Prospects for the UK economy.
Kirby, Simon ; Carreras, Oriol ; Meaning, Jack 等
The production of this forecast is supported by the
Institute's Corporate Members: Bank of England, HM Treasury, Mizuho
Research Institute Ltd, Office for National Statistics, Santander (UK)
pic and by the members of the NiGEM users group.
Introduction
The debate over whether the UK should remain a member of the
European Union (EU) is now raging. The outcome of the referendum, on 23
June 2016, is far from certain. The consequent risk of a vote to leave
appears already to be weighing on the domestic economy. (1) The UK
economy faces a bi-modal future, one that will, on one level, be
resolved in less than two months, at the time of writing; the outcome of
the referendum will determine which future path the economy travels.
Heightened uncertainty does not end with a vote to leave the EU. Rather
there would then be considerable risks arising with respect to outcomes
of negotiations to define the UK's relationships with the EU and
the rest of the world.
The forecast presented in this chapter is based on the key
conditioning assumption that the UK electorate votes to remain a member
of the EU. In this chapter we do not discuss the economic implications
were the UK to leave the EU. The interested reader should consult Baker
et al. and Ebell and Warren, in this Review, for illustrations of the
short and long-run impacts, respectively, of a vote to leave.
These two complementary notes use our global econometric model,
NiGEM, to illustrate the effects of a vote to leave. (2) In the short
term (Baker et al., in this Review), increased uncertainty leads to a
sharp fall in the exchange rate and an increase in risk premia and hence
firms' and households' borrowing costs, tightening the
monetary and financial conditions of the domestic economy. The
depreciation of the exchange rate, acting as a stabilisation mechanism,
softens the negative economic impact.
To illustrate the long-run effect, Ebell and Warren (in this
Review) model the impact of an exit from the EU through the reductions
in goods and services trade, increased tariff barriers, reduction in
foreign direct investment and a reduction in the UK's net fiscal
contribution to the EU. The three sets of economic model considered are:
a 'Norway' model where membership of the EEA is taken and free
trade in goods and services with the EU is maintained, including access
to EEA financial services markets via passporting; (3) a
'Switzerland' model where bilateral agreements with the EU on
free trade in goods occur, but there is no free trade in services and no
access to EEA financial services markets via passporting; and a World
Trade Organisation model where there is no free trade in goods and
services with the EU, and there is no passporting of financial services.
In these scenarios, the permanent loss of output ranges from about 1.5
to as high as 3.7 per cent.
Concerns about the state of economic recovery accompany every
estimate of a moderation in GDP growth. The preliminary estimate for the
first quarter of 2016 is no exception; economic growth is estimated to
have moderated to 0.4 per cent, from 0.6 per cent per quarter in the
final quarter of 2015. These concerns can often overlook the volatility
of the quarterly economic growth process.
However, with the risk of a structural shock to the UK economy on
the near-term horizon it is reasonable to ask whether this has
contributed to the recent softening in the rate of growth. A composite
index of uncertainty based on the first principal component of a broad
range of uncertainty and volatility measures does indeed suggest that
uncertainty increased noticeably in the first quarter of this year
(figure 1). One would expect this to weigh on some business investment
decisions. The Monetary Policy Committee's (MPC) minutes from their
April meeting point to recent signs of uncertainty weighing on
investment decisions. We have assumed that uncertainty caused by the
referendum weighs even further on investment decisions in the second
quarter of this year, with economic growth slowing a little more to 0.3
per cent per quarter.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Assuming a vote to remain a member of the EU, we expect an up-tick
in economic growth in the second half of this year as delayed investment
decisions are implemented. The economy is expected to expand by 2 per
cent per annum this year, 0.3 percentage point lower than the figure
expected just three months ago (figure 2), due to the more pronounced
deceleration in GDP growth than previously expected.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Quarterly rates of growth are expected to remain reasonably robust
throughout 2017. Given the weakness of growth in the first half of 2016,
growth in 2017 is forecast to reach 2.7 per cent per annum, supported by
a positive contribution from net trade. World trade, on a UK export
market weighted basis, has gradually accelerated from 1.9 per cent in
2012 to around 4 per cent last year. Continued recovery in the Euro Area
is expected to generate an acceleration to 5 per cent in 2016 and 5 1/2
per cent in 2017. Sterling's trade weighted exchange rate is
expected to average around 6 per cent below the third quarter of 2015.
The pass-through to export prices provides further support to export
volume growth over the next few years.
