The short-term economic impact of leaving the EU.
Baker, Jessica ; Carreras, Oriol ; Ebell, Monique 等
Our forecast, published in the UK chapter of this Review, is
conditioned on the assumption that the result of the 23 June referendum
is a vote to remain in the EU. The discussion of the economic impact in
the first half of the year, and the accompanying uncertainty due to the
very act of having the vote, is discussed in the UK chapter in this
Review.
However, there exists a significant possibility of a vote to leave
the EU. The future is, by definition, uncertain and we normally
represent this with a distribution of potential outcomes around our
modal path for the economy. The referendum presents a particular
instance where the future may be genuinely considered bi-modal, with two
distinct paths. The outcome of the referendum will determine which of
these future paths the UK economy takes.
This note presents a simulation exercise designed to give a
counterfactual of a world in which the UK votes to leave the EU. We
discuss the short-run developments that are most likely to affect the UK
economy in the immediate aftermath of a leave vote. We do this by
introducing a range of shocks to our global econometric model designed
to capture the effects of the UK leaving the EU. These shocks are
layered together with a series of more long-run structural changes which
are discussed by Ebell and Warren, in this Review.
Focusing on the near-term implications, our analysis suggests that
the level of GDP in 2017 will be 1 per cent lower than our baseline
forecast presented in the UK section of this Review. By 2018 this loss
of output widens to 2.3 per cent. Heightened risk and uncertainty will
cause sterling to depreciate by around 20 per cent immediately following
the referendum, which will result in an intense bout of inflationary
pressure. Meanwhile, the same uncertainty induces a tightening of credit
conditions and a fall in domestic demand as consumption and investment
fall relative to the counterfactual of a vote to remain.
We begin by detailing the process by which the UK would negotiate
exiting the EU followed by a comprehensive exposition of the shocks that
form the core of our short-run analysis. We then conclude with the
quantitative implications of our simulation exercise, macroeconomic
policy responses and a discussion of the transition to the longer run,
which is discussed in detail in Ebell and Warren, in this Review.
The exit process
Should the vote in June result in a decision to leave the European
Union, a number of things will happen. First, the UK government will
notify the European Council of its intention to withdraw. The process
for withdrawal is then governed by Article 50 of the Lisbon Treaty. The
UK has a 2-year window to negotiate a withdrawal agreement, which would
include the terms of the UK's future relationship with the EU, and
which must be approved by a simple majority of the European Parliament
and an enhanced qualified majority (20 out of 27) of the remaining
Member States. An extension to the 2-year window can only be granted by
unanimous agreement of the remaining Member States.
If the 2-year deadline is reached without an approved agreement and
no extension is granted, the UK will fall back on WTO rules and so face
tariffs on exports to the EU at Most Favoured Nation (MFN) rates.
During the 2-year negotiation period there will be significant
uncertainty about the nature of the UK's future trading
relationships with the EU and third party countries. The likely length
of the negotiation process is itself uncertain as no country has
previously used Article 50 to withdraw from the Union. However, we
expect the 2-year timeframe to be optimistic based on previous
experiences of free trade agreements. Negotiations of the Free Trade
Agreement (FTA) between the EU and Canada began in 2009 and are still
ongoing. Greenland's withdrawal from the European Economic
Community in 1985 (predating the Lisbon Treaty, and therefore not
covered by Article 50) took three years to negotiate. Negotiations will
be more prolonged if the UK seeks ambitious concessions in preferential
access to the Single Market, for example free trade in services. An
agreement that included areas of foreign policy would require the
unanimous agreement of all 27 Member States, which in some cases would
require ratification by their national parliaments, significantly
lengthening the process. The UK will also need to negotiate new free
trade agreements with third party countries such as the US, which are
likely to begin only after the agreement with the EU is finalised.
Businesses which rely on non-EU trade may therefore face a lengthier
period of uncertainty.
The short-run impact
A vote to leave would represent a substantial shock to the UK
economy which will have consequences for the short-run outlook. To think
about these consequences in the context of our econometric model (see
Appendix A for a brief summary of the model) we identify and calibrate a
number of more specific shocks. In the analysis presented below we first
provide a discussion of these shocks as well as their calibrations. We
then discuss how the imposition of these shocks changes the outlook for
the UK economy compared to the path laid out in our baseline forecast
presented in the earlier UK chapter.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The shocks
Exchange rate
As discussed in the UK chapter of this Review, markets have already
begun to price in a period of heightened sterling volatility around the
time of the referendum. Our analysis seems to indicate that this was the
dominant driver of the depreciation of sterling from the start of the
year to mid-April. More recently, sterling has recovered some of this
ground, and market measures of uncertainty around sterling have also
reduced. Looking to betting markets and other poll evidence, this
reduction in risk is highly correlated with a lower weight being placed
on the possibility of a vote to leave the EU. Should such a result
become more likely, then we would expect to see the risk premium open up
again and sterling depreciate further.
It is therefore highly likely that a vote to leave the EU on 23
June will widen the risk premium associated with sterling. The question
for our analysis is, by how much? To calibrate our shock, we look to the
options-implied 3-month sterling volatility. This series rose sharply on
the day that the 3-month contract first encompassed the date of the
referendum, and remains elevated. Comparing this increase with that
observed in the recent global financial crisis we observe that it has
been approximately two-thirds of the size, figure
1. We therefore calibrate a shock to the exchange rate risk premium
by scaling the change in the risk premium in the fourth quarter of 2008
by two-thirds. The shock then decays by 50 per cent a quarter. It
reaches zero by the end of 2017 so that by the time the negotiating
window has been concluded the sterling risk premium has returned to its
baseline level.
