Policy evaluation in a time of austerity: introduction.
Bryson, Alex ; Dorsett, Richard ; Portes, Jonathan 等
As Phil Davies (pp. R41-52) notes, the last government made a
series of high-profile commitments to the idea of evidence-based policy.
Central to this philosophy was a culture of evaluation whereby potential
and actual policies were scrutinised and appraised in order to build and
refine a knowledge base of 'what works'. While this was far
from consistently applied, and the results of evaluations were not
always comfortable reading for the government (for example, the very
mixed results from the National Evaluation of Sure Start), on the whole
there was a presumption that major social policy initiatives should be
subject to independent evaluation.
The approach of the new government appears somewhat different.
Although the Treasury has maintained its public commitment to
evidence-based policymaking, research and evaluation budgets have been
severely squeezed. Faced with a choice between service delivery and
policy evaluation, it may be tempting to regard evaluation as a luxury
that government can ill afford, at least in the short term.
We reflect briefly on why such a response may be shortsighted and
offer some thoughts on how the approach to policy evaluation may adapt
to these more straitened times. This is a theme that is taken up in a
number of places by the papers in this issue.
The key reason why evaluation continues to be relevant in times of
financial austerity is that it provides the evidence needed for informed
decision-making. This is especially relevant when resources are scarce,
a point made forcefully by Rachel Glennerster (pp. R4-14) in her review
of policy evaluation in developing countries. Evaluation evidence,
including the assessment of the costs and benefits of policy, offers the
most direct insight to inform such decisions, as Haroon Chowdry (pp.
R53-64) makes clear. Policies found through rigorous analysis to be both
effective and cost-effective are strong candidates for investment.
Furthermore, broader explorations--including qualitative analyses such
as the one discussed by Heather Rolfe (pp. R65-76)--can provide a deeper
understanding of the way policy is implemented and how and why a policy
seems (not) to work, sometimes suggesting ways of adapting policies to
better achieve their aims.
Evaluation can be costly but it is often a means of saving money.
The recently-completed Employment Retention and Advancement (ERA)
demonstration (Hendra et al., 2011) provides an edifying example of how
a thorough evaluation can help guide policymakers away from wasteful
spending. Davies and Chowdry outline the features of the intervention.
The evaluation revealed that impacts for the first two years were large
and significant but subsequently disappeared. Overall, the intervention
failed the cost-benefit test for lone parents. The evidence cautions
strongly against national roll-out of the policy (Chowdry). Evaluations
of labour market programmes typically confine themselves to a shorter
period over which to observe impacts. Had the ERA evaluation only
observed outcomes for two years, say, the conclusion would have been
very different, with significant financial implications.
Properly conducted, evaluations offer an objective assessment of
the appropriateness of policy, thus enabling governments to deploy
available funds in the most cost-effective manner. When the Work and
Pensions Committee asked the employment minister, the Rt Hon Chris
Grayling MP, why the Department for Work and Pensions (DWP) had decided
not to commission an independent evaluation of the Future Jobs Fund
(FJF) he cautioned of the "... danger in financially straitened
times that we spend vast amounts of money evaluating things that we are
no longer going to do." (1) The decision to discontinue the FJF was
not based on evaluation evidence and, consequently, it is impossible to
establish its cost-effectiveness. One argument for ending the FJF was
that, from June 2011, the Work Programme has provided a unified
mechanism for helping individuals move into sustained employment.
Unfortunately, little allowance has been made for a robust quantitative
evaluation of this new policy. The way it was introduced--nationwide and
with no trialling--means that attempts to estimate its effectiveness
face very difficult challenges. Given that both the FJF and the Work
Programme involve the expenditure of billions of pounds of public money,
this may be a false economy.
Convincing and impartial evaluations often require the involvement
of external researchers. This can be achieved in various ways. Over the
past decade, a number of commissioning departments have set up framework
agreements as a means of channelling such input. Under this arrangement,
external contractors compete to become framework members who can then be
invited--on either a competitive or non-competitive basis--to submit
proposals for discrete evaluation (or other) projects. Alternatively,
departments can provide support for external centres. Stephen Machin and
Sandra McNally (pp. R15-25) report on the contribution of the Centre for
the Economics of Education (jointly funded, until recently, by the
Department for Education and the Department for Business, Innovation and
Skills) to the evaluation of schools policies in England. The Low Pay
Commission (LPC) is an independent statutory body set up under the
National Minimum Wage Act 1998. Tim Butcher (pp. R26-40) reflects on how
the LPC's programme of evaluation research has influenced the
evolution of the National Minimum Wage, while Justin van de Ven (pp.
77-89) reports on analyses exploring the potential impact of a new
pension scheme for those on modest incomes, which was funded under the
LPC's research programme. A recent interesting model for providing
funding is the Education Endowment Foundation, a charity founded by the
Sutton Trust and the Impetus Trust and responsible for using a large
grant from the Department for Education to commission projects that will
identify and evaluate ways of improving achievement levels among
disadvantaged children.