The future is by definition uncertain. We present this through a
distribution of possible outcomes around our forecast for the path of
the macroeconomy. Figure 3 provides the 'fan chart' for our
GDP forecast. The probability distribution is derived from stochastic
simulations using our global model, NiGEM. We see a 1 in 10 chance that
GDP growth will be as low as 1 per cent per annum in 2017. On the other
side of the distribution, there is a 10 per cent chance that the economy
will expand by 4 per cent or greater. By 2019 there is a 1 in 10 chance
of an outright contraction of the UK economy. Were the UK to leave the
EU, the expected paths for GDP growth are consistent with the lower half
of the distribution in figure 3. However, a vote to leave would migrate
the UK economy onto an entirely different path from the one presented
here, together with an entirely new probability distribution of
potential outcomes.
The poor productivity performance of the UK economy continues.
Output per hour worked declined by 1.1 per cent in the final quarter of
last year, reversing many of the productivity gains during the year. We
continue to assume that this drop is simply a 'blip'.
Productivity growth is expected to gradually accelerate over the course
of our forecast horizon, averaging around 1 1/2 per cent per annum. The
poor productivity performance since the end of the Great Recession
remains a puzzle. Not understanding the reasons behind the poor
performance raises a significant risk to the future path of the economy.
This poor productivity performance is the corollary of a remarkably
robust development in the labour market and relatively subdued demand.
Since the start of 2010, 2.4 million net jobs have been created. Over
the same time period, the unemployment rate dropped from 8 per cent to
5.1 per cent of the labour force. Job creation is expected broadly to
match the expansion of the labour force over the forecast period,
generating an additional net 1.2 million jobs. This keeps unemployment
close to its equilibrium rate of 5-5 1/2 per cent (figure 4). However,
consistent with the UK's poor productivity performance has been the
adjustment of real producer and consumer wages. Employees' real
consumer wages at the end of 2015 were only at the level they were in
the second half of 2003. With a sustained period of growth and
acceleration in productivity growth, as we assume in this forecast, it
will still take approximately seven years for real consumer wages to
return to the recent peak level of 2007.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
At the core of the government's fiscal framework is a target
for an absolute surplus in 2019-20. In our February Review, we did not
expect this target to be hit. Subsequently, the Office for Budget
Responsibility's (OBR) latest Economic and Fiscal Outlook (EFO)
revised their view in line with ours. Between the November 2015 and
March 2016 forecasts, the OBR have revised up the magnitude of borrowing
in their forecast for 2019-20 by 13 billion [pounds sterling] (the
OBR's pre-Budget measures forecast presented in their March 2016
EFO). This forecasting change by the OBR stemmed from a lowering of the
future path for productivity. The unsurprising response from the
government was to announce further discretionary policy changes in
Budget 2016 to ensure the OBR's forecast was for a surplus of
around 10 billion [pounds sterling].
Such fiscal interventions are a consequence of an inflexible fiscal
rule, rather than policy decisions that are required to ensure the
sustainability of the public finances. Indeed, even in the absence of
the announced policy changes in Budget 2016, both our forecast and that
of the OBR show the public sector becoming a net lender to the rest of
the economy a year later. A welcome change at a future fiscal event will
be the announcement of a flexible target, rather than the announcement
of yet more discretionary policy changes designed to mitigate the loss
of political capital from missing an inflexible target.
The current fiscal framework was passed into law last year. It
contains two additional targets: one that public sector net debt, as a
per cent of GDP, should be falling in each and every year from 2015-16.
The other is a limit on the welfare budget. Both additional targets have
already been missed.