Uncertainty
A brief overview of the literature
Before presenting our approach to deal with the increase in
uncertainty that the referendum will generate in the event of a leave
vote, it is convenient to present the main results that the theoretical
and empirical literature has produced on the effects of uncertainty on
economic activity, as well as the different measures of uncertainty that
have been developed. We cannot hope to provide a comprehensive survey in
this note but at least we can highlight the main points.
A large body of literature has looked into the effects of
uncertainty on investment decisions of firms. An early strand of the
literature captured in the work by Oi (1961), Hartman (1972) and Abel
(1983) suggested that, contrary to common belief, uncertainty could lead
to higher investment if marginal returns to investment were convex.
Later on, Bernanke (1983), Pindyck (1988) and Dixit (1989) showed that
under the presence of sunk costs to investment, which render marginal
returns to capital concave, a firm will delay investment projects
following an increase in uncertainty as there will be a value in
waiting. (1) Investing triggers a cost that cannot be recovered and
therefore it is optimal for the firm to wait until the realisation of
the uncertain outcome ensures sufficiently high expected returns. Leahy
and Whited (1996), using firm-level data, found empirical evidence of
uncertainty exerting a negative influence on investment, thus giving
support to the latter strand of work. Recent work includes Bloom (2009),
who finds that higher uncertainty causes firms to delay investment and
hiring as well as declines in productivity growth as the rate of
reallocation of resources from low to high productivity firms is
inhibited, Bloom et al. (2014), who find similar results within the
context of a DSGE model extended to include uncertainty shocks, and
Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2015), who find that volatility in fiscal
shocks also induces negative effects on economic activity within a New
Keynesian model framework. There seems to be a consensus that
uncertainty drives firms to delay their investment plans.
Besides theoretical work, there has been a considerable amount of
empirical work to establish a link between uncertainty and economic
activity. The results have been broadly in line with the lessons we
learned from the theory. Beaulieu et al. (2005) analysed four major
events between 1990 and 1996, including the second referendum on the
question of Quebec's independence from Canada in 1995, and found
that firms with higher exposure to political risk had to generate a
higher return in the period of heightened uncertainty in the run-up to
the referendum. Durnev (2010) found that corporate investment becomes
less responsive to stock market prices in periods surrounding elections,
with the effect being largest when election results are less certain.
The decline in investment-to-price sensitivity seems to be explained by
market participants perceiving stock prices to be less informative
during election times. Julio and Yook (2012), using data on national
elections for a large number of countries between 1980 and 2005, found
that firms reduce, on average, investment expenditures by 4.8 per cent
during election years relative to non-election years.
Having established a link between uncertainty and economic
activity, the question of how to measure uncertainty comes to the fore.
There are several measures that have been used in academic and
nonacademic work and we identify some broad categories: firstly,
uncertainty/volatility indices derived from stock market price
movements, particularly from option-like assets. One such example is the
VIX, an index of 30-day option-implied volatility based on the
S&P500 index maintained by the Chicago Board Options Exchange
(CBOE). Secondly, there are uncertainty measures based on estimating
stochastic processes with time varying second moments which serve to
capture different degrees of uncertainty over the time line. Examples
include Justiniano and Primiceri (2008), Bloom (2009) and
Fernandez-Villaverde et al. (2015). Finally, there are text search
methods such as the one by Baker et al. (2015), where the uncertainty
index is measured by the number of times a certain set of words related
to the topic at hand appears written in newspapers, central bank
minutes, and so on.
Our note borrows heavily from all this literature. On the one hand,
given the theoretical and empirical results we endorse the view of
uncertainty exerting a negative influence on firms' investment
plans and embed this result in our investment equation. On the other, we
borrow from the literature several of the proposed measures to capture
uncertainty in order to construct the data series on uncertainty that
will feed our investment equation.
Modelling uncertainty within NiGEM
In order to quantify the impact of short-run fluctuations in
uncertainty on business investment, we extend our estimated error
correction model of business investment using a measure of uncertainty
as a variable to help explain short-run deviations from the long-run
relationship. According to standard economic theory, demand for capital
as a factor of production is determined by the real user cost of
capital, the production technology and the mark-up over unit costs. We
follow Barrell and Riley (2006), complementing their specification with
a measure of uncertainty and capacity utilisation.
Following the methodology employed by Haddow et al. (2013), our
measure of uncertainty is derived from extracting the first principal
component from the following series:
1. FTSE option-implied volatility (2)
2. Sterling option-implied volatility (3)
3. CBI 'demand uncertainty limiting investment' score (4)
4. Economic policy uncertainty index (5)
Principal component analysis identifies a common trend from
multiple series. The assumption underlying the method is that a common
driver exists amongst these variables (see Stock and Watson, 2002). Each
data series is stationary and each has been normalised prior to
extracting principal components. This extracted series is our measure of
uncertainty. Figure 2 shows the evolution of our measure of economic
uncertainty over time. Uncertainty, according to this measure, increased
to 0.65 in the first quarter of 2016 and we have assumed an increase to
1.3 in the second quarter. Since not all the series in our principal
component analysis are available at a daily frequency, our assumption is
based on sterling option-implied volatility, which has the largest
factor loading. This measure of uncertainty has almost doubled when
comparing the first 20 days of the current quarter to the first 20 days
of the previous quarter. Following a vote to leave the EU, uncertainty
in our simulation increases in the third quarter of 2016 to a level 3.7
units above our baseline. This assumption is based on data from betting
markets which gives a probability of a vote to leave of around a third.
