1780.3 416.3 -48.0
2008 1402.2 372.1 1774.3 411.1 -39.0
2009 1325.5 334.6 1660.1 362.0 -27.4
2010 1357.8 352.2 1710.0 390.8 -38.6
2011 1363.4 374.7 1738.1 399.2 -24.5
2012 1369.3 396.3 1765.6 402.3 -6.0
2013 1387.8 423.3 1811.1 416.0 7.3
2014 1411.7 449.4 1861.1 432.8 16.6
2015 1440.9 469.3 1910.2 449.3 19.9
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.1 7.9 3.2 7.1
2006/2005 2.5 11.1 4.2 9.1
2007/2006 3.1 -2.6 1.9 -0.8
2008/2007 -0.7 1.0 -0.3 -1.2
2009/2008 -5.5 -10.1 -6.4 -11.9
2010/2009 2.4 5.2 3.0 7.9
2011/2010 0.4 6.4 1.6 2.1
2012/2011 0.4 5.8 1.6 0.8
2013/2012 1.4 6.8 2.6 3.4
2014/2013 1.7 6.2 2.8 4.0
2015/2014 2.1 4.4 2.6 3.8
Decomposition of growth in GDP
2005 2.2 2.0 4.2 -2.0 0.0
2006 2.6 2.9 5.5 -2.7 0.2
2007 3.2 -0.7 2.4 0.2 -0.5
2008 -0.7 0.3 -0.4 0.4 0.7
2009 -5.6 -2.8 -8.4 3.6 0.9
2010 2.5 1.4 3.8 -2.2 -0.9
2011 0.4 1.7 2.1 -0.6 1.1
2012 0.4 1.6 2.1 -0.2 1.4
2013 1.4 2.0 3.3 -1.0 1.0
2014 1.7 1.9 3.6 -1.2 0.7
2015 2.0 1.4 3.4 -1.2 0.2
GDP
at
market
prices
2005 1292.3
2006 1328.4
2007 1364.0
2008 1363.1
2009 1296.7
2010 1315.0
2011 1334.8
2012 1359.2
2013 1391.6
2014 1426.4
2015 1460.5
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.2
2006/2005 2.8
2007/2006 2.7
2008/2007 -0.1
2009/2008 -4.9
2010/2009 1.4
2011/2010 1.5
2012/2011 1.8
2013/2012 2.4
2014/2013 2.5
2015/2014 2.4
Decomposition of growth in GDP
2005 2.2
2006 2.8
2007 2.7
2008 -0.1
2009 -4.9
2010 1.4
2011 1.5
2012 1.8
2013 2.4
2014 2.5
2015 2.4
Notes: (a) Non-profit institutions serving households. (b) Including
acquisitions less disposals of valuables and quarterly alignment
adjustment. (c) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud. (d)
Components may not add up to total GDP growth due to rounding and
statistical discrepancy included in GDP.