Monetary conditions
The impending EU referendum has led us to push back the point at
which we expect the tightening phase of the monetary cycle to begin by
one quarter, to November of this year. The MPC has communicated that it
will view economic data with particular caution given the heightened
uncertainty associated with the referendum, and Governor Carney has
explicitly mentioned it as a cause of the relatively lacklustre
performance of the UK economy so far this year (MPC, 2016). However, the
path implied by market measures of expectations still seems implausibly
accommodative. If the OIS forward curve is to be believed then the first
rate hike is now not priced in until the first quarter of 2020, around
three years later than 3 months ago, and there is increasing probability
being placed on a near-term cut in Bank Rate, figure 5.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
It is likely that the softening of market expectations is heavily
influenced by concerns over the potential negative effects of the UK
voting to leave the European Union. However, absenting this and other
temporary factors such as exchange rate movements and commodities, it
seems that underlying price pressures continue to build. Conditioned on
our view that the UK votes to remain in the EU, we expect the narrative
in the second half of the year to return to one of gradually increasing
price pressures as spare capacity is absorbed and the labour market
tightens further. By the time of the November Inflation Report the MPC
will have seen the Preliminary Estimate of GDP for the third quarter of
this year, which we expect will be relatively robust, especially given
the likely catch-up effects as delayed spending and investment plans are
implemented.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Consumer price inflation is forecast to be below target in the
second half of this year and throughout 2017. However, looking two years
ahead from the final quarter of 2016, price pressures should be
sufficient to have raised inflation substantially. Given the lags in
policy transmission, we expect the MPC to move to raise rates by the end
of this year and then follow a policy of gradually tightening to 1.5 per
cent by the end of 2017. There exists a significant possibility that
caution will stay the hand of the MPC until February of 2017, by which
point they will have had a larger base of post-referendum data outturns
to assure them that this trajectory of prices is established. Assuming
that the subsequent path of policy tightening would be carried out at
the same pace, such a call would make little material difference to the
forecast presented here.
The exchange rate
In early April, the sterling effective exchange rate had
depreciated by around 8 per cent since the start of the year. This has
somewhat reversed in recent weeks, but sterling still sits 4 1/2 per
cent lower than it did at the beginning of January. Understanding the
cause of this depreciation is fundamental to our forecast of how the
real economy evolves (Kirby and Meaning, 2014). The uncovered interest
rate parity condition in our underlying model dictates that this can be
caused either by a shift in the interest rate differentials between the
UK and her trading partners, or by a widening of the premia associated
with sterling. Historically these premia have been dominated by changes
in risk, though more recently they have also captured non-interest rate
monetary interventions, such as quantitative easing.
The stance of monetary policy has relaxed in the UK since February
2016, for a given equilibrium interest rate, as expectations of Bank
Rate have fallen back relatively sharply. All else equal this could be
expected to lead to depreciation through a worsening interest rate
differential. However, it is important to remember that a differential
can be affected from both sides. Interest rate expectations in many of
the UK's trading partners have also softened over this period, and
it is the relative movement of rates that matters. In the Euro Area, for
instance, this reduction in expectations is quantitatively similar to
that observed in the UK. In the US the reduction is slightly smaller,
meaning that monetary conditions in the UK have loosened relative to the
US.
To assess the impact of these shifts we have performed a simulation
exercise using the National Institute's Global Econometric Model,
NiGEM. We impose the change in monetary policy expectations as an
exogenous shock to the future path of policy rates and allow the
structure and dynamics of the model to determine the path for exchange
rates and the rest of the economy.
Recent interest rate movements can be expected to lead to a
marginal depreciation of the sterling effective exchange rate, roughly
14 of 1 per cent. This is driven by the depreciation against the US
dollar, as the sterling/euro exchange rate actually appreciates
slightly. With the additional unconventional monetary stimulus announced
by the ECB in this period, which is not fully captured by our interest
rate shocks, we would expect this appreciation against the euro to be
even stronger. These results imply that little of the recent
depreciation of sterling has been driven by changes in the fundamental
expectation of interest rates, leaving most, if not all to be a result
of increased risk or uncertainty around the holding of sterling.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
A second way of analysing the recent depreciation is to calibrate
directly a shock to the risk premium associated with sterling. This can
be done using a number of metrics, but we look at the 3-month implied
volatility, as shown in figure 7. Here we can see a marked increase in
expected volatility since the start of the year, with a particular jump
on 23 March 2016. This is the point at which the 3-month contracts used
to derive these estimates of volatility first encapsulated the date of
the EU referendum. The series implies markets are pricing in a period of
significantly elevated volatility, and therefore risk, in sterling
around the referendum.
A longer time series shows that at present this expected risk is
about two-thirds of the level observed in the financial crisis of
2008--9. We therefore calibrate the size of our shock by scaling the
widening of the risk premium implied by our model in the last financial
crisis by two-thirds. Consistent with the data in figure 7 we introduce
the shock over two quarters, from the beginning of 2016. To ensure we
isolate the risk premium impact on the exchange rate, we hold short-term
interest rates constant, implying that monetary policy does not act to
offset the impact of the currency movement on domestic prices.
The shock leads to a depreciation of around 11 1/2 per cent of the
sterling effective exchange rate. This is not quantitatively too
dissimilar to the 8 per cent we observed in the actual movements in the
effective exchange rate between the start of the year and mid-April. It
suggests that markets have already built much of the expected volatility
into currency prices. It also echoes the result found by our initial
approach, that risk has been the predominant driver of the recent
depreciation of sterling.