From then on the series follows an AR(1) process with a coefficient of a
half, bringing the level of economic uncertainty back to its mean by
2020.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The government yield curve
Government bond markets are likely to be affected by a decision to
leave the European Union. For instance, a number of ratings agencies
have intimated that such a move could cause them to re-evaluate the
status of UK government securities, and perhaps even prompt a downgrade.
(6) The result would almost certainly be an increase in the cost of
borrowing for the UK government.
Even in the absence of an official downgrade, the uncertainty
immediately following a vote to leave is likely to dissuade investors
from holding gilts. Around 1/4 of the outstanding gilt market is held by
overseas investors who are easily able to move their money across
international markets, and who might be particularly sensitive to the
exchange rate movements and uncertainty associated with a vote to leave.
What is more, if investors believe that leaving the EU will have
negative consequences for the medium and long-term outlook for the UK
economy, they will be inclined to seek more rewarding and less risky
investment opportunities.
Armstrong and Portes, in this Review, argue that there is a risk of
break-up of the UK in the event of a vote to leave the EU. If there were
a second independence referendum, and the Scottish electorate were to
judge that its interests were better served as an EU member outside the
UK, then some additional disruption to the UK economy could be expected.
One of the issues which would again come up is the division of the
UK's national debt, with accompanying risks for the rest of the
UK's fiscal position and this could elevate sovereign risk premia
further.
Such a change in sentiment may cause a sell-off in gilts, or at
least a fall in demand, which for a given supply would lower the price
and push up the yield. To model this, we shock the government bond
premia, which acts as a wedge between the forward convolution of
short-term interest rates and the interest rate on long-term government
bonds. To calibrate the shock, we look at a number of academic studies.
Joyce et al. (2011) look at the financial market impact of quantitative
easing. Although this policy was one which affected the publicly
available supply of gilts, rather than demand, the elasticities may be
informative. They find that the reduction in the publicly available
supply associated with the first quantitative easing programme decreased
gilt yields by approximately 100 basis points. Studies by Breedon et al.
(2014), Meaning and Zhu (2011) and Meaning and Warren (2015) find
quantitatively similar results. Assuming similar elasticities for supply
and demand, such a shift would imply a fall in demand of roughly 12 per
cent of the total gilt market.
Our shock is therefore set to increase the premium on government
bonds by 100 basis points in the third quarter of 2016. It stays at this
elevated level for a further three quarters before receding back to its
pre-referendum level over the next twelve months. This relatively
short-lived shock could easily prove more persistent should economic
conditions deteriorate in the post vote-to-leave world, or for instance
if the renegotiation of trade deals takes longer than expected.
It should be noted that government bond premia derived by comparing
overnight index swap rates with gilt rates of an equivalent maturity
have risen 10-20 basis points already since the announcement of the date
of the referendum. This is in a period when financial markets have
attached a relatively low probability to a vote to leave and so could be
considered very much a lower bound. There are two caveats to this shock
which merit comment. The first is that there is a possibility that in an
uncertain world, investors become more risk-averse and therefore move
out of higher risk sterling investments into more secure assets. Some of
this portfolio switching may be directed towards UK government
securities, which would offset some of the negative effects we have
discussed above. However, with a depreciating currency eroding the
international value of sterling-denominated securities, and a weaker
outlook for growth, it seems more likely that investors will prefer to
rebalance into other relatively safe assets, such as US Treasury
securities, or German bunds. As such, we do not place much importance on
this offset in our simulation exercise.
The second caveat is that, to counter a fall in demand for UK
government securities, the Bank of England could reawaken its
quantitative easing programme. By stepping in to purchase a large
quantity of gilts on the secondary market, quantitative easing could
offset the reduction in private sector demand and stabilise yields in
the gilt market. The difficulty is that the Bank of England already
holds over 20 per cent of the outstanding gilt market and any
intervention would probably have to raise this share significantly. In
our simulation exercise, we assume that the Bank of England does not
enact a new round of quantitative easing, but that it does continue to
re-invest the principal payments from bonds maturing from its existing
portfolio, and thus maintain the size of its balance sheet.
Premia on the cost of borrowing
Corporate and household lending spreads
Several elements support a view that following a vote to leave the
cost of debt financing for firms and households would increase. Firstly,
the sheer degree of uncertainty around the outcome of the UK's
trade deals with the EU and the rest of the world might be enough to
increase the cost of funding of UK financial and non-financial
corporates, particularly those whose main line of business relies on
trade with EU countries. As mentioned in the previous section, the three
main credit rating agencies, S&P, Moody's and Fitch, have
already suggested that they are likely to put the credit rating of
UK's sovereign debt on a negative outlook if a vote to leave wins.
