Commentary: UK finance and Europe.
Armstrong, Angus
The UK relationship with the European Union (EU) will be a defining
issue for the new government. The EU is undergoing profound changes in
the aftermath of the global financial and its sovereign debt crisis.
Accordingly, a thorough analysis of the pros and cons of EU membership
and the scope for reform is required. Following our assessment of the
'Scottish Question' around the independence debate last year,
the 'British Question' is one of our top research priorities.
The EU is the UK's most important economic partner. Over half
of exports are sold to the EU, almost 60 per cent of inward foreign
direct investment comes from the continent and almost half of all
migration is with the EU. However, critics argue that the EU is in
relative decline and that membership limits our sovereignty and our
ability to compete in new markets. Moreover, the EU cannot be considered
to be in a steady state. Assuming no further enlargement, in five
years' time 23 out of the 28 EU states will be Euro Area members. A
new equilibrium might be an EU with a closer political union and a
pooling of fiscal resources that resembles a 'United States of
Europe'. An alternative scenario is that at least one country might
leave the Euro Area. (1) Either outcome would have important
consequences for the UK.
An important part of this debate will be around financial services.
This is inevitable given that the UK is effectively host to the Euro
Area's wholesale financial markets, the EU's key decision to
create a European Banking Union (EBU) and the fundamental differences
between the UK and continental European models of financial
intermediation. This is especially important to the UK because financial
services have long been one of our most successful economic sectors. A
House of Lords report suggested that the consequences of the EBU for the
UK could be 'momentous'. (2) For non-Euro Area members of the
EU the EBU may create either centripetal or centrifugal forces. This
commentary raises four questions regarding financial services and the
UK's EU membership.
UK financial services and the EU
The UK has been a leading global financial centre for two
centuries. British institutions financed development across the Empire,
created capital markets for trading companies and government debt and
famously financed South America's railroads in the late nineteenth
century. Until the recent global financial crisis the UK had not allowed
a bank to fail since 1866 and had a strong reputation for self-policing
and upholding high standards of behaviour. (3) There have been a number
of official reviews over the past century suggesting that the system may
be sub-optimal for the broader economy, but any changes that followed
failed to alter the UK's dominance in international finance. (4)
Financial services (particularly banking and insurance) is one of
our largest economic sectors. Output accounts for over 8 per cent of
total national output and so its success is important for the overall
success of the economy. UK exports of financial services as a share of
GDP are greater than any other country (excluding city states), the UK
has a trade surplus in financial services of 2.5 per cent of GDP and the
sector is estimated to contribute up to 11 per cent of total tax
revenue. (5) The growth of financial services reflects the role of the
UK as an international centre of capital markets. Over 150 foreign banks
have branches and almost 100 have subsidiaries in the UK (see box 1 for
the distinction between branches and subsidiaries). The UK is also home
to four of the thirty Global Systemically Important Banks (GSIBs) and
host to two large GSIB subsidiaries from Switzerland. (6)
The UK joined the European Economic Community in 1973, which became
one part of the EU in 1993. (7) All members of the European Economic
Area are permitted to open branches in other member countries. Since
former Bank of England Governor, Mr Eddie George, negotiated UK
membership to the euro payments system, the introduction of the euro
further strengthened the UK's position. While the UK has a trade
deficit with the rest of the EU of 3.7 per cent, trade in financial
services is in surplus of 1.3 per cent of GDP. (8) London accounts for
25 per cent of total EU banking assets, 70 per cent of derivative
trading, 85 per cent of hedge fund assets under management and 50 per
cent of maritime insurance. (9)
Over the past four decades the relative scale of the UK banking
system has increased by over four times --standing at 450 per cent of
GDP on a residency basis. (10) However, as the past eight years remind
us; with financial services, more is not always better. While there is
no clear link between size of banking system and fragility, Bush (2014)
reports that the fiscal cost of a crisis increases with the size of the
banking system. Many of the losses in the UK banks occurred in their
overseas operations. It would also be incautious to assume that
'too big to fail' is resolved under the current regulatory
proposals. Therefore, the mutual interest between the public and the
financial sector is no longer obvious. This is especially the case given
our limited fiscal capacity to backstop a sector over four times bigger
than output.
Box I: Branches versus subsidiaries
Foreign banks operating in London can do so as a branch or
subsidiary. A branch is simply an office of the foreign bank
operating in London. Capital typically flows freely between the
branch and its foreign parent bank, and the branch typically
maintains no separate capital of its own. It is regulated primarily
by the regulator where the bank is incorporated (the 'home'
regulator), although its 'host' regulator, in this case the
Prudential Regulation Authority (PRA) and Financial Conduct
Authority (FCA), may impose restrictions on the types of activities
it may undertake and the services it may offer to UK based clients.
