The future of housing finance.
Davis, E. Philip
Housing finance was at the epicentre of the global financial
crisis. It raises a variety of risks which change over time and are
notoriously difficult to manage, including credit, interest rate and
market risk and mortgage pre-payment risks. The welfare consequences of
these risks are particularly important because house buying is usually
the largest financial transaction households make, and the cost of
housing means that they cannot usually hedge their exposures to these
risks. As recent events have shown, housing finance is also central to
financial intermediation and stability. Innovation may have increased
the supply of housing finance but it may also have heightened the
concentration of risks. There is an extraordinarily diverse set of
national models of housing finance. It is natural to ask which one is
best, whether they can be transferred across national boundaries and how
to undertake reform. Many regulatory issues at both micro-prudential and
macro-prudential level are wide open.
Accordingly, NIESR, supported financially by the ESRC, Money Macro
and Finance Group, and the Centre for Macroeconomics, held a conference
at the Bank of England on 12 September to discuss these issues from the
point of view of leading experts from around the world. This edition of
the National Institute Economic Review incorporates articles based on
five of the presentations at the conference.
Angus Armstrong and Philip Davis challenge the widespread
supposition that the house price and lending boom of the 2000s was the
unique and key cause of the financial crisis that began in 2007, in the
light of the fact that there was a similar boom in the late 1980s which
did not lead directly to a global systemic banking crisis. They contend
that the strong parallels between the cycles found both statistically
and econometrically suggest that the received wisdom is incorrect and
other factors than the housing boom caused the crisis, while
macroprudential policy is overly targeted at the control of house prices
and lending per se.
Accordingly, there is a need for further research to capture
distinctive structural and conjunctural factors underlying the recent
crisis which differ from the earlier boom, which macroprudential policy
needs to take into account. Key distinguishing factors may include the
initial level of debt/income and the related impact of inflation, the
impact of lower interest rates in the recent boom and global contagion
via liquidity in the recent episode; and the ready availability of
credit from mortgage bond issuance which was much less important in the
1980s. Also changing owner occupation rates and patterns of population
densities may have had a markedly different effect across the booms. And
of course the behaviour of banks and financial markets differed.
Mortgage bonds and bank behaviour are at the forefront of most of
the other papers. For Franklin Allen, James Barth and Glen Yago, the
recent financial crisis has underlined the importance of the interaction
of such financial innovations and the housing market. They consider five
major innovations relevant to housing finance, including not only
securitised mortgages but also mortgages per se, specialised housing
finance institutions; government interventions in housing finance in the
US during the Great Depression; and covered bonds. The history of these
innovations and their positive and negative aspects are discussed.
Notably, a flawed innovation in the US in the 2000s was the private
securitisation giving rise to lax underwriting that can in turn be
traced to perverse incentives. It is evident that there is a great deal
of 'path dependence' in housing finance and therefore radical
innovations from elsewhere are not always easily adopted. The scope of
government involvement in the US for example was mainly developed during
the Great Depression and is firmly rooted in practice. Covered bonds
that are widely employed elsewhere are at a disadvantage in the US due
to higher capital requirements and caution of the FDIC over their senior
status.
International comparison shows that outcomes of housing finance
systems vary markedly, and with rich countries such as Germany and
Switzerland at the bottom of the scale it is by no means clear that a
high owner occupation rate is optimal. Future innovations to help the
stability of the housing market are also suggested, notably more equity
financing to enhance affordability, better management of risks in
securitisations, appropriate pricing of housing and better credit
analysis. Interestingly, they do not cite the need for recourse that was
an Achilles heel of much of the US system, giving rise to
'strategic default'.
Focusing more closely on topics covered by Allen et al., Susan
Wachter contends that housing finance and, specifically, the subprime
private label securitisation market in the US, was the core of the
global financial crisis. Excessive debt expansion in respect of leverage
and credit quality in the run-up to the crisis resulted in credit risk,
which was under-identified and mispriced ex ante, and in systemic risk.
Much of the problem can be traced to the loss of monopoly on behalf of
the government sponsored enterprises (GSEs) that had previously
effectively enforced a cautiously leveraged 30-year fixed rate mortgage
as standard. Breach of the monopoly in the 1990s and 2000s via the
growth of private securitisers allowed a proliferation of riskier and
poorly underwritten loans whose default risk was massively underpriced.
Competitive firms failed to internalise three forms of foreclosure
externality, linked to fire sales, bank loss and borrower losses which
meant their lending decisions boosted aggregate risk. The author
contends that some progress has been made in US regulation, for example
in stress testing, better infrastructure of monitoring aggregate risk,
and preclusion under Dodd-Frank of some risky forms of mortgage lending.
But the necessary fundamental reform of the US securitisation system has
yet to be brought about.
Lawrence Schembri shows that the Canadian system of housing finance
proved to be resilient and efficient during the global financial crisis
and its aftermath, in contrast to that of the US described in the
previous two papers. The Canadian system's effectiveness is the
result of a rigorous and mostly Federally-based prudential regulatory
and supervisory regime (implementing principal- rather than rule-based
approaches) coupled with targeted government guarantees of mortgage
insurance and securitisation products with for example mandatory
insurance of loans with LTVs of over 80 per cent. Compared with the US,
the small number of large and diversified banks is probably also key for
stability in Canada. Shorter maturity of typical mortgages than in the
US helps asset and liability matching and ensures borrowers share
interest rate risk; there are lesser tax subsidies, and there is also
better scrutiny of risk management practices in securitisations. Full
legal recourse in the case of default is mandatory, reducing incentives
to default markedly.
In the post-crisis period, household debt levels and house prices
have risen in Canada, owing, in part, to accommodative monetary
conditions. These vulnerabilities were mitigated by tightening
macroprudential policy, including mortgage insurance rules, and
strengthening mortgage underwriting standards. But the outcome shows
that with the macroprudential tools currently in operation, improving
credit standards on individual loans is easier than affecting
macroeconomic trends in credit growth. The Canadian housing finance
framework needs to be adjusted and strengthened by rebalancing the risk
exposures away from the government towards the private sector
participants in the housing finance market. Although some measures have
already been taken for this purpose, more adjustments may be needed to
create the right incentives and achieve a sustainable rebalancing in
risk exposures. Measures should also be considered to open a liquid
private label securitisation market in Canada; whereas this could help
sustain the activity of smaller lenders, the history of such a market in
the US lends grounds for caution.
Finally, the paper by Jesper Berg and Christian Bentzen describes
the Danish mortgage system by comparing it with that of the UK. The
Danish system has attracted a great deal of attention as a type of
narrow banking model where mortgage loans are financed by specialised
institutions that issue bonds with cash flows that match that of the
mortgage loans. Thereby, the Danish system outsources many of the risks
that are usually kept on the balance sheet of banks to bond investors,
inter alia improving financial stability. Measured in terms of four
criteria (affordability, robustness to house price falls, resilience to
a crisis in terms of ability to lend, and absence of government
subsidies), the Danish system performed better during the financial
crisis than the UK one. For example mortgage spreads remained markedly
lower and there was no credit crunch for mortgages in the wake of 2008.
A strength of the Danish system and an example to other countries is
rapid foreclosure procedures which reduce loss-given-default as well as
reducing default incentives. The authors also highlight transfer of the
more transparent risks to investors and the safety valves in relation to
credit risks that are opaque and therefore more difficult to transfer.
But again, the Danish system is deeply rooted in law and tradition and
would be hard to transplant wholesale to other countries.
E. Philip Davis *
* NIESR and Brunel University. E-mail: e_philip_davis:msn.com.