If sovereign debt receives a negative outlook it is likely that
corporate debt will receive similar treatment, as suggested by the
"sovereign ceiling" concept (Almeida et al., 2016), whereby it
is very rare that corporates are granted ratings above the sovereign
one, which, in turn, implies that corporates that share the same rating
as the sovereign receive a credit downgrade when the sovereign receives
one.
Secondly, as suggested by Davies and Panetta (2011), banks suffer
from sovereign downgrading over and above the trickledown effect on
their own rating as it inflicts losses on their sovereign portfolios,
reduces the value of a significant part of the assets that they can use
as collateral and lessens the funding benefits that banks derive from
government guarantees. As banks' balance sheets come under
pressure, the cost of bank lending to firms and households is likely to
increase. In addition, following a vote to leave the Bank of England may
decide to introduce measures, such as higher bank capital requirements,
to ensure the stability of the UK's financial system. In fact, it
has already introduced a 0.5 percentage point increase in capital
requirements for risk-weighted assets due on 29 March 2017 (see FPC
statement March 2016). Such measures will almost certainly increase the
cost of bank funding even if it is by a small degree (see for instance
Miles et al., 2013).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Finally, as suggested by Armstrong, in this Review, banks are
likely to face an increase in transaction costs derived from the loss of
access to the European financial structure, additional regulatory
burdens and the establishment of subsidiary branches in EU countries
with the implicit risk that comes with it of eroding the appeal of
keeping the UK branch as the European headquarter. Higher transaction
costs on the side of banks would most likely be passed through to some
extent to firms and households, thus raising the cost of borrowing.
Our approach to calibrate the shock to the cost of debt funding in
the model has been to pool the estimates from the literature on the
effects of negative credit rating announcements enacted by credit rating
agencies on sovereign spreads and look at previous past historical
episodes to derive a conservative estimate of the magnitude of the
shock. We focus on the literature on sovereign spreads and use the
concept of sovereign ceiling mentioned before to link the results that
we find to the corporate sector and, in turn, to households via banks.
Table 1 summarises a few results from the literature.
There is a question over the direction of causation between credit
rating decisions and sovereign spreads. It could well be that
agencies' announcements are just a reflection of credit
developments already factored in by the market and therefore carry no
additional information. However, for the purpose of this analysis what
is of relevance is not whether announcements trigger movements in
spreads, but rather that announcements highlight times of heightened
uncertainty on certain assets which allow calibrating movements in
spreads derived from times of higher uncertainty.
Looking at the recent history provides some guidance as well.
Figure 3 plots the spread of UK corporate AAA and BBB graded bonds over
the 10 year gilt and figure 4 plots the credit default swap (CDS) spread
on UK sovereign 5-year bonds. During the Great Recession, spreads of AAA
graded corporates increased by 150 basis points and those of BBB graded
bonds by around 600 basis points. The Eurozone sovereign debt crisis
induced increases in spreads of 100 and 300 basis points for the AAA and
BBB graded bonds, respectively. The UK CDS sovereign spread increased by
at least 70 basis points during the great recession and by around 50
basis points during the Eurozone sovereign crisis. Note that data on CDS
spreads already displays an increase of 20 basis points on the cost of
insuring against default on UK sovereign debt over the past three
months. Although we cannot map such an increase in the spread to a
pricing in of the effects of a vote to leave it is hard to imagine that
such an event bears no relation to the response of the cost of insuring.
Pooling all the information on the effects of credit rating
agencies' negative outlooks statements on bond spreads as well as
the historical data gives us a range of conservative estimates falling
between 30 to 100 basis points increase in the cost of financing
following the period of heightened uncertainty that would start after a
vote to leave. Our choice has been to err on the conservative side and
we have implemented an increase of 50 basis points over a two-year
window starting from the third quarter of 2016. We opt for the appeal of
simplicity and shock the spread between loan and deposit rates that
households face by 50 basis points as well. In practice this is akin to
assuming that banks maintain their profit margins and pass the
adjustment to their cost structure to households.
Equity premium
Not only should the cost of debt financing increase following the
increase in uncertainty triggered by a vote to leave, but also the cost
of equity. The fundamental factor that determines the cost of capital is
unchanged: the expected stream of future dividends that companies can
produce. However, this stream becomes much more difficult to forecast
accurately given all the uncertainties that surround a vote to leave.
From this perspective, we introduce a shock to the cost of equity
finance equivalent to the shock we have introduced to debt finance: an
increase in the spread over the risk free rate of 50 basis points that
lasts for two years starting from the third quarter of 2016.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
A brief look at the historical value of equity finance premium
reassures us regarding the magnitude of the shock. Figure 5 plots the
spread of the UK market wide dividend yield against the 10 year gilt
yield; a measure of the equity premium. During the great recession the
spread increased by around 300 basis points and during the sovereign
crisis by around a 100 basis points. A rather surprising element
observed in figure 5, that the spread kept increasing after the
sovereign crisis, is explained by a continuous decline in the risk-free
rate rather than an increase in the dividend yield of the UK stock
market. From this perspective, the magnitude of our shock is well within
the interval of possible increases in the spread following a period of
heightened uncertainty.
As a robustness check to our choice of the shock, we estimated an
equation linking the spread on equity finance with our measure of
uncertainty described previously. (7) We then obtained the increase in
the spread that would result from a three standard deviation shock in
our uncertainty measure that declines at an autoregressive rate of 0.5
per model period; a very similar shock to the one we have implemented in
our main scenario. The outcome is very similar to the magnitude of the
shock that we have implemented.
