Scotland: currency options and public debt.
Armstrong, Angus ; Ebell, Monique
This paper considers which currency option would be best for an
independent Scotland. We examine three currency options: being part of a
sterling currency zone, adopting the euro, or having an independent
currency. No currency option is the best when considered against all
criteria. Therefore, making the decision requires deciding which
criteria are most important. Recent events around the world,
particularly in Europe, show that it is essential to consider how an
independent Scotland would seek to adjust to adverse economic
circumstances. In economists' terms, it is important to think
through the 'off-equilibrium' adjustment paths of each of the
currency options. The amount of public debt, and so the capacity for a
fiscal response, is a critical determinant of these paths and therefore
of the optimal currency choice. Since commitment to a currency union by
an independent country can only be conditional, an independent Scotland
might find it optimal to abandon the currency union in the future if the
financial stability advantages to having its own currency begin to
outweigh any disadvantages due to trade and transactions costs.
Keywords: currency union; monetary union; optimal currency area;
debt sustainability; speculative attacks
JEL Classifications: E52; E58; F31; F33; F36; H60; H63; R113
"It is patently obvious that periodic balance of payments
crises will remain an integral feature of the international economic
system as long as fixed exchange rates and rigid wage and price levels
prevent the international price system from fulfilling a natural role in
the adjustment process."
Robert A. Mundell, A Theory of Optimal Currency Areas (1961)
Introduction
The choice of currency is integral to the economics of
independence. It matters much more than simply the notes and coins in
peoples' pockets. It determines how monetary policy is managed,
whether there is any scope for exchange rate adjustment, the exposure to
financial sector risks and even the scope for fiscal policy. In many
ways, the choice of currency arrangement will determine the economic
governance of an independent Scotland.
This paper considers the main currency options available to an
independent Scotland. Each option offers a different trade-off between
minimising exchange costs to support transactions across the border
versus the scope for setting independent economic policy. The Treasury
has argued that as long as Scotland is within the UK and there are
fiscal transfers between regions, then it is optimal to have sterling as
the single currency. The Scottish government has argued that if Scotland
becomes an independent country, a sterling monetary union involving a
joint governance structure of the Bank of England would be its preferred
arrangement. (1) However, the Treasury has also repeatedly stated that
it is unlikely to agree to such a monetary union. On this key issue the
electorate is likely to be left with a stalemate.
In our view, it is not enough just to consider which currency
option is most convenient for minimising the cost of transactions across
the border. Recent events around the world, particularly in Europe, show
that it is essential to consider how an independent Scotland would seek
to adjust to adverse economic circumstances. In economists' terms,
it is as important to think through the 'off-equilibrium'
adjustment paths of each of the currency options. The amount of public
debt, and so the capacity for a fiscal response, is critical to these
paths. We argue that the amount of public debt is therefore critical to
the optimal currency choice. There are enough examples of indebted
countries in currency unions that endured destructive feedback loops and
eventual severe recession to warrant full and thorough consideration.
The welfare costs from the disorganisation which follows far outweigh
any marginal effect on trade. A recent study by Laeven and Valencia
(2012) shows that there have been 218 currency crises between 1970 and
2011, 65 of which coincided with sovereign debt crises. The costs of the
instability are an order of magnitude larger than the gains from
increased trade. (2)
Independent Scotland
The optimal choice of currency for any country depends on its
economic circumstances. An independent Scotland would be fundamentally
different from Scotland today. Its initial economic conditions will
depend heavily on how the existing assets and liabilities and
institutions of the current UK are divided between an independent
Scotland and the rest of the UK. The Scottish Government's (2013b)
White Paper suggests that its preferred boundary for measuring the
public sector is HM Treasury's (2013) Whole Government Accounts
(WGA). (3) These are based on commercial principles and represent the
consolidated accounts of all audited public sector entities, meaning
that inter-government claims (for example, the Bank of England's
holdings of assets from quantitative easing) cancel out. It includes
claims on physical assets, off-balance sheet exposures (e.g. the cost of
financial sector interventions and Private Finance Initiative
contracts), accruals arising from past activities (such as public sector
pensions) and certain provisions and contingent liabilities. Natural
resources and future revenues and expenses based on current policies are
excluded.
