Financial structure and incentives.
Cihak, Martin ; Demirguc-Kunt, Asli
The article connects two streams of recent research on the
financial sector. The first is the regulation literature, which
emphasises the central role of incentives in the financial sector. It
points out that the challenge of financial sector regulation,
highlighted by the global financial crisis, is to align private
incentives with public interest without taxing or subsidising private
risk-taking. The second stream of research relates to financial
structures and examines the mix of financial institutions and financial
markets in an economy. It finds that, as economies develop, services
provided by financial markets become comparatively more important than
those provided by banks. The article brings these two streams together,
pointing out that--as financial systems develop from bank-based to
market-based--a traditional regulatory approach that relies on banking
ratios becomes less effective. There is thus a greater need for properly
monitoring and addressing the underlying incentive weaknesses in
market-based systems.
Keywords: Financial sector; financial systems; economic development
JEL Classifications: G00; GOI; G10; G20; O16
Introduction
This article addresses the theme of this Review- financial
structure--from the viewpoint of incentives. The field of financial
structure has generated many interesting debates over the past few
decades, one of them being the relative benefits of bank-based as
opposed to market-based financial systems. This article focuses on
reassessing the received wisdom on this topic in the light of the global
financial crisis.
One issue brought into relief in the global financial crisis is
that, in the financial sector, incentives play a crucial role. The
challenge of financial sector regulation is to align private incentives
with public interest without taxing or subsidising private risk-taking.
Credible threats of market entry and exit, healthy competition, robust
corporate governance, and disclosure of quality information are
essential in getting this balance right. The incentive breakdowns during
the global financial crisis led to calls for regulatory approaches to be
re- oriented to have at their core identification of the underlying
incentive problems in the financial sector (Cihak, Demirguc-Kunt and
Johnston, 2012).
What does this mean from the viewpoint of financial structure? A
wide body of theoretical and empirical literature suggests that, as
economies develop, services provided by financial markets become
relatively more important than those provided by banks. In the current
article, we provide updated empirical evidence to support this finding
and also illustrate that less bank- centric financial systems tend to be
less prone to systemic financial crises. We point out that, as financial
sectors develop from bank-based to market-based systems, the
'Basel-style' regulatory approach, which largely relies on
requiring compliance with regulatory ratios, becomes less and less
effective. There is therefore a greater need for properly monitoring and
addressing the underlying incentive weaknesses in market-based systems,
as illustrated for example by the incentive breakdowns that contributed
to the sub-prime meltdown.
The remainder of the article proceeds as follows. First, we review
and present findings on financial structure, indicating that, with
economic development, services provided by financial markets become
comparatively more important than those provided by banks. Second, we
summarise lessons from the crisis, highlighting the importance of
incentives in the financial sector. Finally, we bring these two lines of
literature together, pointing out the increasing importance of incentive
issues as financial systems develop towards more market-based systems.
Financial structure
Several strands of economic theory suggest that financial
institutions provide services to the economy that are different
from--though sometimes complementary to--those delivered by financial
markets. These theories suggest that financial institutions (and in
particular banks as a key subset of financial institutions) have a
comparative advantage in reducing the market frictions associated with
financing standardised, shorter-term, lower-risk, well-collateralised
endeavours, while decentralised markets are relatively more effective in
custom-designing arrangements to finance more novel, longer-run,
higher-risk projects relying more on intangible inputs. In sum, these
theories predict that both financial institutions and financial markets
have independent impact on economic development (Acemoglu and Zilibotti,
1997; Allen and Gale, 1999; Boot and Thakor, 1997, 2000; Dewatripont and
Maskin, 1995; and Rajan, 1992). In line with these theories, empirical
literature (Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic, 1998; Levine and Zervos, 1998;
and Beck and Levine, 2004) provide evidence that better functioning
banks and securities markets exert robust, independent positive effects
on economic activity.