The outlook after a vote to leave the EU
In our short-run scenario, we bring together each of the shocks
discussed above. These are then layered in with the more structural
long-run effects of the UK leaving the European Union that are discussed
in the following paper in this Review by Ebell and Warren. The results
of this simulation exercise are presented an an annual frequency in
table 3.
What we see is that on impact consumer price inflation jumps
dramatically, figure 6.This is driven predominantly by the large
depreciation of sterling, figure 7, which is itself a result of the
widening of the risk premium. With the sterling effective exchange rate
falling around 20 per cent on impact and remaining 14 per cent below the
counterfactual in 2017, import prices rise and generate inflationary
pressure in the consumption basket.
Real GDP is broadly unaffected in 2016 as the decline in domestic
demand is offset by a marginally positive net trade contribution, figure
8. This comes from a temporary terms of trade improvement as the
depreciation of sterling boosts the price competitiveness of UK
exporters, while reducing the attractiveness of imports to UK consumers.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
This is however short-lived and, by 2017, the domestic factors
dominate, causing the level of GDP to fall to just over 1 per cent lower
than in our baseline forecast.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Investment falls dramatically, figure 10. This comes through a
number of channels. First is the direct impact of uncertainty. This
shock in isolation results in a drop in business investment of just over
10 per cent in the third quarter of 2016, compared to the baseline case
of a vote against leaving the EU, rising to 12 1/2 per cent the
following quarter before gradually returning to baseline levels. This
direct effect is modest compared to other quantitative analyses. Bloom
et al. (2014) for example simulate the effects of uncertainty on
investment using a DSGE model calibrated using data on US firm's
investment behaviour. They find that a 91 per cent increase in
uncertainty results in a fall in investment of around 18 per cent.
Similarly, Bond and Cummins (2004) investigate the effects of increasing
uncertainty as measured by the standard deviation of daily stock returns
on publicly traded US firms. They find that a 15 per cent increase in
uncertainty reduces investment by 6 per cent.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
In addition to the direct uncertainty effect, we also observe a
substitution effect between labour and capital as inputs which further
weighs on investment. Falling real producer wages make labour a more
cost effective input, while widening borrowing premia pushes up the user
cost of capital, reducing the attractiveness of capital and lowering the
optimal capital/output ratio.
Consumption is hit by lower real incomes alongside increased costs
of credit and relative reductions in wealth as house prices fall, figure
11.
Macroeconomic policy responses
The response of policymakers over this period will be extremely
hard to predict. With this in mind, in our baseline counterfactual
exercise we assume that the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) chooses to
wait for the uncertainty to subside before making a decisive policy
move. As such, Bank rate is held fixed for the first two years of the
simulation, until the third quarter of 2018. From this point on we
assume the MPC reacts to the evolution of the economy by following a
Taylor rule. This means that they set the short-term nominal interest
rate in response to fluctuations in the output gap and deviations of
inflation from its 2 per cent target rate.
We parameterise this policy rule using the coefficients used in the
Bank of England's own COMPASS model, as detailed in Burgess et al.
(2013).
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
An interesting exercise is to see what effect our assumption of a
fixed Bank Rate would have, compared to a world in which the MPC sets
Bank Rate in line with its policy rule from the first instance. In this
world, the policy rule as defined above would dictate that the Bank of
England would loosen the stance of monetary policy by cutting Bank Rate
by between 50 and 100 basis points relative to the counterfactual over
the course of 2016 and 2017, figure 12. Based on the current market
expectation of the path of Bank Rate, this would imply a move to zero,
if not marginally negative, nominal interest rates.8 To do this at a
time when inflation is above target, as our scenario would suggest, may
appear counterintuitive. However, as outlined previously, the bulk of
the inflationary pressure stems from the sharp depreciation of sterling
rather than a boom in domestic price pressures, which in fact would be
likely to be softening. Therefore it may be that the MPC chooses to look
through the temporary inflationary period in order to stimulate
underlying demand and meet the mandated target more sustainably in the
medium to long-term.
We can see in figures 6-11 that allowing monetary policy to
actively stabilise the economy from the off makes little difference to
our central narrative. It does manage to reduce the spike in inflation
in 2017 by around Vi percentage point, but with a trade-off in the shape
of a marginally weaker outlook for GDP.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
Within our simulation exercise, we make no allowance for
unconventional monetary policies. If the MPC members feel they wish to
stimulate the economy without implementing a negative policy rate, they
have alternative policy instruments, most notably a fresh round of
quantitative easing. By compressing the premia inherent in government
bond yields, quantitative easing may be able to lower interest rates at
the longer end of the yield curve and provide some additional stimulus.
The Bank of England also has responsibility for maintaining the
stability of the UK's financial system. In this capacity senior
Bank officials have already intimated that preparations have been made
for large-scale liquidity provision in the event that a vote to leave
creates unacceptable levels of market tension. If markets see the Bank
as credible in this role of lender of last resort then the very promise
to act may attenuate the worst of any market panic.