Despite the fluidity of international borders, history offers
surprisingly few precedents on how to divide up national assets and
liabilities. There have been only a few cases of states seceding from a
larger state that have been cordial and not involved war or the end of
colonialism or communism. Two recent examples of 'friendly'
separations which offer some guidance are the so-called 'velvet
divorce' of Czechoslovakia in 1993 and the ultimately failed
campaign for Quebec separation from Canada in 1995. In general, physical
assets are divided on the basis of location, while non-physical assets
and liabilities were divided on the basis of relative population size.
The Vienna Convention of 1983 which sought to set out some principles
for the division of debt in new states proved to be controversial and
has not been ratified by any major advanced economy and so has not come
into force.
While there would be many public sector assets and liabilities to
be divided, three important issues to consider are the remaining North
Sea oil and gas reserves, the UK public sector debt and the Bank of
England. For a full discussion of the issues involved see Armstrong and
Ebell (2014, forthcoming). While the onshore location of physical assets
is clear, offshore assets are less certain. Most maritime experts expect
that the starting point for negotiations over the oil and gas reserves
will be the median line which would award approximately 90 per cent of
the remaining reserves to an independent Scotland. (4) Using the Office
of Budget Responsibility's (OBR) estimate of the cash value of the
tax revenue from remaining reserves, Scotland's 90 per cent share
would be worth around 50.4 billion [pounds sterling]. Scotland would be
a large exporter of oil and gas while the UK would become a significant
importer. (5)
There are a number of issues around how the UK public debt would be
divided. The first is the measure of debt to be used. In 2011-12 the WGA
show public sector net liabilities of 1,347 billion [pounds sterling]
compared to the narrow public sector net debt (PSND) measure of 1,106
billion [pounds sterling] and gross debt or the Maastricht measure of
1,325 billion [pounds sterling]. We assume that gross debt is the basis
for negotiation because it is the most common international measure and
is similar in value to the WGA figures used to measure the assets. The
next issue is how the debt is divided. Following the Czechoslovakia
precedent we assume this is on a relative population basis, which has
been acknowledged by the Scottish government. (6) According to the OBR,
UK public sector debt on a gross basis in 2016/17 (when independence
would take effect) is projected to be 1744 [pounds sterling] or 94 per
cent of UK GDP. Allocating a population share of 8.4 per cent of the
debt and the GDP which includes a geographic share of oil to Scotland
yields an initial debt level of 146 billion [pounds sterling]. This
implies that Scotland's debt to GDP ratio would be approximately 81
per cent, while for the continuing UK it would rise to 104 per cent. (7)
The Scottish government's (2013b) White Paper and statements
from the First Minister also make it clear that sterling and the Bank of
England are viewed as assets to be shared in the event of independence.
(8) After all, the Bank of England is the central bank of all nations of
the UK. Since the Bank of England's balance sheet is primarily
financial (rather than physical), there is a reasonable claim that an
independent Scotland would be entitled to a population share of its
assets and liabilities. Yet the Bank's balance sheet is already
consolidated in the WGA and therefore part of the 'net' asset
figures referred to above. The most recent estimate of the net worth of
the Bank of England is 3.35 billion [pounds sterling], of which a
population share would be 280 million [pounds sterling].
However, the real issue is that sterling has a valuable reputation
of being a 'hard currency' and therefore is accepted as a
sound store of value. The Scottish government rightly sees this property
as being extremely valuable, especially to a new state. But as with all
currencies, sterling's value over the long term depends on
controlling its supply, which can only be assured if the issuing state
controls its finances and honours its commitment to pay its debts.
Governments since Charles II have not defaulted on debt or eroded its
real value through excessive and unexpected inflation. (9) This track
record over such a long time period is unique. Sterling is perceived as
being a sound store of value, which lowers the cost of borrowing. Yet
this property is inalienable to the UK government; it is part of its
history. The UK government may choose to share sterling's
reputational value by extending the powers of the Bank of England, but
it cannot divide and transfer part of its reputation to another
government like a physical asset, even if it were inclined to do so.