Given this, and our assumption that the EU referendum will result
in a vote to remain in the European Union, the risk and uncertainty
associated with the vote itself should dissipate relatively rapidly
after 23 June, causing the exchange rate to appreciate sharply in the
third quarter. We therefore forecast the sterling effective exchange
rate to end this year broadly in line with where it started in 2015.
Should the referendum result not prove decisive, even if on balance
the UK ultimately decides to remain in the EU, then uncertainty around
sterling may prove more persistent than in our central forecast. Were
this to be the case then the bounce back in sterling in the third
quarter would be more muted, though it is unlikely to be a permanent
shock and in all probability would make the difference up within a short
number of quarters.
Similarly, as the referendum itself approaches, there is the
possibility that the risk associated with sterling increases, either
because markets attach a higher probability to the chance of a vote to
leave, or because they downgrade their view of the world in the case of
such a vote. Such a pattern would be consistent with what was observed
around the time of the Scottish independence referendum where markets
re-evaluated the weight they put on a independence outcome in the final
fortnight before the vote, leading to sharp movements in financial
markets. Such a move this time would lead sterling to depreciate further
between now and 23 June.
Prices and earnings
12-month consumer price inflation rose in March for the fifth
consecutive month, reaching 1 1/2 per cent compared to 0.3 per cent in
February and a 0.1 per cent contraction in October 2015. The increase
between February and March was driven in part by the earlier timing of
Easter, which acted to push up air fares significantly, but which should
be reversed by a similar offset in April.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Box A. Recent developments in exchange rates, oil prices and
monetary policy expectations
by Simon Kirby and Jack Meaning
As forecasters we aim to minimise our forecast errors. Outturns for
economic phenomena will undoubtedly differ from what we had
expected; the future, after all, is uncertain. (1) The aim of this box
is to illustrate the implications for our current forecast from
movements over the past three months in three conditioning
assumptions which are published at daily frequency: exchange rates,
oil prices; and monetary policy expectations. This exercise is
undertaken through a set of simulations using our global
econometric model, NIGEM.
The underlying oil price path, based on projections by the Energy
Information Administration of the US Department for Energy, is
significantly weaker this year than we had previously assumed. From
2018 global oil prices are assumed to grow at broadly similar
rates, consequently leading to a permanently lower path for oil
prices over the long run.
Expectations of monetary policy have softened since our last
forecast, both at home and abroad. According to market indicators
the Bank of England is not now expected to begin the tightening
phase of the monetary cycle until the first quarter of 2020 and
Bank Rate is expected to be 0.94 per cent by the end of that year,
72 basis points lower than the expectation three months ago.2 The
United States and Euro Area have both experienced a similar fall
back in expectations around their future paths for policy rates,
although in the US case these have been quantitatively smaller.
Sterling has depreciated against a basket of currencies by more
than we foresaw three months ago, due largely to increased
uncertainty, which would appear to be related to the upcoming
referendum on the UK's continued membership of the European Union.
We assume the UK remains a member of the EU. When the referendum is
over, a great deal of this uncertainty should dissipate quickly and
so the path of the sterling exchange rate in the second half of
2016 is little changed. However, the brief depreciation and
subsequent snap-back within 2016 will almost certainly have
consequences for inflation.
For the oil price, we begin from our February forecast baseline and
impose the updated oil price projection allowing the response of
the rest of the economy to be determined endogenously by the model.
Likewise in a second simulation we impose the changes in market
expectations for Bank Rate, the Fed Funds rate and the ECB's Main
Refinancing Operations (MRO) rate as exogenous shocks, and track
changes to variables in the rest of the model. For the exchange
rate impact, again we begin with the baseline forecast from
February and introduce the updated path for the exchange rate. (3)
Lastly, we look to see how all three sets of shocks interact,
applying them all simultaneously in a single simulation. The
results of all four exercises are presented in table Al.
When combined, the major developments since February have a weakly
inflationary pressure this year. However, for 2017, the effect is
disinflationary by over a 1/4 percentage point. This is predominantly
a result of the sharp appreciation in the second half of 2016 as
the exchange rate snaps back from the recent depreciation, as
uncertainty surrounding the referendum subsides. The past three
months has served to add inflationary pressure in the medium term,
largely a result of the looser expectations of monetary policy. The
outlook for GDP growth is stronger by around a quarter of a
percentage point this year, and marginally less in 2017. Recent
developments look to add around 30 basis points to the level of GDP
by the end of our forecast period.
