Unconventional monetary policy: introduction.
Armstrong, Angus ; Ebell, Monique
The world's four major central banks have turned to new forms
of monetary policy to support demand during the Global Financial Crisis.
(1) The conventional policy instrument of overnight interest rates was
reduced to close to zero per cent within eighteen months of the crisis.
(2) This presents a problem of providing further stimulus by lowering
interest rates; if rates turn negative then depositors always have the
option of holding wealth in cash at a zero interest rate. The option of
holding cash is thought to create an effective floor on interest rates
known as the zero lower bound (ZLB). Central banks have had to find new
ways of deploying monetary policy, popularly known as
'unconventional' monetary policy, to provide further stimulus
subject to the ZLB.
Central banks have also carried out many other interventions, from
buying private or risky sovereign securities (accepting credit risk), to
direct liquidity and solvency support to institutions and markets and
implementing government guarantees to support lending. These
interventions directly involve credit risk and so can be considered as
distinct from monetary policy. The Bank of England (the Bank) and the
European Central Bank (ECB) have been particularly keen to maintain this
distinction. (3) Yet the validity of the distinction is unclear;
monetary policy influences the risk premia on assets with consequences
for financial stability; financial stability policies influence the
transmission mechanism for monetary policy; and income from
unconventional monetary policy is counted as a fiscal revenue.
In this issue of the Review, we accept this distinction of
unconventional monetary policies from other measures taken by central
banks. In particular, three types of unconventional policies have been
widely used by the major central banks. First, forward guidance was
introduced by the US Federal Reserve (the Fed) in December 2008 and has
since been used by all four major central banks. (4) Second, all four
central banks have engaged in large asset purchase programmes through
the creation of bank reserves, known as quantitative easing (QE).
Finally, there is a healthy debate about whether nominal interest rates
can, in fact, safely be set substantively below zero per cent. Four
European central banks have now introduced negative policy rates without
any obvious sign of instability.
When assessing the suitability of unconventional monetary policies
we face the quandary that mainstream economic models (e.g. New
Keynesian) offer little rationale for intervening. According to these
models the current interest rate and expected path of future interest
rates fully encapsulates the impact of monetary policy on the economy.
Unless unconventional monetary can change expectations about the future
path of policy then there is no channel to influence the economy.
Bernanke (2014) remarked that that QE "works in practice, but does
not work in theory". (5) However, these strong results are
generated in models that generally have no meaningful financial sector
and assume that agents such as central banks can fully commit to policy
targets. The financial sector continues to be underplayed in economic
models and in practice. Its absence may lead to misleading assessments
of the effectiveness of unconventional monetary policies.
An 'unconventional' history
While theory may not be much of a guide for unconventional
policies, there is a rich history of intellectual debate on the
appropriateness of such measures. During the Great Depression all three
unconventional measures were widely debated. Indeed, Keynes (1936) set
out a general economic system where the interest rate could not fall to
the level required to support investment and output at full employment.
An important part of Keynes's system became known as the
'liquidity trap'. (6) Keynes noted that "there is a
possibility ... that, after the rate of interest has fallen to a certain
level, liquidity-preference may become virtually absolute in the sense
that almost everyone prefers cash to holding a debt which yields so low
a rate of interest. In this event the monetary authority would have lost
effective control over the rate of interest." (7)
Keynes considered and discussed two of the three forms of our
modern day 'unconventional' monetary policies: forward
guidance and quantitative easing. He recognised that monetary policy
operates through short-term interest rates and could not necessarily
influence the long-term interest rate which contains future expected
interest rates and therefore is also important for investment. Indeed,
he appreciated the time inconsistency problem facing monetary
policymakers: "a monetary policy which strikes the public as being
experimental in character or easy to change may fail in its objective of
greatly reducing the long-term rate of interest". (8) Of course,
"the same policy might prove easily successful ... if it is ...
rooted in strong conviction, and promoted by an authority unlikely to be
superseded". (9) Thus, Keynes effectively provides an early
description of forward guidance.
The historical roots of QE have similarly close ties to Keynes.
There is considerable dispute about how exactly QE functions, with the
Bank of England offering many possible answers. Perhaps the clearest
explanation is given in Governor King's speech in early 2009 soon
after the policy was announced: "the success is not to be judged by
the increase in bank lending. Its aim is to increase the money
supply." (10) In an open letter to President Roosevelt (1933),
Keynes described the idea that output and income can be raised by
increasing the quantity of money as "like trying to get fat by
buying a larger belt". Keynes described the quantity of money as
only a limiting factor and the volume of expenditure is the operative
factor.