Of course, the funds available to support evaluation are limited
and there is a separate point about whether and how there might be scope
to deliver robust evaluation evidence at lower cost. There are no
universal laws here and each policy or pilot must be considered in its
own right. However, it is important to keep in mind opportunities for
efficiencies in this regard.
The ERA evaluation mentioned above was perhaps as comprehensive an
evaluation as it is possible to imagine. The intervention itself was
costly (involving substantial financial payments, training of special
advisers and time-consuming delivery of support and guidance) but the
evaluation involved a lengthy design phase, close monitoring of
implementation, detailed manipulation of administrative data, large
longitudinal survey data collection, extensive qualitative interviewing
with recipients and providers of the service, careful estimation of the
impact of the programme and, lastly, a cost-benefit analysis (which
itself involved a substantial cost-collection exercise). Comprehensive
and expensive evaluations such as this are unlikely to be commissioned
in the foreseeable future. However, smaller evaluations can also provide
high-quality evidence. As Rachel Glennerster points out, even random
assignment evaluations, which are generally regarded as being more
credible than alternative approaches, can be afforded in certain
circumstances (often, it is not the randomisation itself which is
costly). A good example is Dorsett and Smeaton (2008) which randomly
assigned to older benefit claimants the requirement to participate fully
in an active labour market programme. By tracking employment and benefit
outcomes using administrative data, compelling evidence of programme
effectiveness was provided. The point here is that the nature of the
intervention was such that a much more limited evaluation was feasible
and could provide reliable impact estimates at a fraction of the cost of
the ERA demonstration. Whether such a pared-down approach is appropriate
to other evaluations depends on a number of factors, including whether
the programme is new (as opposed to an existing programme being extended
to a new client group) and whether the outcomes of interest exist in
readily-available administrative data. Certain conditions still must be
met, of course. Rolfe reports here on a random assignment evaluation
that was less successful.
One legitimate criticism often heard from politicians and senior
policymakers is that evaluation evidence, while interesting, comes too
late to influence policy as directly as it might. There is thus a
premium on researchers working with policymakers to ensure timely
feedback. Of course, certain types of evidence simply cannot be produced
on short order. The ERA demonstration is again a good example;
estimating longer-term impacts required observing what happens to people
over a five-year period. However, some types of evidence can be provided
more quickly. Qualitative evidence, for instance, can provide early
insights and, importantly, highlight practical issues that have a clear
relevance to the effectiveness of policy. Furthermore, in some cases
(such as van de Ven in this issue), it may be possible to use economic
models to estimate in advance what the effect of a particular
intervention may be. Such an approach requires that the policy change is
amenable to economic modelling. Changes to the tax/transfer system, for
instance, involve an amendment to individuals' incentives to work
that can be explored ex ante (see, for example, Brewer et al., 2006, for
such an evaluation of Working Families' Tax Credit). However, there
is an unavoidable fact that good evaluation evidence often takes time to
materialise. While ministers may be impatient to see results, the
quality and usefulness of the evidence base in the UK would be improved
were this key point borne in mind, not least in the commissioning of
research.
The academic and research community is interested in the
effectiveness of government policies and wants to carry out evaluation
studies even without government funding. Such studies are of clear
public benefit and should be of interest to government. However, the
data required to carry out evaluation studies are often subject to rigid
access restrictions. This is entirely appropriate given the potential
for disclosure when working with individual-level data. However, while
issues of data security and anonymity remain paramount, this should not
be an argument for stasis. Recently, there have been some improvements
in facilitating safe access to individual-level datasets for research
purposes. We very much welcome this and hope that it is the beginning of
a trend that would extend to ever more government-held datasets. This
offers a means of democratising research and allowing the data to
achieve their potential as a public good. Taken together, the papers in
this edition make a compelling case for robust, independent evaluation
being at the heart of government efforts to deploy policies that improve
citizens' welfare.
doi: 10.1177/002795011221900101
REFERENCES
Brewer, M., Duncan, A., Shephard, A. and Suarez, M. (2006),
'Did working families' tax credit work? The impact of in-work
support on labour supply in Great Britain', Labor Economics
December, 13(6), pp. 699-720.
Dorsett, R. and Smeaton, D. (2008), Mandating Intensive Activity
Period for Jobseekers aged 50+: Final Report of the Quantitative
Evaluation, DWP Research Report 500.
Hendra, R., Riccio, J., Dorsett, R., Greenberg, D., Knight, G.,
Phillips, J., Robins, P., Vegeris, S. and Walter, J., with Hill, A.,
Ray, K. and Smith, J. (2011), Breaking the Low-pay, No-pay cycle: Final
Evidence from the UK Employment Retention and Advancement (ERA)
Demonstration, DWP Research Report 765.
NOTE
(1) House of Commons Work and Pensions Committee, Youth
Unemployment and the Future Jobs Fund, First report of 2010/-11, HC 472.
Alex Bryson, Richard Dorsett and Jonathan Portes *
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research. E-mail:
[email protected]