However, these changes are not the only factors that adjust our
forecast. While we have lowered our forecast for the rate of
inflation by broadly similar magnitudes to those reported in this
box, this year and next, the same cannot be said of the change in
GDP growth, especially for this year. As we discuss in the chapter,
a marginally weaker outturn to the start of this year and amore
subdued near term weigh on the GDP growth forecast for this year.
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
Notes
(1) For many economic statistics so is the past.
(2) This is the relative change in market expectations as implied
by the Bank of England's forward OIS curve. These do not directly
relate to the central paths on our model which are based on the
author's judgement for the modal path for Bank Rate.
(3) The shock is applied to the bilateral dollar/sterling and
euro/sterling exchange rates with the short-term nominal interest
rates in the UK, US and Euro Area held fixed. Fixing the interest
rates translates the imposed exchange rate movement into a risk
premia shock for sterling and the euro against the US dollar and
thus can be interpreted as a relative risk premium shock for
sterling against both the US dollar and the euro.
Table A1. The impact of developments over the past
three months in oil prices, exchange rates and monetary
policy expectations
Individual shocks Combined
(effect on inflation (simultaneous
rate) shocks)
Oil Monetary Exchange Inflation GDP
price policy rate risk rate growth
changes changes premium
changes
2016 -0.06 0.15 0.15 0.12 0.29
2017 -0.12 0.13 -0.23 -0.28 0.17
2018 -0.09 0.24 0.04 0.15 0.07
2019 -0.06 0.33 0.06 0.31 0.04
2020 -0.04 0.34 0.06 0.38 -0.01
2021 -0.02 0.29 0.05 0.37 -0.16
Source: NiGEM simulations.
Dollar oil prices were lower in the first quarter of 2016 than we
had expected in February's Review, but look to have rebounded more
strongly in the second quarter. The net effect leaves the level broadly
consistent with our forecast from three months ago. The Energy
Information Administration projections which underpin our forecast are
substantially softer in the second half of this year than those in our
previous release, falling to $36 a barrel. This lull is never caught up
and so, despite similar growth rates over the medium term, the oil price
level has been permanently revised down. It now reaches $47 a barrel in
2017 and just $51 a barrel by the end of our forecast horizon.
Adjusting for the bilateral exchange rate accentuates the
disinflationary impact of the revision with sterling oil prices falling
by 4 percentage points more than in our February forecast in 2016 and
rising by 8 percentage points less in 2017. Should the outlook for the
sterling/dollar exchange rate prove softer than our central forecast,
for reasons discussed previously, then the changes to our oil price
projection would have a muted inflationary consequence.
Stripping out energy and other volatile components of the consumer
basket, core inflation rose to 1.5 per cent in the twelve months to
March, from 1.2 per cent in February. Sterling's recent
depreciation could be expected to exert additional inflationary pressure
over the near term. However, it is our assessment that this depreciation
has been driven largely by an increase in uncertainty associated with
the impending referendum on EU membership and as such, the exchange rate
will snap back in the second half of the year to around the level
observed at the end of 2015. This volatile 12-month period for sterling
will cause a sequence of shocks to consumer price growth, first
inflationary and then disinflationary, which will come to fruition
through 2017.
Even with a vote to remain, if the ultimate result of the
referendum is in any way indecisive then uncertainty around sterling may
prove to be more persistent than in our central case, which would weigh
down on the exchange rate and generate more inflationary pressure than
is currently projected.
In all, we expect the next 12-18 months to be a volatile period for
consumer price inflation, with a number of temporary factors filtering
through. The general trend however remains one of building price
pressures and a gradual return of inflation to the Bank of
England's target (figure 6). This gradual return to target includes
a softer near-term profile for inflation rates than were published three
months ago (figure 8). But at the two-year policy horizon inflation is
expected to be around target.
Average weekly earnings, as measured by regular pay rose at an
annual rate of 2.2 per cent in the three months to February 2016. While
this is significantly lower than the 4 per cent growth observed in the
years prior to 2008, adjusting for inflation it represents relatively
robust growth in real earnings. Real earnings growth averaged 2.3 per
cent per annum in the same pre-crisis period, and stood at 2 per cent in
February of this year. It would seem to indicate that nominal earnings
are being held down by low inflation, rather than any particularly large
degree of slack in the labour market.