The idea of engineering substantially negative interest rates also
has a long history. Silvio Gesell (a German merchant living in
Argentina) suggested that currency notes could be required to be stamped
to maintain their legal tender status. The cost of the stamp would be a
cost of holding the currency and set to be equivalent to a negative
interest rate. Keynes (1936) appears to have been enthusiastic,
dedicating much of chapter 23 to this idea, but remained unconvinced as
the analysis was partial equilibrium. Another possibility for generating
a negative interest rate was suggested by Robert Eisler (1932): when an
exchange rate is set between bank reserves and cash (rather than the
presumed parity rate). Since the interest rate on reserves can be set at
any rate, the zero interest rate on cash could be made negative by
depreciating the exchange rate of cash against reserves. This idea is
developed in the first paper in this special issue.
Lender risk
There are of course similarities between the Great Depression and
the global financial crisis. Both were preceded by the accumulation of
private sector debts, rising asset prices and increased leverage in the
financial system. (11) The relevance is that the fall in demand and
resultant debt overhang raised doubts about the effectiveness of
monetary policy. However, the limiting factor may not be the ZLB on
short-term policy rates or sovereign bonds but the lending rate for
enterprises. Keynes (1936) noted that two types of risk affect the
volume of investment--borrower risk (associated with the riskiness of
the project) and lender risk which is a "pure addition to the cost
of investment and would not exist if the borrower and lender were the
same person". (12) The exclusion of a meaningful financial sector
in many economic models may downplay the cost of intermediation above
the zero rate as the effective lower bound. While large firms can access
capital markets, the vast majority of firms and around half of output is
generated by small and medium enterprises which rely on the banking
sector. The lower bound for these firms' borrowing costs is not
zero, but the cost of intermediation. Two points follow. As long as many
institutions continue to trade at market values below book values it is
difficult for the cost of intermediation to fall further. Also, how the
banking sector responds to unconventional monetary policies may
determine their effectiveness.
Electronic money
The first paper in this Review, by Miles Kimball, takes up the
challenge of how to deliver significant negative interest rates when
necessary for economic stabilisation. The objective is to remove the ZLB
with the minimum of social and political complications so that central
banks could revert to negative interest rates within weeks if warranted.
Kimball takes up Eisler's idea of introducing an exchange rate
between bank money and paper (currency) money. Most of our transactions
today are carried out using electronic money (bank transfers, cheques,
credit and debit cards and touch cards) with currency only used for
small transactions. Kimball suggests it would be straightforward to
impose negative interest rates on electronic money. In such periods cash
would no longer have a par exchange rate against electronic money but
would depreciate very gradually over time to yield the same negative
interest rate.
Items in shops would be priced in terms of electronic money, at
least for larger items usually paid for by cards or transfers, which are
also more interest rate sensitive. The cash exchange rate would depend
on the depreciation rate set by the central bank and the time period
since negative rates began. For example, a negative 4 per cent interest
rate would be equivalent to a 0.011 per cent of a cent decline in the
value of a dollar each day over one year. This would minimise disruption
to cash balances for transactions purposes and discourage flight from
electronic money stocks into currency. If negative interest rates are
necessary (ruling out other options such as fiscal policy) then this
idea of an exchange rate between electronic and paper currency is surely
the most viable.
While Kimball notes that economic theory makes little distinction
between positive and negative interest rates, we would like to know more
about how profit maximising financial institutions might respond. An
environment where significantly negative interest rates are required is
likely to be one with great uncertainty and hoarding of liquid assets.
Banks may be less willing to pass negative interest rates on to their
depositors for fear of flight, perhaps into another currency or
financial asset. As a result banks would receive a negative return on
their reserves at the central bank. This would increase the financial
pressure on banks and may even lead them to increase lending rates to
maintain their profit margin. The effect of the negative interest rate
policy on the economy may be muted or even counterproductive depending
on the behaviour of financial institutions.
Quantitative easing and inflation
The second paper examines quantitative easing within the context of
the quantity theory of money, in particular whether the accumulation of
bank reserves will lead to an eventual rise in inflation. Bill Cline
provides an expert account of why one might expect vast increases in
bank reserves to lead to growth in the broad money supply and inflation.
The reason that this has not occurred is the decline in the money
multiplier (the transformation of reserves into broad money) rather than
a particular fall in the velocity of circulation. The money multiplier
is a function of cash balances, bank profitability and the amount of
leverage banks are seeking. If financial institutions and households and
firms are seeking to de-leverage this is consistent with a falling money
multiplier.
It would be incautious to consider that because inflation has not
arisen thus far central banks are in the clear. As the economy and
financial institutions normalise, banks may be prepared to increase
lending faster given their large reserve holdings. Cline summarises the
Fed's exit strategy of increasing the interest rate on reserves.
Higher reserve requirements are limited by law. Therefore the real risk
is that there could be a dramatic switch from 'risk-off' to
'risk-on' behaviour whereby banks are not discouraged by the
higher returns on reserves. Again this depends very much on the response
of financial intermediaries.