A subsidiary is a separately registered bank incorporated in
London, but which is wholly or partly owned by the foreign bank.
Because it is registered in London, its primary regulators are the
PRA and the FCA, and it must meet UK prudential requirements
independently of its parent, although it may use the support of its
parent to do so. Branch structures may pose greater risks for
financial stability. Capital can easily flow between branches and
their parent meaning that financial shocks are easily transmitted
across borders. On the other hand, branches may be more efficient
than subsidiaries, leading to a tension between the preferences of
supervisors and those of banking groups.
Towards European Banking Union
Flaws in the design of the single currency system were dramatically
exposed by the financial crisis. The lack of political union when the
single currency was introduced meant that the European Central Bank
(ECB) had no fiscal backstop, no financial supervisory role and
therefore no capacity to provide emergency liquidity assistance if
necessary. (11) The absence of this essentially fiscal function, but
conducted by a central bank, created a fragile Euro Area banking system
with a doom loop between governments and their banking systems.
Governments bailed out failing banks by issuing public debt, which led
to higher interest rates which further damaged the distressed banks,
thereby requiring an even greater bailout. (12) The IMF (2013) estimates
that in 2008-12 the cost of recapitalisation and asset management
reached 4.6 per cent of EU GDP and, including guarantees, 13 per cent of
EU GDP. (13)
In 2012 the EU Heads of State and Government agreed to create the
EBU, which they claim will complete the economic and monetary union.
Article 127(6) of the Maastricht Treaty is interpreted such that the ECB
can take on specific supervisory tasks without Treaty change on the
unanimous decision of the European Council. The IMF (2013) notes that
this is an expansive interpretation of the Treaty, creating some
litigation risk as a financial institution could bring a case before the
European Court of Justice (ECJ). Membership of the EBU is obligatory for
Euro Area members and non-Euro Area countries may choose to join. While
non-Euro Area members can be represented on the ECB's Supervisory
Board, ultimate regulatory authority lies with the Governing Council of
the ECB (which consists of permanent staff and Euro Area
representatives). This raises governance issues and the UK and Swedish
governments have made clear that they will not participate in the EBU.
EBU has three elements. The foundation is a single regulatory
rulebook covering all financial institutions (including 8,300 banks) in
the EU. These rules cover capital requirements, protection of depositors
and prevention and management of bank failures. Members who do not join
the EBU can add domestic regulatory powers to the rulebook which
functions as a regulatory minimum across the EU. A Single Supervisory
Mechanism (SSM) assigns the ECB as the central prudential supervisor of
financial institutions in the EBU. The ECB directly supervises the
largest 120 EBU significant banking groups, while national supervisors
monitor the remaining institutions. The Single Resolution Mechanism
(SRM) resolves distressed banking groups covered by the SSM with
ultimate access to the Single Resolution Fund (SRF) financed by the
EU's banking sector.
Is financial sovereignty achievable?
The way that governments responded to the financial crisis showed
that relying on 'mutual recognition of national interests' is
too optimistic. Therefore, a first question is whether UK financial
sovereignty is consistent with the emerging EU governance structure?
National governments resorted to resolving institutions on national
boundaries. For example, Icelandic banks gave preference to domestic
depositors, Fortis was divided and resolved along national boundaries
and TARP was only available to US headquartered banks. When national
governments or unions consider only their own interests, and not the
possible spillovers on other nations, this can lead to suboptimal
outcomes. In a highly integrated financial system, decisions in a nation
or union can undermine sovereignty elsewhere.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Schoenmaker (2009) generalised this problem into a trilemma where
only two of three outcomes can be achieved (see figure 1). This is an
extension of the classical trilemma of Mundell-Fleming. (14) In this
context, consider an extreme case of a systemic financial event, where
several financial institutions are affected at the same time. The
decision of one country to resolve an international institution (say,
Lehman Brothers) may well have financial stability or fiscal
consequences for other countries. Unless these consequences are taken
into account then the decision may be sub-optimal. The more integrated
the financial system, the more that financial sovereignty and, in
extreme cases fiscal sovereignty, is shared (all else equal).
The SRM and SRF can be interpreted as resolving this trilemma by
pooling financial resources, or sharing sovereignty. In the event of a
bank resolution shareholders and other (pre-determined) liability
holders will have their assets written-down while the bank is a going
concern. In the event of further losses, and after national support, the
SRF will be available to EBU members. The idea is that the fiscal
backstop is not national taxpayers so breaking the 'doom
loop'. Buiter and Raubin (2010) nicely describe this as
compensating for the loss of financial independence (by no longer having
a national currency) to mitigate sovereign risk. The solution allows
banks to remain closely integrated while the common resolution fund
avoids the feedback to the sovereign by limiting national sovereignty.