(10)
Currency options
The main currency options for an independent Scotland are
summarised in table 1. Scotland could, in theory, choose to use any
currency as legal tender, but there are probably three realistic
options: to introduce a new currency, to use sterling or to use the
euro. Each of these options has at least two variants shown in the
second column in the table. For example, Scotland could reintroduce its
own currency, and the policy arrangement could either be a floating or
fixed/pegged exchange rate. Similarly, there are two broad categories of
currency unions; an informal currency union and a monetary union
(sometimes called a formal currency union). The Scottish government
could choose to use sterling or the euro in an informal currency union.
This would not necessarily require the agreement of the authority
issuing the currency. For example, Montenegro uses the euro without the
agreement of the European Union. A fundamentally different currency
arrangement is a monetary union where the central bank is shared between
two or more governments, and operates on behalf of its member regions.
The obvious example is the European Union's supranational central
bank, the European Central Bank, which consists of representatives of
all seventeen members of the eurozone who must act in the interests of
all members rather than the nations they represent. If the UK government
agreed to share control of the Bank of England, and have two independent
governments indemnify it for any losses, this would become a Sterling
Monetary Union. This would require the endorsement and legislation of
the continuing UK government as the Bank of England is constituted under
Acts of the UK Parliament.
Scots pound option
If Scotland were to introduce its own currency, the obvious
disadvantage is that there would be transaction costs for trading,
investing, moving and spending across the border. However, the evidence
from introducing the euro suggests that the impact on trade and welfare
is perhaps less than expected. Dell'Ariccia (1999) shows that the
elimination of exchange rate volatility between fifteen EU states and
Switzerland would have increased bilateral trade by 12 per cent. Using a
different methodology, Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2010) find that
adopting the euro did not have a significant effect on trade compared to
other EU and EEA countries which did not. In a more direct test, Thorn
and Walsh (2002) consider the case of Ireland ending the Irish pound
link to sterling in 1979. They conclude that ending the link "did
not slow the growth of Irish trade with Britain to any significant
effect". (11) Even a casual look at other European countries which
retain their own currency (e.g. Norway, Sweden, Denmark and Switzerland)
does not show obvious disadvantages.
The most important advantage of having a Scottish currency is the
added element of flexibility. A Scottish currency would bring the
greatest degree of autonomy over economic policy and so is perhaps the
most consistent with the notion of economic independence. The Fiscal
Commission Working Group (FCWG) states, "in the long run, the
creation of a new Scottish currency would represent a significant
increase in economic sovereignty, with interest rate and exchange rate
policy being two new policy tools and adjustment mechanisms to support
the Scottish economy". (12) However, this is a double-edged sword;
a newly independent country with no track record and substantial debt
would need to earn the credibility that the greater autonomy and
flexibility will be used appropriately. (13)
The Scottish government would also have full responsibility for
financial stability. Central banks which issue their own currency can
play a special role in supporting financial stability. They have a
unique feature in that, unlike private firms, they need not default. If
the Central Bank of Scotland (CBoS) does not tie the value of its
currency to an asset, such as gold or another currency such as the euro
or sterling, then it has no commitment to exchange its currency for any
other asset. (14) The central bank's only liability is a promise to
repay the bearer, which could be honoured by repaying creditors with
some newly created money. The only limit is that this increase in money
does not violate the inflation target. In periods of financial distress when private agents want to hoard the safest asset, central banks'
supply of liquidity provides an important safety valve. (15)
Sterling currency zone
The attractions of sterling for an independent Scotland are
familiarity, no risk of disruption to existing contracts and that there
would continue to be no transaction costs for exchanges between Scotland
and the rest of the UK. Having prices of goods and services in sterling
on both sides of the border may promote competition, although looking at
the performance of European states which joined the euro compared to
those which retain their own currency, this is likely to be modest.