From the fiscal side, the budget position is worsened by 0.2 per
cent of GDP in 2017 and 0.6 per cent of GDP in 2018, making it
increasingly difficult for the government to achieve an absolute surplus
by 2019-20, figure 13. Notably, the weaker performance of the economy
may in fact provide increased fiscal space as within the current mandate
there is a clause which states that the government no longer needs to
achieve a budgetary surplus if GDP growth falls below 1 per cent per
annum. The figures implied by our counterfactual exercise suggest that
this would happen in 2018.
Transitioning to the longer run
None of the shocks detailed above persist beyond the 2-year
negotiating period. This may seem a generous assumption, considering the
potentially protracted nature of negotiations not only with the EU, but
also with the rest of the UK's trading partners, both old and new.
However, beyond this horizon we deem it likely that much of the
uncertainty will have dissipated and markets will have a much clearer
idea of the direction both the negotiations, and the UK economy, are
taking, even if not all of the issues are fully resolved.
The counterpart to this waning uncertainty though is that as
decisions are made and final positions taken, the more structural and
permanent changes to the UK economy come into effect. As our uncertainty
and premia shocks fade through 2017 and early 2018 there is a gradual
introduction of changes to the UK's share of export markets, and
eventually the imposition of tariffs. These second-phase shocks are
detailed and discussed in Ebell and Warren, who analyse a range of
post-EU arrangememnts for the UK. The results we have presented here
have been derived on the assumptions within their WTO variant. For
details of this, the readeer is referred to the work which follows. It
must be noted that the ultimate long-run assumptions have consequences
for our transition period. The forward-looking nature of agents means
that, although subject to uncertainty, they do foresee, at least in
part, the shifts that are ahead of them. The negative fallout from these
later shocks in fact acts to weigh down on the performance of the UK
even before they come in to effect.
NOTES
(1) The result holds under the assumption of continuous uncertainty
as well as when the stochastic process underlying the uncertain outcome
does not display mean regression.
(2) Three-month option-implied volatility of the FTSE 100 All-share
index. Source: Datastream
(3) Three-month option-implied volatility of the sterling-euro and
sterling-dollar export-weighted exchange rate. Source: Datastream.
(4) 'Uncertainty about demand' score from the question
'What factors are likely to limit your capital expenditure
authorisations over the next twelve months' in the Confederation of
British Industry's (CBI) Quarterly Industrial Trends and Service
Sector surveys.
(5) Index based on newspaper articles regarding policy uncertainty.
Source: http://www.policyuncertainty.com/index.html
(6) Source: Bloomberg (2016), Moody's (2015) and Fitch Ratings
(2015).
(7) We obtained the best fit by regressing our measure of equity
finance premium against our measure of uncertainty and two lags of the
dependent variable.
(8) The depth of the cut in Bank Rate may appear overstated by
figure 12, as it shows the absolute difference from a baseline which
assumes Bank Rate begins to rise from the final quarter of 2016. This
means that policy is in fact in part looser just by holding rates lower
for longer, reducing the actual size of the implied cut. However, market
expectations are for Bank Rate to be flat until the end of 2020, and so
the path shown in figure 12 would imply a reduction in Bank Rate to
approximately--1/2 per cent per annum at the most extreme.
REFERENCES
Abel, A.B. (1983), 'Optimal investment under
uncertainty', The American Economic Review, 73(1), pp. 228-33.
Alfonso, A., Furceri, D. and Gomes, P. (2012), 'Sovereign
credit ratings and financial markets linkages: application to European
data.', Journal of International Money and Finance, 31 (3), pp.
606-38.
Almeida, H., Cunha, I., Ferreira, M.A. and Restrepo, F. (2014), The
real effects of sovereign credit rating downgrades', Research
Paper.
Baker, S.R., Bloom, N. and Davis, S. J. (2015), 'Measuring
economic policy uncertainty', National Bureau of Economic Research,
No. w2I633.
Bank of England, Financial Policy Committee (2016), News Release,
March 2016.
Barrell, R. and Dury, K. (2003), 'Asymmetric labour markets in
a converging Europe: do differences matter?', National Institute
Economic Review, 183, pp. 56-64.
Barrell, R. and Pain, N. (1997), 'Foreign direct investment,
technological change, and economic growth within Europe', Economic
Journal, 107, pp. 1770-76.
Barrell, R. and Riley, R. (2006), 'Is UK business investment
unusually weak?', National Institute Economic Review, 196, pp.
60-62.
Blanchard, O.J. and Fisher, S. (1989), Lectures on Macroeconomics,
Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Beaulieu, M.C., Cosset, J.C., and Essaddam, N. (2005), 'The
impact of political risk on the volatility of stock returns: the case of
Canada '.Journal of International Business Studies, pp. 701-18.
Bernanke, B.S. (1983), 'Irreversibility, uncertainty, and
cyclical investment', The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(1),
pp. 85-106.
Bloom, N. (2009), 'The impact of uncertainty shocks',
Econometrica, 77(3), pp. 623-85.
Bloom, N., Floetotto, M., Jaimovich, N., Saporta Eksten, I. and
Terry, S. (2014), 'Really uncertain business cycles', US
Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies, Paper No. CES-WP-I4-I8.
Bloomberg (2016), 'The impact of 'Brexit' on
Sovereign Ratings for the U.K.', February 2016.
Bond, S. and Cummins, J. (2004), 'Uncertainty and investment:
an empirical investigation using data on analysts' profits
forecasts', Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2004-20, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US).