A substantial body of economic theory also emphasises that the
comparative importance of banks and markets for economic activity
changes during economic development, with markets becoming relatively
more important for economic activity. For example, Allen and Gale
(2000), Boot and Thakor (1997, 2000), Boyd and Smith (1998), and Song
and Thakor (2012) suggest that the services provided by markets become
comparatively more important as economies develop. These theories
suggest that, at higher levels of economic development, economies
require the types of custom-designed financial arrangements that ease
the financing of more novel, longer-run investment that often employ
more intangible inputs than the types of projects that dominate economic
activity at lower levels of economic development. These theories predict
that securities markets are better than banks at financing such
activities, and that therefore the services provided by securities
markets will become more important for fostering economic activity as
economies grow, while those provided by banks will tend to become less
important.
In what follows, we use several measures of the financial system.
We would like to have indicators of the degree to which the mixture of
financial institutions and markets affect the provision of financial
services and thereby help to ameliorate market frictions. But, such
empirical proxies do not exist for a broad cross-section of countries
over the past few decades. Instead, we rely on standard measures of the
size and activity of banks and securities markets. These measures are
constructed for 190 economies over the period from 1970 to 2010. To
approximate 'bank' development, we use private credit, which
is deposit money bank credit to the private sector as a share of GDP. To
measure 'market' development, we primarily use stock value
traded, which is the value of stock market transactions as a share of
GDP. This market development indicator incorporates information on the
size and activity of the stock market, not simply on the value of listed
shares. Additionally, as a robustness check, we examine stock market
capitalisation, which is the value of listed shares on a country's
stock exchanges as a share of GDP and securities market capitalisation,
which equals the capitalisation of the stock market plus the
capitalisation of the private domestic bond markets, divided by GDP.
There is substantial variation across countries (table 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The increasing importance of financial markets, relative to
financial institutions, for economic activity, is brought out quite
clearly by the empirical data. Figure 1 demonstrates this by plotting
the ratio of stock market capitalisation to financial institutions'
assets (a proxy for financial structure) versus gross domestic product
(GDP) per capita (a proxy for economic development), showing the strong
positive correlation between the two. This strong positive relationship,
while of course not a proof of causality, is consistent with the
theoretical predictions discussed above.
To understand better the mechanics of the relationship between
financial structure and economic development illustrated in figure 1, it
is useful to decompose the financial structure indicator, and to examine
the relationship between financial institution size and economic
development separately from the relationship between financial market
size and economic development. Figure 2 illustrates such a
decomposition, showing that both financial institution size as well as
stock market size increases, relative to GDP, with economic development
(the estimated regression slopes being positive). The difference is that
with growing GDP per capita, stock market size increases faster
(relative to GDP), resulting in a shift of the overall financial
structure towards a more market-based system.
Were the relationships between the size of banks, size of markets,
and economic development affected by the recent crisis? To address this
question, figures 2 and 3 show scatter plots for the same variables, but
in different time periods. Specifically, figure 2 relates to the more
recent period of global financial crisis (2008-10), while figure 3
covers the pre-crisis period (1990-2007). The figures confirm the
relative stability of the relationships between financial system
development and economic development. The finding that both financial
institution size and stock market size increase, relative to GDP, with
economic development, is valid both for pre-crisis and for crisis
observations. It also holds for both samples that stock market size
increases faster (relative to GDP) with increasing GDP per capita. This
result does not weaken during the crisis--if anything, the estimated
slope is higher in the more recent data.
Figures 1,2 and 3 show correlations and basic regressions, but
these findings are consistent with more elaborate regression results. In
particular, Demirguc-Kunt, Feyen and Levine (2012) estimate quantile
regressions (1) of economic activity on both bank and securities market
depth relative to GDP, finding that both banks and securities markets
become larger relative to the size of the overall economy as countries
develop economically. These findings hold across various measures of
bank and securities market development, including measures incorporating
private domestic bond markets. They find that the association between
economic activity and bank development decreases with economic
development, but the association between economic activity and
securities market development increases as countries grow. In other
words, as economies develop, the marginal increase in economic activity
associated with an increase in bank development falls, while the
marginal increase in economic activity associated with an increase in
securities market development goes up. These results are in line with
the correlations presented here in figures 1, 2 and 3, and they are also
consistent with predictions from the theoretical literature discussed
above.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The global financial crisis experience has also (re)opened the
question of whether crises are more or less likely in bank-based versus
market-based systems. Of course, the United States and the United
Kingdom, both examples of market-based financial systems, were at the
epicentre of the recent crisis. But that does not necessarily mean that
market-based systems are more prone to crises over longer periods of
time. Figure 4 illustrates this issue graphically for cross-country data
from 1970-2010, that is, combining data from the current crisis with
those from earlier crisis episodes. The figure juxtaposes the data on
financial structures with the often-used financial crisis database by
Laeven and Valencia (2010).