Although these are clear advantages over both the euro and Scots pound
options, it would be a mistake to confuse familiarity with continuity;
the structure of the economies of an independent Scotland and continuing
UK would be very different compared with their structure within the
Union. (16)
There have been many different types of currency unions. (17) At
one extreme the Scottish government could simply use sterling as its
legal tender without needing any formal permission from the UK
government. This would be a sterling equivalent to
'dollarisation' in Panama for example, or even
Montenegro's unilateral decision to use the euro. A more plausible
sterling currency zone design is that Scotland could form a currency
board arrangement where all sterling notes issued by the Scottish
central bank are backed by sterling deposits at the Bank of England.
This would be similar to the currency arrangements in the Crown
Dependencies (Isle of Man, Jersey and Channel Islands). However,
Scotland would not have influence on either conventional or
unconventional monetary policy (such as the funding for lending scheme
or the asset purchase scheme).
Within an informal currency union an important issue is the extent
to which the Bank of England would provide standard lender of last
resort facilities to financial institutions headquartered in Scotland.
Several UK subsidiaries of foreign banks are members of the Sterling
Monetary Framework and therefore have access to lender of last resort
facilities at the Bank of England. There is no reason why Scottish
banks' subsidiaries in the rest of the UK, which meet the
qualifying prerequisites, would be excluded from the Framework. However,
there is a substantive difference between providing sterling liquidity
to institutions operating in the UK and providing open support
facilities to institutions in what would become an offshore sterling
market.
A sterling monetary union would involve sharing the ownership of
the central bank for the sterling currency zone. The Fiscal Commission
Working Group (2013b) suggests the creation of a supranational central
bank with the Bank of England and Central Bank of Scotland as members or
through a joint ownership and governance structure of the Bank of
England based on population. However, the large difference in size
between Scotland and the rest of the UK is a critical limitation. Based
on a fair division of voting rights, with the rest of the UK ten times
bigger (by population) than an independent Scotland, it is unclear how
this would result in real shared responsibility. Neither is it clear
whether the one-sided monetary union would be very different from the
informal currency union. For example, it has been suggested that perhaps
there could be a Scotland representative on the Monetary Policy
Committee. But it is unclear how a single vote could ever exert any more
influence than at the margin. (18)
A shared central bank also raises the prospect of moral hazard. The
taxpayers of the UK would now have an exposure to an independent
Scotland and the taxpayers in an independent Scotland would have an
exposure to events in the UK. Whenever agents are not directly
responsible for the consequences of their actions there is the
possibility of moral hazard. However, the only realistic scenario is
that the rest of the UK may be required to bail out an independent
Scotland (rather than vice versa). To avoid any prospect of this
outcome, the UK government would require strict and binding limits on
Scotland's fiscal independence. Europe offers an important lesson
on enforcing non bail-out conditions on governments in the midst of a
fiscal crisis. Once the full implications of allowing a default were
understood the infamous no bail-out Clause 125 of the Maastricht Treaty was soon ignored.
In these circumstances, whether a monetary union is effective
depends on whether the UK could impose binding constraints on an
independent Scotland to minimise moral hazard and its risk exposure. Yet
the idea that one country can impose constraints which bind in all
circumstances on another country contradicts the idea of independence.
The Scottish government's White Paper (2013) is very clear that, as
an independent nation the choice of currency arrangement in the future
must always be open to the people of Scotland. This must always be the
case in a democratic nation. Yet it also makes clear to the rest of the
UK that any monetary union would only last as long as it remains in the
interests of Scotland. This contradicts the notion of imposing binding
constraints in all circumstances.
Flandreau (2006) makes a similar point in his assessment of the
Austro-Hungarian Monetary Union; the common central bank delivers a
range of services that are valuable to both parts, but not equally. If
power is proportional to size, the small country has very little control
over common decisions. It is bound by the discipline of the union
without being able to influence decision-making in a way that would
address its own specific interests. Cooperation (that is, participation
in the union) is suboptimal and the small country prefers to quit.