Channels of quantitative easing
Jagjit Chadha addresses some of the limits of the mainstream
approach to monetary policy. In his view, QE is simply an extension of
conventional monetary policy, i.e. an extended open market operation
involving 'unsterilised' bank reserves, but applied to the
ZLB. However, if such operations influence the risk premia on the assets
bought, then this may be an important channel by which QE influences the
economy. Chadha opens the discussion on financial intermediation and
differences in borrowing and lending rates, showing how this can lead to
distributional consequences as well as alter the impact of QE. In the
policy space this draws him to discuss how QE might complement
macro-prudential measures. This inevitably brings unconventional
monetary policy into the realm of actions which have fiscal
consequences. The paper concludes with a call for more consideration of
how the array of tools now available to central banks can be used in a
complementary fashion.
Jack Meaning and James Warren provide a quantitative assessment of
the extent and channels by which QE influences longer-term interest
rates. They consider how the Bank of England's acquisition of 30
per cent of the stock of gilts in private hands may have influenced bond
prices in two ways: through the New Keynesian channel of changing
expectations of future monetary policy; and through market segmentation
theories where bonds are imperfect substitutes. They show that QE may
have lowered bond yields by 25 basis points; at the lower end of
economists' estimates. This may be consistent with a greater shift
in short-term interest rates. The authors suggest that when QE is
unwound the increase in supply may raise interest rates over and above
any expected changes in monetary policy. This also highlights the
inevitable interaction between fiscal and monetary policy.
An important issue is the impact of QE beyond the direct affect on
sovereign bond yields. The impact on financial intermediaries may in
fact be as important for the real economy. A recent paper by Lambert and
Ueda (2014) provides an assessment of QE in the US on banks'
profitability. They reject the common assumption that QE is beneficial
for banks. Rather they provide evidence that the flattening yield curve
may damage bank profitability and even encourage greater risk taking.
This may accord with the increased concentration and size of banks since
the crisis. It is the impact of QE on financial intermediation together
with the sovereign yield curve which will determine the overall
effectiveness of the policy on the real economy.
The papers in this issue of the Review provide leading assessments
of the viability and impact of unconventional monetary policies. We are
extremely grateful to the authors. Our judgement is that incorporating
profit maximising financial intermediaries is required both in
understanding economic cycles and for a full assessment of the
desirability of unconventional monetary policies.
NOTES
(1) The four major central banks in this introduction refer to the
Federal Reserve, European Central Bank, Bank of Japan and Bank of
England.
(2) Central banks differed in their urgency to deploy conventional
monetary policy. The Fed reduced its target interest rate by 100 basis
points in the twelve months before the economy entered recession in the
first quarter of 2008. The Bank of England raised interest rates in July
2007, two months before the demise of Northern Rock, and the Bank Rate
was 5 per cent in October 2008--after two quarters of economic
contraction. The ECB began raising interest rates in 201 I just ahead of
the full consequences of its sovereign debt crisis.
(3) The ECB defines large asset purchases where credit risk remains
within national boundaries as monetary policy (Public Sector Purchase
Programme) while the purchase of distressed sovereign assets where
credit risk is shared (either the Securities Markets Programme or
Outright Market Transactions) is defined as improving the transmission
mechanism rather than traditional monetary policy.
(4) The Federal Reserve minutes (16 December, 2008) stated that
"weak economic conditions are likely to warrant exceptionally low
levels of the federal funds rate for some time".
(5) Bernanke (2014), p. 14.
(6) The term 'liquidity trap' is generally credited to
Robertson (1940).
(7) Keynes (1936), p. 207.
(8) Keynes (1936), p. 203.
(9) Keynes (1936), p. 203.
(10) King (2009), p. 3.
(11) There are also many important differences between the Great
Depression and the global financial crisis; in particular, the policy
response of supporting banks allowing fiscal deficits to absorb the fall
in private demand. The UK equivalent of the great depression happened in
the 1920s and no financial institutions were lost.
(12) Keynes (1936), p. 144.
REFERENCES
Bernanke, B. (2014), 'Central banking after the Great
Recession: lessons learned and challenges ahead', discussion at The
Brookings Institute, 16 January.
Keynes, J.M. (1933), 'An open letter to President
Roosevelt', New York Times.
--(1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, The
Royal Economic Society, 1973.
King, M. (2009), Mansion House Speech, Bank of England, 17 June.
Lambert, F. and Ueda. K. (2014), 'The effects of
unconventional monetary policies on bank soundness', IMF Working
Paper, WP/I4/I52.
Robertson, D.H. (1940), Essays in Monetary Theory, P. S. King.
Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell *
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research and Centre for
Macroeconomics. E-mail:
[email protected] or
[email protected].
The authors are supported by the Economic and Social Research Council
through its Centre on Constitutional Change.