The trilemma suggests that because the UK is outside the EBU and
relies on its own fiscal resources, then maintaining a large integrated
cross-border financial system may not be compatible with financial
stability. It is unclear how the interests of EBU nations and EU nations
outside the EBU will be aligned. This is particularly important for the
UK because six of the EU's thirty GSIBs operate as legal
institutions in the UK. Decisions can be taken within the EBU with
regard to a GSIB subsidiary or branch in an EBU member state, which
could have fiscal consequences for the UK and hence the loss of national
financial sovereignty.
Schoenmaker and Siegmann (2013) carry out an intriguing exercise of
estimating the possible costs and benefits of pooling resolution costs
across EU members. They find that the benefits of risk sharing are
greatest for the UK. In fact, joining the EBU would be one solution to
Chancellor Osborne's 'British dilemma'. (15) However,
even if the UK joined the EBU it cannot be represented on the ECB
Governing Council as long as it remains outside the Euro Area. We doubt
the UK would hand such a degree of fiscal sovereignty to an institution
it could not ultimately influence.
Unless the UK has a fundamental change of position with regard to
the euro, solving the EBU governance issues is required if the trilemma
is to be resolved. The default outcome is that the business models of
cross-border banks become balkanised, requiring individually capitalised
subsidiaries regulated by host nations. This reduces the degree of
financial integration and increases the cost of cross-border
intermediation. Outside the EU the trilemma would be solved by
significantly reduced cross-border integration with less influence on
financial regulation policy decisions.
Is national regulation plausible?
A similar coordination problem arises if national policies (figure
1) are interpreted as domestic financial regulations. To what extent is
the domain of national financial regulation limited in a country with
large cross-border capital flows in order to be consistent with
financial stability? Capital and liquidity can easily be transferred
across branches in a banking group to exploit regulatory differences.
Unless spillovers are taken into account cross-border flows may exploit
regulatory differences and the outcome may be sub-optimal.
Prior to the crisis there was little sign of 'mutual
recognition' of the potential consequences of significant capital
inflows associated with current account imbalances. The divergence in
regulation between the UK and Euro Area members, from capital and
leverage ratios to tax and conduct, suggests a significant divergence
from 'maximum harmonisation' previously heralded for a single
market. The Bank of England has already indicated that it intends to
have higher prudential requirements than the EU. The issue is whether
being heavily financially integrated limits the scope for different
regulatory policy.
The most difficult regulatory domain may be macro-prudential
policy. This is supposed to mitigate systemic risk across the financial
system and over economic and financial cycles (such as the credit
cycle). Cross-border flows are notoriously pro-cyclical suggesting
coordination is desirable. The EU has established the European Systemic
Risk Board (ESRB) responsible for monitoring and preventing systemic
risk arising across the union. The ESRB has no direct control over
policy and issues recommendations to member states which must either
'comply or explain'. Implementation is left to national
regulators but the ECB has the authority to implement new
macro-prudential regulations across EBU members.
An important layer of protection for the UK from the ECB and EBU
dominated ESRB is the European Banking Authority (EBA) located in
London. (16) This is responsible for implementing the single rulebook on
banking applicable to all 28 members of the EU and the efficient and
orderly functioning of the banking sector. To protect the interests of
non-EBU countries from Euro Area regulations, decisions at the EBA are
decided by a 'double majority' voting system. This is a
'qualified majority' of EU members and a 'simple
majority' of Euro Area and non-Euro Area countries. However, the
EBA can only request that the ECB follows its decision but cannot
require it to do so.
A possible solution is that an independent monetary policy with a
floating currency can create enough degrees of freedom to manage
differences in regulation. Yet Rey (2013) observes that even with a
flexible currency the size of and cyclicality of cross-border capital
means that the scope for independent monetary policy is limited. The
degree to which cross-border capital markets are correlated even with
separate currencies suggests the coordination problem remains. The
alternative is that cross-border institutions shift from branches and
towards subsidiaries. This is consistent with the host regulator being
able to resolve and regulate the institution and avoid some of the
regulatory coordination problems. (17) Again this may add to the cost of
intermediation.
There is also a question over how long the EBA can be an effective
form of defence for the UK. Assuming no further enlargement, and those
who are committed to join the euro do so on schedule, by 2020 23 of the
28 nations will be Euro Area members. This would essentially come down
to the ECB and the Bank of England as the dominant institutions but with
very different membership support. This implies the 'double
majority' voting system increasingly serves the UK. The question is
whether within the EU this can be sustained. Outside the EU the UK would
have no vote. The UK's largest bank, HSBC, has recently cited
uncertainty over the UK's position with regard to the EU as one
reason for its review of location.