Breedon, F., Chadha, J. and Waters, A (2014), 'The financial
market impact of quantitative easing', Oxford Review of Economic
Policy.
Burgess, S., Fernandez-Corugeda, E., Groth, C., Harrison, R.,
Monti, F., Theodoridis, K. and Waldron, M. (2013), 'The Bank of
England's forecasting platform: COMPASS, MAPS, EASE and the suite
of models', Bank of England Working Paper No. 471.
Cantor, R. and Packer, F. (1996), 'Determinants and impact of
sovereign credit ratings', Economic policy review, 2(2).
Davies, M. and Panetta, F. (201 I), 'How does sovereign risk
affect bank funding conditions? What can policymakers do?', VoxEU.
org, 26.
Dixit, A. (1989), 'Entry and exit decisions under
uncertainty', Journal of political Economy, pp. 620-38.
Durnev, A. (2010), 'The real effects of political uncertainty:
elections and investment sensitivity to stock prices', SSRN Working
Paper Series.
Fernandez-Villaverde, J., Guerron-Quintana, P., Kuester, K. and
Rubio-Ramlrez, J. (2015), 'Fiscal volatility shocks and economic
activity', The American Economic Review, 105(11), pp. 3352-84.
Fitch Ratings (2015), 'Fitch: Brexit Vote Would Be Moderately
Credit Negative for UK', 14 December 2015.
Haddow, A., Hare, C., Hooley, J. and Shakir, T. (2013),
'Macroeconomic uncertainty; what is it, how can we measure it and
why does it matter?', Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 53, 2,
pp. 100-109.
Hartman, R. (1972), 'The effects of price and cost uncertainty
on investment', Journal of Economic Theory, 5(2), pp. 258-66.
Joyce, M., Lasaosa, A., Stevens, I. and Tong, M. (2010), 'The
financial market impact of quantitative easing', Bank of England
Working Paper No 393.
Julio, B. and Yook, Y. (2012), 'Political uncertainty and
corporate investment cycles', The Journal of Finance, 67(1), pp.
45-83.
Justiniano, A. and Primiceri, G.E. (2008), 'The time-varying
volatility of macroeconomic fluctuations', The American Economic
Review, 98(3), p. 604-41.
Kiff, J., Nowak, S.B. and Schumacher, L.B. (2012), 'Are rating
agencies powerful? An investigation into the impact and accuracy of
sovereign ratings', IMF Working Paper, No. 12/23.
Leahy, J. and Whited, T.M. (1996), 'The Effects of uncertainty
on investment: some stylized facts', Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 28(1), pp. 64-83.
Meaning, J. and Warren, J. (2015), 'The transmission of
unconventional monetary policy in UK debt markets', National
Institute Economic Review, 234.
Meaning, J. and Zhu, F. (201 I) 'The impact of recent central
bank asset purchase programmes', The Bank for International
Settlements Quarterly Review, December.
Miles, D., Yang, J. and Marcheggiano, G. (2013), 'Optimal bank
capital', The Economic Journal, 123(567), pp. 1-37.
Moody's (2015), 'EU exit would be negative for UK
economy, but credit impact would depend on policy', 3 December
2015.
Oi, W.Y. (1961), 'The desirability of price instability under
perfect competition', Econometrica, 29(I), pp. 58-64.
Pindyck, R.S. (1988), 'Irreversible investment, capacity
choice, and the value of the firm', The American Economic Review,
pp. 969-85.
Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W. (2002), 'Forecasting using
principal components from a large number of predictors', Journal of
the American Statistical Association, 97, 460, pp. 1167-79.
Appendix A. National Institute Global Econometric Model (NiGEM): a
non-technical overview
NiGEM is a global econometric model, and most countries in the EU,
the OECD and major emerging markets are modelled individually. The rest
of the world is modelled through regional blocks so that the model is
global in scope. All country models contain the determinants of domestic
demand, export and import volumes, prices, current accounts and gross
foreign assets and liabilities. Output is tied down in the long run by
factor inputs and technical progress interacting through production
functions. Economies are linked through trade, competitiveness and
financial markets and are fully simultaneous.
Agents are presumed to be forward-looking, at least in some
markets, but nominal rigidities slow the process of adjustment to
external shocks. The model has complete demand and supply sides; there
is an extensive monetary and financial sector, together with household
and government sectors. As far as possible the same theoretical
structure has been adopted for each country. As a result, variations in
the properties of each country model reflect genuine differences
emerging from estimation, rather than different theoretical approaches.
Policy reactions are important in the determination of speeds of
adjustment. Nominal short-term interest rates are set in relation to a
forward looking feedback rule. Forward looking long-term interest rates
are the forward convolution of future short-term interest rates with an
exogenous term premium. An endogenous tax rule ensures that governments
remain solvent in the long run; the deficit and debt stock return to
sustainable levels after any shock, as is discussed in Blanchard and
Fisher (1989). Exchange rates are forward looking and so can
'jump' in response to a shock.
Within NiGEM, labour markets in each country are described by a
wage equation (see Barrell and Dury, 2003 for a detailed description)
and a labour demand equation (see, for example, Barrell and Pain, 1997).
The wage equations depend on productivity and unemployment, and have a
degree of rational expectations embedded in them--that is to say the
wage bargain is assumed to depend partly on expected future inflation
and partly on current inflation. The speed of the wage adjustment is
estimated for each country. Wages adjust to bring labour demand in line
with labour supply. Employment depends on real producer wages, output
and trend productivity, again with speeds of adjustment of employment
estimated and varying for each country.