Eurozone
The third realistic currency option is for Scotland to use the euro
as legal tender. The trade benefits in an informal euro currency union
would be dominated by an informal sterling currency union and so we rule
this option out. Scotland is expected to be an EU member and therefore
is very likely to be required to commit to joining the euro at some
unspecified future date. (19) The process involves meeting the
Maastricht convergence criteria on monetary and fiscal conditions. Of
particular note is the requirement to have a stable currency in an ERM
II framework for at least two years before joining the union. This
implies Scotland cannot jump from sterling to the euro but would go
through an interim period with its own currency. No country has joined
the zone without first having a period of time with its own currency. It
is unlikely that Scotland would be allowed to be an EU member and use
the euro on an informal basis. (20) Hence, we will focus our discussion
on the two immediately viable alternatives: a currency union with the
continuing UK and an independent Scottish currency.
Debt and the stability of the currency union
We now focus on the implications of government debt burdens for the
credibility of a currency union. This builds on the
'off-equilibrium' adjustment paths mentioned in the
introduction. Debt matters for the stability of a currency arrangement
because it affects the government's room for manoeuvre when an
adverse shock eventually hits the economy. When a negative shock, say to
tax revenues, hits an economy a credible adjustment plan is required to
return to the long-run equilibrium debt path. When a country has its own
currency, this adjustment can be any combination of fiscal policy,
monetary policy and allowing for the currency to adjust. When a country
uses the currency of another country, such as the junior partner in a
monetary union, the government only has fiscal policy to restore the
economy to full employment equilibrium. Any doubts of investors about
the political commitment to make this fiscal adjustment raises the
prospect of leaving the currency union.
The argument is clearest by contrasting a low debt with a high debt
economy within a currency union. In the low government debt economy,
when a bad shock occurs it can borrow at low cost from international
markets and repay investors when the economy recovers. By contrast, in
the high government debt economy borrowing will be expensive, which will
add to the debt burden and raise doubts about debt sustainability. A
higher interest rate must be paid on new borrowings and as existing debt
is rolled over. At some combination of the government debt level and
investors' risk aversion the option of leaving the currency union
becomes more palatable than the social and political consequences of
making the required fiscal adjustment. Once investors perceive the
political calculus has changed this can bring about the very outcome
they fear. That is, once borrowing costs rise sufficiently, the
incentives for the high debt government to leave the currency union
become obvious to investors, and capital flight and/or a speculative
attack ensue.
Velasco (1996) provides a useful framework for understanding the
impact of government debt on the stability of a currency union. (21)
Governments look to minimise the cost of adjusting or transitioning back
to full employment. The cost of using either fiscal or monetary policy
in isolation increases with the size of the adjustment. This implies
that, in general, being limited to use only fiscal policy, as in a
one-sided currency union or as the junior partner of a monetary union,
will always be more costly than using a combination of fiscal and
monetary means, as is possible with an own currency. The added cost of
being restricted to only fiscal adjustment is the cost of remaining in
the currency union. This cost is balanced by the benefits of remaining
in a currency union and the costs of leaving.
In our previous work we show that within a monetary union sovereign
borrowing costs are increasing in the levels of government debt and
deficits. (22) When a heavily indebted country which already runs a
substantial deficit seeks to increase its borrowing further, the
interest rate at which it can borrow might rise substantially. This can
lead to a vicious circle of higher borrowing costs which further
increase deficits and debt, once again increasing borrowing costs, as
some southern eurozone members have experienced in recent years. The
rising social, economic and political cost of relying only on fiscal
adjustment for a heavily indebted country might call the credibility of
the monetary union into question: is it really better to pursue the more
costly fiscal-only adjustment and remain in the union? Or is it
preferable to relinquish the benefits from remaining in the union, and
regain the flexibility to use both monetary and fiscal policy? One could
argue that the euro survived because of the willingness to move towards
greater economic and political union, in contrast to the situation in
which Scotland is actively pursuing greater autonomy.
Velasco (1996) shows that the larger the shock--and the larger the
initial debt level--the more attractive it is to devalue and the less
credible is the fixed exchange rate embedded in the currency union.
There are effectively three regions for the level of government debt. In
the safe region, with the lowest government debt levels, the benefits of
remaining in the currency union always outweigh the costs. In the
unstable region, with the highest level of government debt, the costs to
remaining in the currency union outweigh the benefits for some values of
the shock to tax revenues. In the intermediate range the stability of
the monetary union depends on beliefs. If agents believe that the
government will stick to the currency union for all shocks, then these
beliefs are self-fulfilling. If, however, agents believe that there are
some shocks for which the government will abandon the currency union,
this sows the seeds of its destruction. Dooley (1988) wryly observed
that, "monetary arrangements are given birth at conference tables,
and laid to rest in foreign exchange markets".