Will location policy become competitive?
Financial services are a highly desirable economic sector and there
has always been competition between nations to host this business. The
Royal Exchange opened in London in 1566 inspired by Sir Thomas Gresham.
It was originally called a bourse, designed by a Flemish architect,
built by European craftsmen and the traders were mostly from overseas.
(18) Assuming the EBU becomes a closer union, will a location policy
emerge to attract financial services within the geographical borders of
the union? If the UK is within the EU this must comply with the
Competition Law and there is a right to appeal to the ECJ.
An interesting recent case is the ECB's Eurosystem Oversight
Policy Framework making the case that Clearing Houses with substantial
business in euro should be within the Euro Area: "as a matter of
principle, infrastructures that settle euro-denominated payment
transactions should settle these transactions in central bank money and
be legally incorporated in the Euro Area with full managerial and
operational control". (19) The UK appealed to the ECJ on several
points, and the court upheld that the ECB does not have competence to
rule on securities clearing. Note that the ruling did not address the
principle about supplying euro liquidity to infrastructure outside the
Euro Area. This is yet to be addressed.
The issue raises a number of points for the UK. First, the ruling
supports the integrity of the ECJ. This is important given the likely
disagreements over regulation (for example, on bonus caps and a
financial transaction tax). Second, clearing houses are acknowledged to
contain liquidity risk by the ECB. The IMF accepts that they may pose
systemic risk if mismanaged. Third, since the ex ante liquidity and
solvency risks cannot be easily separated, this issue must be resolved
in advance. The immediate solution appears to be swap lines between the
Bank of England and the ECB as all EU sovereign debt is zero
risk-weighted. However, depending on the size of the exposure there
would be currency risk for the UK. (20)
Another potential location issue arises with EC President
Juncker's initiative for a Capital Markets Union. It is designed to
complement bank lending, particularly for loans to small and medium
enterprises, and the EC suggests the market could exceed 300bn [euro] by
2017. An advisory 'hub' is due to be operational by the middle
of this year and there are indications that the market will physically
exist in an actual location. This is clearly attractive to the UK
because English Law is common to capital market instruments, the UK is
already host to relatively large equity capital markets and the dominant
location of euro interbank markets necessary for hedging risk.
Since much of the justification is to reach a size of market seen
in the UK, Switzerland and the US, the EC may either see the UK as the
most likely location to achieve their aspiration or prefer a competing
location. Whether the UK can compete against the interests of EBU
members for new euro capital markets remains to be seen. Outside the EU
would limit the UK's ability to influence all administrative but
not necessarily economic decisions.
What is the alternative?
The critical issue for UK financial services is the consequences of
the creation of the EBU. This creates two dominant central banks with
uneven EU member support, resolution powers for significant banks
residing with two authorities, and divergent regulation across a
financial integrated union. Ferran (2014) has suggested that this may
create centripetal or centrifugal forces. (21)
One approach is to seek to resolve these issues through
re-negotiation of particular agreements. This requires establishing
priorities and possible solutions for member states. For example, the
voting rights at the EBA could be along size of financial sector rather
than simply national members. Another approach is to consider leaving
the EU. This begs a series of questions including what the alternative
arrangement would be, what would be the consequences for other
countries, what would be the consequences within the UK, whether this is
preferable to the status quo, or a re-negotiated EU.
The procedure for exiting the EU is by Article 50. Once notice is
served, the dynamics would be difficult to control as the UK would not
take part in formal exit negotiations. It may be that the EU would seek
an accommodating solution, on the other hand there may be a risk of
other departures which the EU may wish to discourage through less
accommodation. One of the most important issues is whether UK
institutions would continue to have direct access to the euro payments
system.
A number of alternative arrangements outside the EU are often
suggested. Some arrangements were created for particular circumstances
and, while they establish precedence, it is unclear that they could be
replicated. For example, Norway is a member of the European Economic
Area (EEA) with full market access to the EU and agreements with the
rest of the world. But it has no say on any policy or representation in
EU institutions, referred to as 'fax diplomacy' or regulation
without representation. Switzerland has negotiated a series of bilateral
sector level agreements with the EU over many years. This includes free
trade in goods but not services (hence why two Swiss GSIBs operate
through London). Under both arrangements the UK would have very little
influence on EU financial policy, resolution procedures and location
policy discussed above.