Table A4. External sector
Exports Imports Net Exports Imports Net
of of trade of of trade in
goods goods in services services services
(a) (a) goods
(a)
[pounds sterling] billion, 2006 prices (b)
2005 218.6 289.7 -71.1 121.7 94.8 27.0
2006 243.6 319.9 -76.3 134.4 99.6 34.8
2007 218.5 311.3 -92.8 149.8 105.0 44.8
2008 221.5 305.7 -84.1 150.6 105.5 45.1
2009 194.2 267.3 -73.0 140.4 94.8 45.6
2010 214.3 295.4 -81.1 137.9 95.4 42.5
2011 233.5 305.2 -71.7 141.2 94.0 47.2
2012 249.6 306.7 -57.1 146.7 95.6 51.1
2013 268.0 317.1 -49.1 155.3 98.9 56.4
2014 284.7 330.1 -45.4 164.7 102.7 62.0
2015 296.6 342.8 -46.2 172.7 106.5 66.2
Percentage changes
2005/2004 8.9 7.0 6.3 7.3
2006/2005 11.5 10.4 10.4 5.1
2007/2006 -10.3 -2.7 11.5 5.4
2008/2007 1.4 -1.8 0.5 0.5
2009/2008 -12.3 -12.6 -6.8 -10.2
2010/2009 10.3 10.5 -1.8 0.6
2011/2010 9.0 3.3 2.4 -1.5
2012/2011 6.9 0.5 3.9 1.7
2013/2012 7.4 3.4 5.9 3.5
2014/2013 6.2 4.1 6.1 3.8
2015/2014 4.2 3.9 4.8 3.7
Export World Terms Current
price trade (d) of trade balance
competitive- (e)
ness (c)
2006=100 % of GDP
2005 98.0 92.4 100.1 -2.6
2006 100.0 100.0 100.0 -3.4
2007 104.1 107.2 101.4 -2.6
2008 101.2 110.0 101.4 -1.6
2009 93.7 97.7 99.6 -1.7
2010 95.6 108.0 99.7 -2.2
2011 98.1 116.1 97.8 -2.0
2012 97.8 122.3 99.0 -0.4
2013 97.7 129.1 100.2 0.5
2014 97.4 134.9 100.5 1.0
2015 97.0 140.4 100.2 0.9
Percentage changes
2005/2004 -2.5 7.7 -2.6
2006/2005 2.1 8.2 -0.1
2007/2006 4.1 7.2 1.4
2008/2007 -2.7 2.6 0.0
2009/2008 -7.4 -11.2 -1.7
2010/2009 2.0 10.5 0.1
2011/2010 2.6 75 -1.9
2012/2011 -0.3 5.4 1.2
2013/2012 -0.1 5.5 1.2
2014/2013 -0.3 4.5 0.3
2015/2014 -0.4 4.1 -0.3
Notes: (a) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud. (b) Balance
of payments basis. (c) A rise denotes a loss in UK competitiveness.
(d) Weighted by import shares in UK export markets. (e) Ratio of
average value of exports to imports.
Table A5. Household income and expenditure
Average (a) Compen- Total Gross
earnings sation of personal disposable
employees income income
2006=100 billion [pounds sterling],
current prices
2005 95.7 677.5 1081.1 817.6
2006 100.0 713.0 1133.0 853.1
2007 105.0 752.2 1179.8 881.5
2008 106.6 769.2 1230.3 919.5
2009 109.3 774.0 1241.4 942.2
1010 111.9 797.1 1276.9 972.4
1011 116.3 815.6 1311.3 1005.5
2011 119.6 848.8 1377.4 1044.2
2013 123.4 887.8 1440.5 1088.9
2014 127.5 928.5 1511.7 1139.2
2015 131.3 966.7 1583.9 1191.6
Percentage changes
2005/2004 3.6 4.8 5.3 4.5
2006/2005 4.5 5.2 4.8 4.3
2007/2006 5.0 5.5 4.1 3.3
2008/2007 1.5 2.3 4.3 4.3
2009/2008 2.5 0.6 0.9 2.5
2010/2009 3.4 3.0 1.9 3.2
2011/2010 3.0 2.3 3.6 3.4
2012/2011 2.8 4.1 4.2 3.8
2013/2012 3.2 4.6 4.6 4.3
2014/2013 3.3 4.6 4.9 4.6
2015/2014 3.1 4.1 4.8 4.6
Real Final consumption Saving
disposable expenditure ratio (c)
income (b)
Total Durable
billion [pounds sterling],
current prices
2005 839.3 836.6 85.8 3.9
2006 853.1 852.0 91.7 3.5
2007 856.6 870.8 97.9 2.6