Figure 4 suggests that bank-based systems may be relatively more
prone to systemic crises. To illustrate this, consider for example all
financial systems above the 45 degree line, that is, systems in which
the financial structure ratio (defined as stock market value traded
divided by private credit) is below 1. For those systems, the frequency
of crisis observations is 13.1 per cent, while for the systems below the
45 degree line the crisis frequency is 6.9 per cent.
Is there a link between financial structure and the likelihood of a
financial crisis? Fully addressing this question would deserve in-depth
analysis that would go beyond the scope of this article and would
require controlling for variables that may make poorer countries, which
tend to be bank- based, more subject to crises. Nevertheless, when we
numerically solve for the financial structure ratio that maximises the
signal-to-noise ratio, that is, minimises the frequency of misclassified
observations, we get some interesting clues. Based on the sample in
figure 4, that 'maximum signal-to-noise' financial structure
ratio equals 0.5. For systems with a financial structure ratio below 0.5
(that is, systems where stock market value traded is less than half of
the private sector credit), crisis frequency is 14.7 per cent, while it
is only 5.5 per cent in the other systems (a difference that is
statistically significant at the 1 per cent level). (2) Of course, this
does not mean that market-based systems are crisis-free--they still have
crises on average every eighteen years. But it means that overall they
tend to be relatively less prone to costly systemic crises. These
findings are consistent with some of the recent literature suggesting
that there may be 'too much finance' if private credit exceeds
a certain percentage of GDP (e.g., Arcand, Berkes and Panizza, 2011);
our findings provide suggestive evidence that in many financial systems,
stock market development may have stability advantages over further
growth in private credit. We intend to explore these relationships in
our further work.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Policy implications and the importance of incentives
These findings have two important policy implications.
First, in line with previous theory and empirical literature, we
show that, as economies develop, services provided by securities markets
become more important than those provided by banks. This was true before
the global financial crisis, and still holds even for the crisis data.
We also provide suggestive evidence that, despite the fact that the
recent financial crisis started in market- based financial systems,
bank-based financial systems generally suffer more from crises. These
finding advertise the costs of policy and institutional impediments to
the evolution of the financial system.
Second, as countries develop and their financial systems move from
bank-based towards market-based, the traditional regulatory approach,
which emphasises compliance with regulatory ratios, becomes less and
less effective. Such a 'Basel-style' approach, which focuses
on symptoms rather than on addressing underlying incentive issues in the
financial sector, can work to some extent in bank-based systems with a
small number of players, but it is increasingly likely to break down in
complex financial systems with developed financial markets and a
multitude of market players. There is therefore a greater need for
properly monitoring and addressing the underlying incentive weaknesses
in market-based systems.
Illustrations of the incentive breakdowns
The need for monitoring and addressing the underlying incentive
issues was illustrated by the incentive breakdowns that contributed to
the sub-prime meltdown. A wide body of literature illustrates that
distorted incentives, at several levels, were a key cause of the US
subprime mortgage crisis. For example, Wallison and Calomiris (2009) and
Calomiris (2011) show that the policies to promote home ownership in the
United States created perverse incentives within official and
quasi-official agencies, contributing to the build-up of exposures in
subprime mortgages, and to forbearance in the regulatory oversight of
the risks. Similarly, Levine (2010) finds that the design,
implementation, and maintenance of financial policies in 1996-2006 were
primary causes of the US financial system's demise. He examines and
rejects the view that the collapse was only due to the popping of the
housing bubble and the herding behaviour of financiers selling
increasingly complex and questionable financial products. Rather, the
evidence indicates that regulatory agencies were aware of the growing
fragility of the financial system associated with their policies during
the decade before the crisis and yet chose not to modify those policies,
under pressure from industry and politicians.