REFERENCES
Armstrong, A. and McCarthy, D. (2014), 'Scotland's Lender
of Last Resort options', NIESR Discussion Paper no. 434.
Buiter, W. and Rahbari, E. (2010), 'Greece and the fiscal
crisis in the Euro zone', CEPR Policy Insight 51.
Bush, O. (2014), 'Why is the UK banking system so big and is
that a problem?', Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin.
Davies, G. (2002), A History of Money, University of Wales Press.
ECB (2011), European Oversight Policy Framework.
Ferran, E. (2014), 'European Banking Union and the EU Single
Financial Market: more differentiation, integraiton or
disintegration', mimeo.
Folkerts-Landau, D. and Garber, P.M. (1992), 'The European
Central Bank: a bank or a monetary policy rule?', NBER working
Paper No. 4016.
House of Lords European Committee, 2012, European Banking Union:
Key issues and challenges, The Stationary Office Limited.
IMF (2013), 'A Banking Union for the Euro Area', Staff
discussion Nate 13/01.
London Economics (2014), 'The importance of wholesale
financial services to the EU economy 2014', Special Interest Paper,
City of London Corporation.
PwC (2014), Total Tax Contribution of UK Financial Services, 7th
Edition, Research Report, City of London Corporation.
Rey, H. (2013), 'Dilemma not trilemma: the global financial
cycle and monetary policy independence', Jackson Hole Symposium,
August.
Schoenmaker, D, (2009), 'The financial trilemma', Working
Paper, SSRN #1340395.
Schoenmaker, D. and Siegmann, A.H. (2013), 'Efficiency gains
of a European Banking Union', Duisenberg School of
Finance-Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, TI 13-26/DSF 51.
NOTES
(1) There is no procedure for a country to leave the Euro Area. The
country in question would become a member of the EU outside the Euro
Area but without a Treaty opt-out clause and therefore of unclear
constitutional status.
(2) House of Lords (2012) p. 5.
(3) Overend and Gurney failed in 1866. However it is important to
note that other British banks would have failed without the intervention
by the authorities (e.g., National Westminster Bank in the 1970s). This
willingness to support institutions may have contributed to the growth
of the City.
(4) For example, see the Macmillan Committee (1929) on Finance and
Industry.
(5) This estimate is from PwC (2014) and includes all taxes such as
VAT, income taxes paid, tax on interest income etc. It is therefore a
maximum total amount.
(6) HSBC, Royal Bank of Scotland, Barclays, Standard Chartered, UBS
and Credit Suisse.
(7) The UK joined the European Economic Community in 1973 and
negotiated four areas of opt-outs from the Maastricht Treaty which
created the economic and monetary union: Schengen area, EMU, Charter of
Fundamental Rights and Freedom, Security and Justice (with opt-in
clauses).
(8) All trade data are from the ONS and for 2013.
(9) Figures from The City UK (2014).
(10) See Bush (2014) for a discussion of how banking systems can be
measured on ownership (UK owned banks including subsidiaries and
branches) or residency (UK banks and foreign bank subsidiaries and
branches located in the UK). On the former measure the banking system is
350 per cent of GDP and on the latter measure 450 per cent of GDP.
(11) See Folkerts-Landau and Garber (1992), for an early study of
the unusual nature of the ECB's mandate.
(12) In many countries it was the size of the banking systems which
had such a dramatic impact on government finances. The IMF (2013) points
to a second feedback loop from sovereign debt distress due to fiscal
indiscipline to the banking system and then back to the sovereign.
(13) See IMF (2013). The guarantees are between 2008 and 2010 only.
(14) The classical trilemma states that only two of a triple of
capital mobility, a fixed exchange rate independent monetary policy can
be maintained.
(15) The British Dilemma was coined when the Vickers Commission was
established. How can the UK enjoy the benefits of a large financial
system when this implies a large contingent liability on the state?
(16) The European System for Financial Supervision consists of: the
European Securities and Markets Authorities (ESMA), the
European Banking Authority (EBA) and the European Insurance and
Occupational Pensions Authority (EIOPA). The system also comprises the
European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) as well as the Joint Committee of
the European Supervisory Authorities and the national supervisory
authorities.
(17) This is similar to the Single Point of Entry versus Multiple
Point of Entry approaches to resolution. The latter is more consistent
with a fragmented banking system and minimises coordination problems.
(18) See Davies (2002).
(19) ECB (2011) p. 10.
(20) The Bank of England had swap agreements with European central
banks in the 1992 ERM crisis and a deterioration in the mark to market
value eventually led to the loss of sterling.
(21) Ferran (2014), p. I.
Angus Armstrong, NIESR and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail:
[email protected].