2008 866.3 874.5 100.8 2.0
2009 876.4 846.9 99.9 6.0
1010 867.9 854.9 105.1 4.9
1011 861.0 854.4 104.0 4.8
2011 878.3 858.4 104.7 6.3
2013 899.6 872.9 106.7 7.1
2014 922.7 891.3 108.8 7.6
2015 946.1 911.8 110.9 7.8
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.0 2.2 6.3
2006/2005 1.6 1.8 6.9
2007/2006 0.4 2.2 6.7
2008/2007 1.1 0.4 3.0
2009/2008 1.2 -3.2 -0.9
2010/2009 -1.0 0.9 5.3
2011/2010 -0.8 -0.1 -1.2
2012/2011 2.0 0.5 0.7
2013/2012 2.4 1.7 1.9
2014/2013 2.6 2.1 2.0
2015/2014 2.5 2.3 1.9
House Net
prices (d) worth to
income
2006=100 ratio (e)
2005 94.1 6.6
2006 100.0 7.0
2007 110.9 7.1
2008 109.9 6.0
2009 101.3 6.5
1010 108.5 6.8
1011 108.5 6.7
2011 107.2 6.6
2013 107.1 6.5
2014 108.0 6.5
2015 109.8 6.4
Percentage changes
2005/2004 5.5
2006/2005 6.3
2007/2006 10.9
2008/2007 -0.9
2009/2008 -7.8
2010/2009 7.1
2011/2010 0.0
2012/2011 -1.2
2013/2012 -0.1
2014/2013 0.9
2015/2014 1.7
Notes: (a) Average earnings equals total labour compensation divided
by the number of employees. (b) Deflated by consumers' expenditure
deflator. (c) Includes adjustment for change in net equity of
households in pension funds. (d) Department for Communities and Local
Government, mix-adjusted. (e) Net worth is defined as housing wealth
plus net financial assets.
Table A6. Fixed investment and capital
billion [pounds sterling, 2006 prices
Gross fixed investment (a)
Business Private General Total
investment housing (b) government
2005 122.1 67.2 23.7 213.6
2006 127.9 73.9 25.4 227.2
2007 144.0 74.1 27.0 245.1
2008 142.4 56.7 33.6 232.8
2009 115.5 41.5 40.0 197.0
2010 118.7 43.4 40.7 202.8
2011 125.0 47.2 34.3 206.5
2012 131.4 49.8 31.0 212.2
2013 138.5 54.0 29.2 221.7
2014 146.0 59.2 28.7 233.9
2015 153.3 64.7 29.5 247.5
Percentage changes
2005/2004 4.5 -4.8 10.9 2.4
2006/2005 4.8 10.0 7.3 6.4
2007/2006 12.5 0.2 6.4 7.8
2008/2007 -1.1 -23.4 24.5 -5.0
2009/2008 -18.9 -26.9 18.9 -15.4
2010/2009 2.7 4.8 1.8 3.0
2011/2010 5.3 8.6 -15.6 1.8
2012/2011 5.1 5.5 -9.7 2.8
2013/2012 5.4 8.4 -5.9 4.4
2014/2013 5.4 9.6 -1.5 5.5
2015/2014 5.0 9.4 2.5 5.8
User Corporate Capital stock
cost profit
of share of Private Public (c)
capital (%) GDP (%)
2005 17.1 24.2 2163.9 554.1
2006 16.6 25.0 2219.2 564.1
2007 16.5 25.2 2301.2 577.1
2008 16.1 26.2 2370.7 593.2
2009 14.7 25.0 2401.3 612.2
2010 14.5 23.8 2414.2 632.9
2011 16.5 24.9 2433.5 646.6
2012 17.1 25.5 2458.5 656.7
2013 17.0 26.0 2491.6 664.6
2014 16.9 26.4 2533.9 671.9
2015 16.9 26.8 2585.3 679.6
Percentage changes
2005/2004 2.4 1.9
2006/2005 2.6 1.8
2007/2006 3.7 2.3
2008/2007 3.0 2.8
2009/2008 1.3 3.2
2010/2009 0.5 3.4
2011/2010 0.8 2.2
2012/2011 1.0 1.6
2013/2012 1.3 1.2
2014/2013 1.7 1.1
2015/2014 2.0 1.1
Notes: (a) Fixed investment figures exclude the effect of the transfer
of BFNL nuclear reactors to central government in 2005Q2. (b) Includes
private sector transfer costs of non-produced assets. (c) Including
public sector non-financial corporations.