The incentive breakdowns were not exclusive to the US subprime
market, of course. Barth, Caprio and Levine (2012), using a broader
sample of developed financial systems, note that regulators often failed
to implement the regulations and powers that they already had. They
point out that, amongst other factors, psychological bias in favour of
the industry, similar to that prevailing in sport, where referees
regularly call games in favour of home teams, operates in finance (see
also the literature on regulatory capture, eg Kane, 2001). In the
authors' view, therefore, the key issue to address is not
necessarily more regulation (although some additional regulations may be
appropriate), but how to get regulators to enforce the rules.
The global financial crisis was thus a stark reminder of the
crucial role of incentives in the financial market. In the run-up to the
crisis, market discipline did not play its role because the underlying
conditions for it to work were not met. In particular, market
players' incentives were distorted and they did not have access to
the necessary information. Many instruments were allowed to become
highly complex and non transparent. Many institutions were also allowed
to become too complex, too interconnected, and too big to fail
(Otker-Robe et al., 2011; Blundell-Wignall et al., 2012). Information on
interconnections and exposures of financial institutions was lacking.
The increasing use of over-the-counter financial derivatives enabled
financial institutions to transfer or to take on risk in non transparent
ways, and to do so rapidly. Within financial institutions, there were
serious principal/ agent problems related to the nature of ownership and
the structure of executive compensation that favoured risk-taking and
higher short-term returns to the longer-term detriment of shareholders.
The assessment of the risks of the entities and instruments fell to
specialised bodies, such as the rating agencies and auditing firms, but
the ability of these agencies to conduct independent due diligence was
limited in large part by conflicts of interest. In such a situation,
effective market discipline could not function (Rajan, 2010).
Compounding the incentive problems in the financial market,
financial regulators themselves also continue to face important
conflicts of interest. For some, this arises from conflicting mandates;
for example, some regulators are mandated to promote financial system
development as well as to prudentially supervise it. Some regulators
lack independence, and even regulators that are legally independent find
it often difficult to withstand pressures from the industry. (3) The
'revolving door' of staff between the regulatory authorities
and the industry- unavoidable to some extent, because industry
background and familiarity with the instruments and activities help in
understanding risks--resulted in the perception of conflicts of interest
for some individual supervisors (Kane, 2007).
Issues with the policy response so far
As part of the policy response to the global financial crisis, the
Financial Stability Board (2009) has developed an agenda of reform, and
the Basel Committee has prepared new capital and liquidity requirements
(as part of the so-called Basel III). New legislation has been passed or
is being prepared also at the national level. For example, the
Dodd-Frank Act is being implemented in the United States. (4)
While the reform initiatives go some way towards addressing the
incentive breakdowns highlighted in the run-up to the crisis, there are
significant implementation challenges. The prevalent regulatory
approaches rely too much on 'symptomatic treatment' and, as a
result, fail to address perverse incentives faced by financial
institutions, market participants, regulators, supervisors and
politicians.
Underlying these initiatives is the belief that the crisis would
not have occurred if only the regulatory standards had been more
comprehensive and sufficiently extensive, and if only the supervisors
had had more extensive discretionary authority and resources. So, the
deficiencies that caused the crisis are supposedly eliminated by
ever-more complex sets of rules and regulations. However, in the United
States, where the global financial crisis started, the regulations were
already quite complicated and supervisory discretion and resources were
extensive during the pre-crisis period. Internationally, the complexity
of the banking rules had already increased significantly before the
crisis with the introduction of Basel II. Nevertheless, private
risk-taking at public expense reached unprecedented levels.
No matter how well intentioned and executed the Basel III redesign,
Basel is an inherently static framework. As with its predecessors (Basel
I and Basel II), Basel III is likely to be overtaken by events. Risk
weights need to be able to change with the evolution of risks. For
example, capital requirements should take into account the co-dependence
of financial institutions, which can change substantively as the
financial system evolves. This type of regulatory arbitrage and
re-regulation is an inevitable part of regulatory reform that does not
take into account incentive issues in a dynamic, forwardlooking fashion.