The Scottish government's White Paper (2013) is admirably
clear that, as an independent nation, the choice of currency arrangement
in the future must always be open to the people of Scotland. This is the
case in any democratic nation. However, it also makes clear to the
continuing UK that any monetary union would only last as long as it
remains in the interests of Scotland. This questions the ability to
impose truly binding fiscal constraints on an independent country, which
has so far proved elusive in Europe.
Conclusion
We argue that when considering the optimal currency choice for an
independent Scotland it is essential to consider how it would seek to
adjust to adverse economic circumstances. In economists' terms, it
is as important to think through the 'off-equilibrium'
adjustment paths of each of the currency options. The amount of public
debt, and so the capacity for a fiscal response, is critical to these
paths.
The amount of public debt that an independent Scotland would
inherit is critical to the optimal currency choice. The lower
Scotland's initial debt and debt servicing burden, the smaller the
fiscal tightening necessary to return to a sustainable debt burden, and
the less painful any further spending cuts or tax rises would be to the
electorate. The less painful is fiscal adjustment, the more likely are
markets to believe it to be a credible adjustment mechanism. If Scotland
were to find itself with high debt and interest rates, and in the throes of an already painful austerity drive, and were to face a further
adverse shock, then markets might question the commitment to remaining
in the monetary union.
The Scottish government's acknowledgement that the decision to
remain in a monetary union inevitably depends on future governments
implies that the commitments cannot be binding in all circumstances. An
independent Scotland might find that in future the financial stability
advantages to having its own currency outweigh any disadvantages due to
trade and transactions costs.
REFERENCES
Armstrong, A. and Ebell, M. (2013a), 'Scotland's currency
options', Centre for Macroeconomics, Discussion Paper 2013-2.
--(2013b), Scottish independence and the UK debt burden,
http://niesr.ac.uk/blog/scottish-independence-and-uks-debt-burden.
--(2014), 'Assets, liabilities and adjustment in an
independent Scotland', Oxford Review of Economic Policy (forthcoming).
Capie, F.H. and Wood, G.E. (2012), Money Over Two Centuries:
Selected Topics in British Monetary History, Oxford, Oxford University
Press.
De Grauwe, P. and Ji, Y. (2013), 'Fiscal implications of the
ECB's bond-buying programme', Voxeu.org.
Dell'Ariccia, G. (1999), 'Exchange rate fluctuations and
trade flows: evidence from the European Union', IMF Working Paper
98/107.
Dooley, M. (1988), 'Speculative attacks on a monetary
union?', International Journal of Finance and Economics, 3, pp.
21-6.
Fiscal Commission Working Group (2013a), First
Report--Macroeconomic Framework, The Scottish Government.
--(2013b), First Report- Annex, The Scottish Government. Flandreau,
M. (2006), 'The logic of compromise: monetary bargaining in
Austria-Hungary, 1867-1913', European Review of Economic History,
10(01), April, pp. 3-33.
Gourinchas, P. and Jeanne, O. (2012), 'Global safe
assets', BIS Working Paper 399.
HM Treasury (2013), Whole Government Accounts, HMSO.
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2012), 'Systemic banking crisis
catabase: an update', IMF WP/12/163.
MacDonald, R. (2013), 'Currency issues and options for an
independent Scotland', mimeo, University of Glasgow.
Mundell, R.A. (1961), 'A theory of optimal currency
areas', The American Economic Review, September.
Nugee, J. (2011), Of Currencies Crises and Completions, SSgA
Capital Insights.
Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. (2009), This Time is Different."
Eight Centuries of Financial Folly, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Santos Silva, J. and Tenreyro, S. (2010), 'Currency unions in
prospect and retrospect', Annual Review of Economics, 2(1), pp.
51-75.
Scottish Government (2013a), Government Expenditure and Revenue
Scotland 2011-12, The Scottish Government.