Table A7. Productivity and the labour market
Thousands
Employment ILO Population
unemploy- Labour of
Employees Total(a) ment force(b) working
age
2005 24929 28775 1466 30241 37419
2006 25096 29027 1672 30699 37708
2007 25209 29225 1653 30878 37916
2008 25408 29441 1781 31221 38090
2009 24939 28978 2394 31372 38236
2010 14844 29029 2481 31511 38395
2011 24683 28902 2742 31644 38711
2012 24985 29227 2568 31794 38935
2013 25327 29602 2357 31959 39169
2014 25641 29950 2175 32125 39406
2015 25906 30249 2041 32291 39638
Percentage changes
2005/2004 1.2 1.0 2.9 1.1 0.9
2006/2005 0.7 0.9 14.1 1.5 0.8
2007/2006 0.5 0.7 -1.2 0.6 0.6
2008/2007 0.8 0.7 7.7 1.1 0.5
2009/2008 -1.8 -1.6 34.5 0.5 0.4
2010/2009 -0.4 0.2 3.6 0.4 0.4
2011/2010 -0.6 -0.4 10.5 0.4 0.8
2012/2011 1.2 1.1 -6.4 0.5 0.6
2013/2012 1.4 1.3 -8.2 0.5 0.6
2014/2013 1.2 1.2 -7.7 0.5 0.6
2015/2014 1.0 1.0 -6.2 0.5 0.6
Productivity Unemployment, %
(2006=100)
Claimant ILO unem-
Per hour Manufact- rate ployment
uring rate
2005 97.7 95.4 2.7 4.8
2006 100.0 100.0 3.0 5.4
2007 102.0 102.6 2.7 5.4
2008 101.4 102.4 2.8 5.7
2009 99.5 98.4 4.7 7.6
2010 100.6 104.7 4.6 7.9
2011 102.3 110.7 5.2 8.7
2012 102.8 116.0 4.6 8.1
2013 103.6 120.7 4.0 7.4
2014 104.6 124.8 3.5 6.8
2015 106.0 128.6 3.1 6.3
Percentage changes
2005/2004 1.1 4.6
2006/2005 2.4 4.9
2007/2006 1.9 2.6
2008/2007 -0.5 -0.3
2009/2008 -1.9 -3.8
2010/2009 1.1 6.3
2011/2010 1.7 5.8
2012/2011 0.4 4.8
2013/2012 0.8 4.0
2014/2013 1.0 3.4
2015/2014 1.3 3.0
Notes: (a) Includes self-employed, government-supported trainees and
unpaid family members. (b) Employment plus ILO unemployment
Table A8. Public sector financial balance and borrowing requirement
billion [pounds sterling], fiscal years
2008-9 2009-10
Current receipts: Taxes on income 355.2 337.9
Taxes on expenditure 167.6 168.6
Other current receipts 11.3 14.3
Total 534.1 520.8
(as a % of GDP) 37.3 37.1
Current expenditure: Goods and services 319.0 330.0
Net social benefits paid 171.5 188.3
Debt interest 32.3 31.5
Other current expenditure 43.0 50.9
Total 565.9 600.6
(as a % of GDP) 39.5 42.8
Depreciation 19.0 19.8
Surplus on public sector current budget (a) -50.8 -99.6
(as a % of GDP) -3.6 -7.1
Gross investment 65.7 74.9
Net investment 46.7 55.1
(as a % of GDP) 3.3 3.9
Total managed expenditure 631.6 675.5
(as a % of GDP) 44.1 48.1
Public sector net borrowing 97.5 154.7
(as a % of GDP) 6.8 11.0
Financial transactions 26.9 11.5
Public sector net cash requirement 70.6 143.2
(as a % of GDP) 4.9 10.2
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 44.1 53.8
GDP deflator at market prices (2006=100) 106.6 108.4
Money GDP 1433.4 1404.1
Financial balance under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) -5.0 -11.4
Gross debt under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) 52.1 68.1
2010-11 2011-12
Current receipts: Taxes on income 348.1 363.1
Taxes on expenditure 193.0 205.8
Other current receipts 13.0 14.0
Total 554.1 582.8
(as a % of GDP) 37.6 37.8
Current expenditure: Goods and services 338.2 342.7
Net social benefits paid 196.7 204.1
Debt interest 45.4 51.3
Other current expenditure 51.6 49.4
Total 631.8 647.5
(as a % of GDP) 42.9 42.0
Depreciation 20.5 21.8