How to address incentive issues in an evolving financial system?
Ever more complicated rules, or even more supervisory discretion or
resources, will not address the fundamental problems, unless there is an
appropriate alignment of incentives. On the contrary, introducing
simpler rules that take into account the incentives of market
participants and regulators are less likely to be circumvented by market
participants and easier for supervisors to monitor and enforce. An
example would be to replace current risk-weighted capital adequacy rules
with a simple leverage ratio complemented by loan interest rates. Such
simpler rules, accompanied by increased transparency and appropriate
alignment of incentives, could greatly enhance the role of market
discipline.
As part of a more fundamental solution, Cihak, Demirguc-Kunt and
Johnston (2012) propose regular 'incentive audits' to help
identify and address those perverse incentives, before they give rise to
systemic risk. The paper outlines an approach to the regulation of
financial systems that would place issues of asymmetric information and
incentives at its centre rather than as an afterthought. The proposed
'incentive audit' is a new tool to better identify perverse
incentives faced by financial institutions, market participants and
regulators, before they give rise to systemic risk.
There is a particularly great need for properly monitoring and
addressing the underlying incentive weaknesses in market-based systems,
as illustrated for example by the incentive breakdowns that contributed
to the subprime meltdown in the US. Therefore, carrying out incentive
audits, while relevant in any financial system, would be particularly
useful in market-based systems.
Conclusion
In this article, we have brought together two distinct but related
streams of recent research on the financial sector. One is the
literature on financial structures, which finds, amongst other things,
that, as economies develop, services provided by financial markets
become comparatively more important than those provided by banks. It
also suggests that less bank-centric systems are less prone to systemic
crises. The second stream is the regulation literature, which emphasises
the central role of incentives in the financial sector. It points out
that the challenge of financial sector regulation, highlighted by the
global financial crisis, is to align private incentives with public
interest without taxing or subsidising private risk-taking.
Our core observation is that, as financial systems develop from
bank-based to market-based, the traditional regulatory approach that
relies on banking ratios becomes less effective. There is therefore a
greater need for properly monitoring and addressing the underlying
incentive weaknesses in market-based systems--as illustrated for example
by the incentive breakdowns that contributed to the subprime meltdown in
the US. In other words, tools such as 'incentive audits',
while relevant in any financial system, would be especially useful in
market-based systems.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D. and Zilibotti, F. (1997), 'Was Prometheus unbound
by chance? Risk, diversification, and growth', Journal of Political
Economy, 105, pp. 709-75.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (1999), 'Diversity of opinion and
financing of new technologies', European Economic Review, 39, pp.
179-209.
--(2000), Comparing Financial Systems, Cambridge MA, MIT Press.
Arcand, J., Berkes, E. and Panizza, U. (2011), 'Too much
finance?', VoxEU.
Barth, J.R., Caprio, G. and Levine, R. (2012), Guardians of
Finance: Making Regulators Work for Us, Cambridge MA, MIT Press.
Beck, T. and Levine, R. (2004), 'Stock markets, banks, and
growth: panel evidence', Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, pp.
423-42.
BlundelI-Wignall, A., Atkinson, P.E. and Roulet, C. (2012),
'The business models of large interconnected banks and the lessons
of the financial crisis', National Institute Economic Review, 221,
July.
Boot, A.W.A. and Thakor, A. (1997), 'Financial system
architecture', Review of Financial Studies, 10, pp. 693-733.
--(2000), 'Can relationship banking survive
competition?', Journal of Finance, 55, pp. 679-713.
Boyd, J.H. and Smith, B.D. (1998), 'The evolution of debt and
equity markets in economic development', Economic Theory, 12, pp.
519-60.
Calomiris, C. (2011), 'An incentive-robust programme for
financial reform', The Manchester School, 79, pp. 39-72.
Cihak, M., Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Johnston, R.B. (2012), 'Good
regulation needs to fix the broken incentives', Working Paper,
World Bank, Washington, DC.
Cihak, M., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Mohseni, A. and Martinez Peria, M.
(2012), 'Banking regulation and supervision around the world:
post-crisis update', Policy Research Paper, World Bank.