Nominal earnings growth is also disparate between sectors. Public
sector earnings growth remains subdued and significantly below the whole
economy average. Conversely, the construction sector has experienced
earnings growth in excess of 7 per cent per annum, while in the
financial and business services sector it has been around 3 per cent.
This could indicate tightening becoming more acute in particular
industries.
Twelve-month unit labour cost growth, as measured by the ONS,
slowed at the end of 2015 to 1.3 per cent in the final quarter, from 1.7
per cent in the third. We expect it to remain subdued throughout 2016
and 2017 as productivity growth offsets increasing wage pressure. By
2018 though, unit labour costs should increase more robustly, adding
inflationary pressure to the economy.
Components of demand
Revisions in the March 2016 Quarterly National Accounts release by
the ONS lifted output growth for 2015 by 0.1 percentage point to 2.3 per
cent, partly related to a marginally stronger outturn for economic
growth in the final quarter of the year. In contrast, the ONS's
Preliminary Estimate of GDP for the first quarter of this year suggests
a 0.2 percentage point moderation from the last quarter of 2015 to a
growth rate of 0.4 per cent per quarter (figure 9). This may reflect
concerns over the risk of a majority vote to leave the EU in the
upcoming referendum. If this is indeed the case, then a further
softening in the rate of economic growth could occur in the second
quarter of this year as we converge on the referendum date. Indeed, we
expect economic growth to slow to 0.3 per cent per quarter in the second
quarter of this year. Given our forecast is conditioned on a vote to
remain, we expect an acceleration in economic activity in the second
half of this year, as delayed investment plans begin to be implemented.
Overall we have softened our prediction for output growth in 2016 by 0.3
percentage point to 2 per cent per annum.
Domestic demand is expected to contribute 2.5 percentage points to
overall GDP growth this year. Although we project a softening in the
rate of expansion of consumer spending, as outlined in the Household
Sector section of this chapter, it is still forecast to be the main
factor behind the expansion of domestic demand, explaining 1.8 out of
the 2.5 percentage points that domestic demand contributes to GDP.
Private consumption will be sustained by a low rate of consumer price
inflation, a consequence of external disinflationary pressures, and
positive wealth effects stemming from real house price inflation. Just
as in our Review published in February 2016, we expect net trade to be a
drag on growth, subtracting 0.7 percentage point from GDP growth this
year.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
We have incorporated the adjustment to the government revenue and
spending plans outlined in Budget 2016. We build in the announced plans
for government consumption and investment, assuming they are largely met
over the forecast period. Last November's Comprehensive Spending
Review set the government departmental spending plans for the period
through to the end of fiscal year 2019-20. Even with the re-profiling of
government investment plans within this period, there is little impact
on the overall contributions to GDP growth.
The net external sector subtracted from GDP growth by an average of
1/2 percentage point over the period 2012 to 2015. We expect net trade
to continue to weigh on growth in the first half of 2016. Growth in
export volumes accelerated to 5.1 per cent in 2015, from 1.2 per cent in
2014. This was, nevertheless, far more modest than the acceleration in
the rate of growth of import volumes, which increased from 2.4 per cent
to 6.3 per cent over the same period. This performance differential has
continued into the beginning of this year according to recent ONS trade
data. In the three months to February 2016, the volume of goods exports
declined by 1.9 per cent, due primarily to a reduction in exports to
non-EU export markets.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
The weakness in demand from the UK's major export market, the
Euro Area, has weighed on UK exports since the end of the Great
Recession (figure A3). The forecast improvement in export volumes is
dependent on the Euro Area sustaining its own economic recovery. Net
trade is expected to add 0.3 and 0.8 percentage point to GDP growth in
2017 and 2018, respectively.
Between 2013 and the end of 2015, the UK's real effective
exchange rate has appreciated by almost 15 per cent. During the first
quarter of 2016 some of this has been reversed as sterling depreciated
by 6 per cent, an effect we think has been induced by the risk of a vote
to leave the EU in the upcoming referendum. We expect this pattern to
continue over the second quarter of 2016 with a further depreciation of
4 per cent. Fundamental to our forecast is an assumption that sterling
will 'snap back' following a vote to remain and the real
effective exchange rate will recover most, but not all, of the ground
lost since the end of last year, leaving it 5 per cent below the recent
peak recorded in 2015, and 12 per cent below the pre-crisis peak.