Surplus on public sector current budget (a) -98.3 -86.4
(as a % of GDP) -6.7 -5.6
Gross investment 61.7 52.4
Net investment 41.2 30.6
(as a % of GDP) 2.8 2.0
Total managed expenditure 693.6 699.9
(as a % of GDP) 47.1 45.4
Public sector net borrowing 139.5 117.0
(as a % of GDP) 9.5 7.6
Financial transactions -0.9 -10.0
Public sector net cash requirement 140.4 127.0
(as a % of GDP) 9.5 8.2
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 61.2 67.1
GDP deflator at market prices (2006=100) 111.5 115.0
Money GDP 1474.1 1540.9
Financial balance under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) -10.1 -8.4
Gross debt under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) 78.4 82.2
2012-13 2013-14
Current receipts: Taxes on income 384.5 407.5
Taxes on expenditure 210.6 217.4
Other current receipts 14.5 15.2
Total 609.6 640.1
(as a % of GDP) 38.0 38.1
Current expenditure: Goods and services 344.7 348.4
Net social benefits paid 208.7 213.4
Debt interest 55.1 58.3
Other current expenditure 50.9 52.5
Total 659.4 672.6
(as a % of GDP) 41.1 40.0
Depreciation 22.8 23.8
Surplus on public sector current budget (a) -72.6 -56.3
(as a % of GDP) -4.5 -3.3
Gross investment 50.4 49.1
Net investment 27.6 25.3
(as a % of GDP) 1.7 1.5
Total managed expenditure 709.8 721.8
(as a % of GDP) 44.2 42.9
Public sector net borrowing 100.2 81.6
(as a % of GDP) 6.2 4.9
Financial transactions -6.0 -13.0
Public sector net cash requirement 106.2 94.6
(as a % of GDP) 6.6 5.6
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 70.8 73.1
GDP deflator at market prices (2006=100) 117.5 120.0
Money GDP 1605.9 1681.1
Financial balance under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) -7.1 -5.7
Gross debt under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) 85.3 86.6
2014-15 2015-16
Current receipts: Taxes on income 430.8 453.7
Taxes on expenditure 225.5 234.7
Other current receipts 15.9 16.6
Total 672.2 705.0
(as a % of GDP) 38.2 38.5
Current expenditure: Goods and services 348.0 352.9
Net social benefits paid 222.3 233.4
Debt interest 61.9 66.2
Other current expenditure 54.3 56.1
Total 686.6 708.6
(as a % of GDP) 39.1 38.6
Depreciation 24.7 25.7
Surplus on public sector current budget (a) -39.1 -29.2
(as a % of GDP) -2.2 -1.6
Gross investment 49.2 50.8
Net investment 24.5 25.1
(as a % of GDP) 1.4 1.4
Total managed expenditure 735.8 759.3
(as a % of GDP) 41.9 41.4
Public sector net borrowing 63.6 54.3
(as a % of GDP) 3.6 3.0
Financial transactions -7.0 -7.0
Public sector net cash requirement 70.6 61.3
(as a % of GDP) 4.0 3.3
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 74.0 74.3
GDP deflator at market prices (2006=100) 122.5 124.8
Money GDP 1757.6 1833.4
Financial balance under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) -4.4 -3.6
Gross debt under Maastricht (% of GDP) (b) 86.7 86.2
Notes: These data are constructed from seasonally adjusted national
accounts data. This results in differences between the figures here
and unadjusted fiscal year data. Data exclude the impact of financial
sector interventions. (a) Public sector current budget surplus is
total current receipts less total current expenditure and
depreciation. (b) Calendar year.