--(2013b), Scotland's Future, The Scottish Government. Thom,
R. and Walsh, B. (2002), 'Effect of a common currency on trade:
lessons from the Irish experience', European Economic Review,
46(6), pp. 1111-23.
Velasco, A. (1996), 'Fixed exchange rates: credibility,
flexibility and multiplicity', European Economic Review, 40, pp.
1023-35.
Angus Armstrong * and Monique Ebell **
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research, Economic and
Social Research Council and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail:
[email protected]. ** National Institute of Economic and Social
Research and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail:
[email protected].
NOTES
(1) The terms currency union and monetary union both imply the use
of a single currency, but a monetary union has a common central bank.
The Fiscal Commission Working Group (2013a,b) refers specifically to a
monetary union.
(2) Laeven and Valencia (2012) show that for banking crises the
average cost in lost output relative to trend in advanced economies is a
staggering 33 per cent.
(3) See Scottish Government (2013b) pp. 30, 341 and 554.
(4) The median line is equidistant from the two closest coast
lines. It was used to divide the North Sea into UK and Norwegian
territories and to demarcate fishing boundaries between Scotland and the
rest of the UK.
(5) MacDonald (2013) emphasises the asymmetric impact of oil price
shocks on Scotland and the remaining UK as a factor which works against
these two regions forming an optimal currency area.
(6) Scotland's First Minister suggested that a division of UK
debt on the basis of population would be fair during a TV interview on
11th January 2012.
(7) See Armstrong and Ebell (2013b) available at
http://niesr.ac.uk/blog/scottish-independence-and-uks-debt-burden for a
discussion of the consequences on fiscal aggregates of how the debt
would be repaid.
(8) Scottish Government (2013b) p. 7. The First Minister stated
during the launch of the White Paper that the Bank of England and
sterling are as much Scotland's asset as London's asset.
(9) Some scholars such as Reinhart and Rogoff (2009, p. 111)
suggest that the conversion of loan stock in 1932 was debt forgiveness
and therefore a default. Capie and Wood (2012, p. 170) describe how the
stock had a final redemption date of 1947 with an option to repay
anytime after I June 1929. This is similar to the option in many
government and agency bonds today.
(10) An argument can be made that there should be compensation. But
it is not clear in which direction this should flow: from the UK to
Scotland in return for leaving the reputational value or Scotland to the
UK by possibly eroding the reputational value by leaving the union.
(11) Thom and Walsh (2002) p. 1122.
(12) Fiscal Commission Working Group (2013a), p. 123.
(13) The transition to a new currency also raises significant
challenges. See Armstrong and Ebell (2013a) for a discussion.
(14) See De Grauwe and Ji (2013) in the eurozone context.
(15) See Gourinchas and Jeanne (2012).
(16) See MacDonald (2013) for a discussion of the real exchange
rate between an independent Scotland and UK.
(17) See Nugee (2011).
(18) One vote would approximate a population based representation
on the MPC.
(19) To award a small independent country an opt-out when the rest
of the union is moving toward greater integration would seem
incongruous, although the timing of joining the euro is likely to be
unspecified.
(20) Montenegro or Kosovo are very small and the circumstances were
so exceptional that they were permitted.
(21) Velasco (1996) analyses the impact of government debt on the
credibility of a fixed exchange rate. We understand a currency union to
be a special case of a fixed exchange rate.
(22) Armstrong and Ebell (2013a).
Table 1. Summary of an independent Scotland's feasible currency options
Currency Arrangement Transaction Monetary policy
costs
Scots pound Fixed/pegged Highest costs Central Bank
of Scotland
Floating Central Bank
of Scotland
Sterling Informal None Bank of England
currency union
Monetary union Bank of England
Euro Informal Medium costs European
currency union Central Bank
Monetary union European
Central Bank
Currency Arrangement Financial Fiscal policy
stability
Scots pound Fixed/pegged Scotland No formal
limits
Floating Scotland No formal
limits
Sterling Informal Scotland No formal
currency union limits
Monetary union Shared with UK Formal limits
Euro Informal Scotland No formal
currency union limits
Monetary union Shared with EU Formal limits