We do not allow for an impaired interest rate channel or an
increase in liquidity constrained consumers, while hysteresis effects in
labour and capital markets are not a feature in NiGEM and so we do not
address any of these effects that might materialise.
Jessica Baker, Oriol Carreras, Monique Ebell, Ian Hurst, Simon
Kirby, Jack Meaning, Rebecca Piggott and James Warren *
* National Institute of Economic and Social Research. E-mail:
[email protected]. Thanks to Angus Armstrong and Jagjit Chadha for
helpful comments and suggestions.
Table 1. Empirical estimates of effects of credit agencies downgrades
Paper Empirical estimate
Cantor and A one-notch downgrade from a credit rating agency
Packer (1996) correlates with an increase of the sovereign yield
spread of 22 per cent. With the current spread between
UK 10-year gilts and the German bund equivalent that
would amount to around an increase of around 30 basis
points.
Alfonso et A negative outlook statement from credit agencies
al. (2012) generates a 7 basis points increase in sovereign bond
yields within the two-day window before and after the
announcement. A downgrade, 11 basis points.
Kiff et al. Sovereign bond spreads of advanced economies increase
(2012) by as much as 100 basis points in the 20 days before
and after a credit rating downgrade announcement.
Table 2. Summary of short-term shocks introduced from 2016Q3
Calibrated from Size of shock
Exchange rate 3-month options-implied 2/3 of the magnitude
premium sterling volatility observed in 2008
Uncertainty Betting markets and Three times the
historical data level in 2016Q2
Term premium Joyce et al. (201 1), Breedon 100 basis points
et al. (2012),
Meaning and Warren (2015)
Household and Cantor and Packer (1996), 50 basis points
corporate Alfonso et al. (2012), Kiff
credit premium et al. (2012), historical data
and author's calculations
Equity premium Historical data and author's 50 basis points
calculations
Duration
Exchange rate Shock decays to zero
premium over the following 7 quarters
Uncertainty Shock decays to zero over the
following 13 quarters
Term premium Shock persists for 4 quarters and
then decays to zero over the
following 4 quarters
Household and Shock persists for 6 quarters and then
corporate decays to zero over the following
credit premium two quarters
Equity premium Shock persists for 6 quarters and then
decays to zero over the following
two quarters
Table 3. Summary: WTO variant
2016 2017 2018 2019
GDP Optimistic -0.2 -1.0 -2.3 -2.8
% change from base Pessimistic -0.2 -0.7 -2.4 -3.5
Consumption Optimistic -0.1 -1.2 -1.7 -2.1
% change from base Pessimistic -0.1 -1.5 -2.1 -2.8
Investment (PSI) Optimistic -4.8 -15.0 -12.8 -8.1
% change from base Pessimistic -4.8 -15.1 -13.8 -9.0
Real consumer wages Optimistic -0.6 -1.9 -2.1 -2.9
% change from base Pessimistic -0.6 -2.6 -3.0 -4.1
Output per hour worked Optimistic -0.4 -1.1 -1.6 -1.6
% change from base Pessimistic -0.4 -0.5 -1.6 -1.8
Unemployment, % Optimistic -0.2 -0.1 0.7 1.2
Change in levels Pessimistic -0.2 0.2 0.8 1.7
Inflation Optimistic 0.7 2.2 1.3 1.3
Change in levels Pessimistic 0.7 3.8 2.1 1.8
Bank rate, % Optimistic 0.00 0.00 0.25 0.50
Change in levels Pessimistic 0.00 0.00 0.25 0.75
Long rate, % Optimistic 0.5 1.0 0.1 -0.1
Change in levels Pessimistic 0.5 1.0 0.1 -0.1
Effective direct Optimistic 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.4
tax rate, % Pessimistic 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.6
Change in levels
2020 2025 2030
GDP Optimistic -2.5 -2.6 -2.7
% change from base Pessimistic -3.3 -3.4 -3.7
Consumption Optimistic -2.4 -3.2 -4.0
% change from base Pessimistic -3.3 -4.2 -5.4
Investment (PSI) Optimistic -4.6 -3.4 -2.7
% change from base Pessimistic -4.6 -3.3 -2.4
Real consumer wages Optimistic -3.5 -4.2 -4.6
% change from base Pessimistic -4.9 -5.8 -6.3
Output per hour worked Optimistic -1.8 -2.4 -2.7
% change from base Pessimistic -2.2 -3.2 -3.6
Unemployment, % Optimistic 0.8 0.3 0.1
Change in levels Pessimistic 1.2 0.3 0.2
Inflation Optimistic 0.4 0.1 0.0
Change in levels Pessimistic 0.6 0.1 0.0
Bank rate, % Optimistic 0.00 0.00 -0.25
Change in levels Pessimistic 0.25 0.00 -0.25
Long rate, % Optimistic -0.1 -0.1 -0.2
Change in levels Pessimistic -0.2 -0.2 -0.3
Effective direct Optimistic 0.6 0.3 0.6
tax rate, % Pessimistic 0.8 0.4 0.8
Change in levels
Source: NiGEM simulations.
Note: For details of long-run shock see Ebell and Warren,
in this Review.