Table A9. Accumulation
As a percentage of GDP
Households Companies General government
Saving invest- Saving invest- Saving invest-
ment ment ment
2005 2.7 5.3 12.8 10.1 -1.1 1.7
2006 2.3 5.6 12.0 10.2 -0.2 1.7
2007 1.7 5.8 14.3 10.8 -0.4 1.6
2008 1.3 4.6 15.0 9.8 -1.3 2.2
2009 4.2 3.4 13.9 7.4 -6.3 2.6
1010 3.4 3.4 15.1 8.5 -6.5 1.5
2011 3.3 3.7 13.9 8.6 -4.9 1.9
2012 4.3 3.9 13.2 8.5 -3.9 1.6
2013 4.8 4.1 12.4 8.5 -2.7 1.4
2014 5.2 4.5 11.7 8.5 -1.6 1.3
2015 5.3 4.9 11.0 8.6 -0.8 1.2
Whole economy Finance Net
from national
Saving invest- abroad saving (a)
ment
2005 14.5 17.1 2.6 -1.8
2006 14.1 17.5 3.4 -0.7
2007 15.6 18.2 2.6 -1.5
2008 15.0 16.7 1.6 -2.0
2009 11.8 13.5 1.7 -1.5
1010 11.2 14.4 2.1 -2.1
2011 11.2 14.1 2.0 -1.9
2012 13.6 14.0 0.4 -1.6
2013 14.5 14.0 -0.5 -1.0
2014 15.3 14.3 -1.0 -0.6
2015 15.5 14.7 -0.9 -0.4
Note: (a) Negative sign indicates a surplus for the UK.
Table A10. Long-term projections
All figures percentage change unless otherwise stated
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
GDP (market prices) 2.7 -0.1 -4.9 1.4 1.5
Average earnings 5.0 1.5 2.5 3.4 3.0
GDP deflator (market prices) 3.0 3.0 1.4 2.9 3.3
Consumer Prices Index 2.3 3.6 2.2 3.3 3.8
Per capita GDP 2.0 -0.7 -5.5 0.9 0.9
Whole economy productivity (a) 1.9 -0.5 -1.9 1.1 1.7
Labour input (b) 0.8 0.4 -2.9 0.4 -0.2
ILO unemployment rate (%) 5.4 5.7 7.6 7.9 8.7
Current account (% of GDP) -2.6 -1.6 -1.7 -2.2 -2.0
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 40.8 42.6 47.7 47.8 45.7
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 2.5 4.6 10.8 10.2 7.9
Public sector net debt
(% of GDP) 36.7 38.8 48.6 57.0 63.6
Effective exchange rate
(2005=100) 102.9 90.7 81.2 81.0 82.1
Bank Rate (%) 5.5 4.7 0.6 0.5 0.8
3 month interest rates (%) 6.0 5.5 1.2 0.7 1.0
10 year interest rates (%) 5.0 4.5 3.7 3.6 3.8
2012 2013 2014 2015 2016-20
GDP (market prices) 1.8 2.4 2.5 2.4 2.5
Average earnings 2.8 3.2 3.3 3.1 3.5
GDP deflator (market prices) 2.2 2.2 2.1 1.9 1.9
Consumer Prices Index 1.8 1.8 2.0 2.0 2.0
Per capita GDP 1.2 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.8
Whole economy productivity (a) 0.4 0.8 1.0 1.3 2.0
Labour input (b) 1.5 1.7 1.5 1.0 0.4
ILO unemployment rate (%) 8.1 7.4 6.8 6.3 6.1
Current account (% of GDP) -0.4 0.5 1.0 0.9 0.1
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 44.5 43.2 42.1 41.5 41.1
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 6.6 5.2 3.9 3.1 2.2
Public sector net debt
(% of GDP) 68.7 71.8 73.5 74.1 72.3
Effective exchange rate
(2005=100) 82.5 82.7 82.8 83.1 84.3
Bank Rate (%) 1.8 2.7 3.3 3.6 4.5
3 month interest rates (%) 1.9 2.8 3.3 3.7 4.6
10 year interest rates (%) 4.1 4.4 4.5 4.7 4.9
Notes: (a) Per hour. (b) Total hours worked.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The forecast was completed using the latest version of the National
Institute Global Econometric Model (NiGEM). Thanks to Dawn Holland for
helpful comments and suggestions.