The appreciation in the UK's real effective exchange rate,
from the middle of 2013, was accompanied by a decrease in export price
competitiveness. The magnitude of the loss in competitiveness was
smaller in relative terms than the appreciation of the real effective
exchange rate; a pass-through of less than 50 per cent, slightly less
than suggested by benchmark estimates from the IMF (2015) who find that
around 60 per cent of real effective exchange rate movements are passed
through to export prices in the first year, falling to around half in
the long run. We observe the same phenomenon when we compare the
magnitude of the depreciation of the real effective exchange rate and
the increase in export price competitiveness during the period between
2007 and 2009. One reason for this result could be that exporters took
advantage of the depreciation to build up their margins after the onset
of the Great Recession, especially given the large amount of uncertainty
that surrounded that period and that, when sterling recovered part of
the ground lost, they buffered against the potential losses in
competitiveness by narrowing their margins.
In our forecast, we assume that price competitiveness moves broadly
in line with developments in the real effective exchange rate (figure
10), however this may not necessarily be the case if exporters decide to
absorb part of the depreciation into wider profit margins just as they
did during the 2007-9 period. This poses a downside risk to our forecast
for UK export volume growth over the next few years.
Household sector
Real personal disposable income (disposable income henceforth) grew
by 3.3 per cent in 2015, fuelled by a low rate of consumer price
inflation derived from the fall in energy prices, the lagged effect from
an appreciation in sterling, and a rise in income due to strong
employment growth. We expect real disposable income growth to ease to
2.2 per cent per annum in 2016. The long-term evolution of disposable
income depends crucially on the return of meaningful productivity growth
which has failed to materialise so far and which we expect to return in
2017. Our forecast is that disposable income growth will trough in 2017
as consumer price inflation returns gradually to the Bank's target
of 2 per cent and recover from then onwards as real wages pick up
following the path of productivity. Together with population
projections, our forecast implies an average real per capita income
growth of close to 2 per cent between 2017 and 2021.
According to our preferred measure of house prices, the seasonally
adjusted mix-adjusted house price index published by the ONS, house
prices have increased by an annual rate of 7.4 per cent in the three
months to February 2016 compared to 6.9 and 5.5 per cent in the three
months to November and August 2015. The Halifax and Nationwide index,
which act as leading indicators for the ONS measure as they are derived
earlier in the house purchase process, portray a very similar picture of
accelerating inflation in the near term: house price inflation in the
first quarter of 2016 compared to the same quarter one year earlier was
10.1 per cent according to Halifax, compared to 9.7 and 8.7 per cent in
the fourth and third quarter of 2015. Nationwide reports an annual rate
of growth of 5 per cent in the first quarter of this year compared to 4
and 3.5 pe r cent in the preceding quarters.
Such acceleration in house price inflation was expected as
second-home buyers and those buying to let brought their house purchase
plans forward in response to the April 2016 increase in the Stamp Duty
tax rate for buy-to-let and second homes property announced in
November's 2015 Autumn Statement. The surge in demand has been
remarkable as it can be seen in data on the volume of residential
property transactions from HMRC: residential property transactions
increased from around 110 thousand in January this year, to 117 and 165
thousand in February and March, respectively (figure 11). The March
figure is the highest in the data reported, on a consistent basis, by
HMRC since 2005. The historical series on property transactions contains
only two similar, albeit smaller, spikes: the first one in December 2009
associated with a temporary increase in the lower threshold of the Stamp
Duty Land Tax and another peak in March and April 2012 that coincided
with the ending of the first time buyer's Stamp Duty tax relief. In
both cases, following the policy-induced rise in transactions, a period
of depressed activity followed. We do not expect the effect of this
policy change to be any different: Royal Institute of Chartered
Surveyors' (RICS) data on buyers' enquiries have already
displayed a steep decline in March 2016 compared to the previous month
(figure 12). Given the lag in the process of purchasing a house, a drop
off in buyer enquiries would be expected prior to the tax change coming
into effect. Data on mortgage approvals for house purchasing from the
March 2016 Bank of England Money and Credit report display only a
gradual increase of approvals since November 2015, a piece of data that
seems at odds with the data from HMRC on property transactions. However,
both pieces of evidence can be reconciled by looking at the value of
loans secured on property which have increased by 4 billion [pounds
sterling] in just one single month to March 2016 (figure 13).
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
We expect the rate of house price inflation to peak in 2016. While
income growth should provide a support to house price inflation,
affordability remains an acute constraint on the inflow of first-time
buyers. The recent tightening of lending standards by the Financial
Policy Committee (Bank of England, 2016), together with the start of
gradual increases in Bank Rate and the pass through to mortgage rates,
should weigh on future demand for housing. Overall, we expect house
price inflation to moderate over the forecast horizon.