Cihak, M. and Tieman, A. (2011), 'Quality of financial sector
regulation and supervision around the world', in Eijffinger, S. and
Masciandaro, D. (Eds), Handbook of Central Banking, Financial Regulation
and Supervision, Edward Elgar Publishing.
Demirguc-Kunt, A., Feyen, E. and Levine, R. (2012), 'The
evolving importance of banks and securities markets', The World
Bank Economic Review (forthcoming).
Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (1998), 'Law, finance,
and firm growth', Journal of Finance, 53, pp. 2107-37.
Dewatripont, M. and Maskin, E. (1995), 'Credit efficiency in
centralized and decentralized economies', Review of Economic
Studies, 62, pp. 541-55. Financial Stability Board (2009),
Improving Financial Regulation.
Kane, E. (2001), 'Dynamic inconsistency of capital
forbearance: longrun vs. short-run effects of too-big-to-fail
policymaking, Pacific Basin Financial Journal, 9, 4 (August), pp.
281-99.
--(2007), 'Basel II: a contracting perspective,' Journal
of Financial
Services Research, 32(I), pp. 39-53, October.
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2010), 'Resolution of banking
crisis: the good, the bad, and the ugly', Working Paper 10/146,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Levine, R. (2002), 'Bank-based or market-based financial
systems: which is better?', Journal of Financial Intermediation,
11, pp. 398-428.
--(2010), 'An autopsy of the U.S. financial system', NBER
Working Paper No. 15956, April.
Levine, R. and Zervos, S. (1998), 'Stock markets, banks, and
economic growth', American Economic Review, 88, pp. 537-58.
Otker-Robe, I., Narain, A., Ilyina, A. and Surti, J. (2011),
'The too-important-to-fail conundrum: impossible to ignore and
difficult
to resolve', IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/11/12. Rajan, R.G.
(1992), 'Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and
arms length debt', Journal of Finance, 47, pp. 1367-400.
--(2010), Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the
World Economy, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Song, F. and Thakor, A.V. (2012), 'Financial system
architecture and the co-evolution of bank and capital markets',
Economic Journal, (forthcoming).
Wallison, P.J. and Calomiris, C.W. (2009), The last trillion-dollar
commitment: the destruction of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac', Journal
of Structured Finance, Spring, pp. 71-80.
NOTES
(1) The quantile regressions model the relation between log real
GDP per capita and financial development at the specific percentiles (or
quantiles) of log real GDP per capita.
(2) These calculations use the systemic banking crisis definition
of Laeven and Valencia (2010) but the results are qualitatively similar
when this is replaced by alternative (broader) crisis definitions from
the paper.
(3) Even supervisors that are independent in principle can be
overruled for political purposes in practice. For example, US
supervisors did raise alarms over the risks of subprime lending, but a
significant tightening of the prudential practices did not occur before
the crisis, reflecting pressures from the industry and lawmakers
(Levine, 2010). Reviews of compliance with the relevant international
standards (such as the Basel Core Principles) around the world find that
some of the weakest areas relate to operational independence of
regulators (Cihak and Tieman, 2011).
(4) Cihak, Demirguc-Kunt, Mohseni and Martinez Peria (2012) provide
an update on regulatory developments in countries based on the World
Bank's Banking Regulation and Supervision survey.
* World Bank, Washington, D.C. Emails:
[email protected] and
[email protected]. The views expressed in this paper are those
of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the World Bank
or World Bank policy. The authors' thinking on financial structure
and incentives has benefited from discussions with Ross Levine and Barry
Johnston, respectively, as well as from comments at a World Bank
seminar. Any remaining errors are those of the authors.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics
Standard
Variable Mean deviation Maximum Minimum
Log of real GDP per
capita (constant
2000 USD) 7.6 1.6 10.9 4.1
Private credit 39.3 35.9 319.7 0.0
Stock value traded 28.8 57.4 632.3 0.0
Stock market
capitalisation 47.7 58.4 561.4 0.0
Securities market
capitalisation 59.1 71.2 588.3 0.0
Source: World Bank's Global Financial Development Database.
Note: Calculated from available annual data for 1970-2010.