The forecast was completed on 25 January 2011.
REFERENCES
Barrell, R., Hurst, A.I. and Mitchell, J. (2009), 'Uncertainty
bounds for cyclically adjusted budget balances', in Larch, M. and
Martins, L.N. (eds), Fiscal Indicators, London, Routledge, pp. 187-206.
Barrell, R. and Kirby, S. (2008), 'Oil prices and
growth', National Institute Economic Review, 204, pp. 39-42.
Bird, D. (2010) 'Zero pay growth in public sector average
weekly earnings; is it likely?', Economic and Labour Market Review,
4.
Holland, D., Kirby, S. and Whitworth, R. (2009), 'Labour
markets in recession: an international comparison', National
Institute Economic Review, 209, pp. 3541. --(2010), 'An
international comparison of employment in recovery', National
Institute Economic Review, 214, October, pp F35-40.
Pike, P., Lewis, M. and Turner, D. (2009), 'Impact of VAT
reduction on the consumer price indices', Economic and Labour
Market Review, 3, 8, pp. 17-21.
NOTES
(1) Pike et al. (2009) suggest that only 66 per cent of 'local
shops' passed on the VAT reduction to customers.
(2) RDELs are broadly consistent with nominal government
consumption as defined in the National Accounts.
(3) The government's Fiscal Mandate is a target that looks
five years ahead. The current target is for the cyclically adjusted
budget deficit to be in balance by 2015-16.
(4) Fiscal drag implies that an increasing number of taxpayers will
be exempt from claiming child benefit.
(5) In 2009-10 there was a 4 billion [pounds sterling] discrepancy between the National Accounts measure of spending that we use in the
forecast and the Public Sector Finances measure projected by the OBR. We
assume this discrepancy disappears by 2011-12.
(6) Barrell, Hurst and Mitchell (2009) discuss this issue.
Simon Kirby, with Ray Barrell and Rachel Whitworth The production
of this forecast is supported by the Institute's Corporate Members:
Abbey plc, Bank of England, Barclays Bank plc, HM Treasury, Nomura Research Institute Europe Ltd, and the Office for National Statistics
and by the members of the NiGEM users group.
Table 1. Summary of the forecast
Percentage change
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
GDP 2.7 -0.1 -4.9 1.4 1.5
Per capita GDP 2.0 -0.7 -5.5 0.9 0.9
CPI Inflation 2.3 3.6 2.2 3.3 3.8
RPIX Inflation 3.2 4.3 2.0 4.8 4.5
RPDI 0.4 1.1 1.2 -1.0 -0.8
Unemployment, % 5.4 5.7 7.6 7.9 8.7
Bank Rate, % 5.5 4.7 0.6 0.5 0.8
Long Rates, % 5.0 4.5 3.7 3.6 3.8
Effective exchange rate 2.1 -11.9 -10.5 -0.2 1.4
Current account as % of GDP -2.6 -1.6 -1.7 -2.2 -2.0
PSNB as % of GDP (a) 2.3 6.8 11.0 9.5 7.6
KIND as % of GDP (a) 36.4 44.1 53.8 61.2 67.1
2012 2013 2014 2015
GDP 1.8 2.4 2.5 2.4
Per capita GDP 1.2 1.8 1.9 1.8
CPI Inflation 1.8 1.8 2.0 2.0
RPIX Inflation 2.2 2.3 2.5 2.5
RPDI 2.0 2.4 2.6 2.5
Unemployment, % 8.1 7.4 6.8 6.3
Bank Rate, % 1.8 2.7 3.3 3.6
Long Rates, % 4.1 4.4 4.5 4.7
Effective exchange rate 0.5 0.2 0.1 0.4
Current account as % of GDP -0.4 0.5 1.0 0.9
PSNB as % of GDP (a) 6.2 4.9 3.6 3.0
KIND as % of GDP (a) 70.8 73.1 74.0 74.3
Notes: RPDI is real personal disposable income. PSNB is public sector
net borrowing. PSND is public sector net debt. (a) Fiscal year,
excludes the impact of financial sector interventions.