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
Household consumption was the main driver of economic growth in
2015, contributing 1.8 out of 2.3 percentage points to output growth.
Expenditure has been sustained on the back of strong income growth,
wealth effects of house price inflation (4) and the appreciation of
sterling and falling energy prices which increased the purchasing power
of households.
We estimate that robust consumer spending growth continued into the
first quarter of this year. Data on retail sales until March 2016, which
constitute a timely indicator of consumer spending and represent around
a third of the total, increased by 0.8 per cent during the first quarter
of this year, a slight decline compared to an average rate of growth of
1.1 per cent in 2015. We have revised our projection of consumer
spending growth for this year to 2.8 per cent, down from 3.6 per cent in
our previous Review. This revision incorporates the effects driven by
heightened uncertainty of the referendum. We expect further moderations
in the growth rate of private expenditure between 2017 and 2021 as house
price inflation moderates, consumer price inflation returns to the 2 per
cent target of the Bank of England and income gearing--the share of
income devoted to interest rate payments--increases following the likely
increase in Bank Rate.
Following a period of deleveraging from a peak of almost 170 per
cent, the household debt-to-income ratio has remained stable at around
141 per cent since 2013. We expect the ratio to increase by 2 percentage
points by 2017, driven by a strong expansion of consumer credit that
feeds the strong performance of private consumption together with the
recent pick-up in the value of loans secured on property, and to
decrease from then onwards as nominal income growth picks up.
The saving ratio, which includes the adjustment for changes in net
equity of households in pension funds, has reached a new historical low
of 3.8 per cent in the fourth quarter of 2015. The dip has been almost
entirely driven by an increase in consumption expenditure which has made
a dent in the overall savings of households. The favourable dynamics of
employment growth and the gains in purchasing power from external
developments have spurred consumption plans of consumers that might
otherwise have been delayed. This raises the question of whether
consumers have based these decisions on real interest rates remaining
low for an extended period of time. A sharper rise in the real rate of
interest may lead to a re-evaluation of expectations by consumers, and
poses a downside risk to our growth forecast. Looking ahead we expect
the saving ratio to trough in 2016 and to recover from 2017 onwards as
the average propensity to consume moderates as households use more of
the future gains in real consumer wages to improve their balance sheets.
The degree of trade-off between current and future consumption will
crucially depend on the outlook for the real rate of interest and
productivity performance of the economy.
Supply conditions
The 2016 Budget included a further cut in the main rate of
corporation tax to 17 per cent to come into effect in 2020. This follows
a cut from 28 per cent to 20 per cent in 2010 and is intended to support
business investment in the UK. Although business investment as a share
of GDP has been following an upward trend since the middle of 2010, it
remains low relative to other developed economies and is below the level
in all the G7 economies apart from Canada (figure 14). The Bank of
England's Credit Conditions Survey for the first quarter of 2016
reports that the supply of credit to businesses of all sizes has
remained unchanged for the second quarter in a row. Demand for credit
from small and medium businesses is reported to have fallen, while
demand from large businesses was unchanged but is expected to increase
in the second quarter of this year. Spreads on lending to large
companies have been narrowing since the end of 2012 but were unchanged
in the first quarter of this year and are expected to remain so in the
second quarter. Spreads remained broadly unchanged for small and medium
sized businesses but associated fees and commissions fell.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
As noted above, uncertainty is likely to weigh heavily on
investment between now and the June referendum, and for the following
two years or so of the negotiation period in the event of a vote for
leaving the EU. Our central forecast assumes the UK remains a member of
the EU, but uncertainty surrounding the referendum still features. We
have constructed an uncertainty index based on various measures of
uncertainty and volatility (see Baker et al. in this Review). This index
shows a sharp increase in uncertainty, of 0.65 standard deviations, in
the first quarter of 2016. Uncertainty as measured by this index was
about half the magnitude of the peak associated with the sovereign debt
crisis and a sixth the 2008 peak during the global financial crisis. Our
forecast for business investment has been revised downwards to account
for an increasingly uncertain economic environment. We now expect
business investment to grow by 3.2 per cent this year and 5.9 per cent
next year before starting to slow, down from our previous forecast of
6.1 and 5.5 per cent for this year and next respectively.
The National Living Wage (NLW) came into force in April this year.
It applies to workers aged 25 and over and is currently 24 per cent
above the National Minimum Wage (average of London and rest of UK). The
CPID and Resolution Foundation (2016) conducted a representative survey
of 1,037 employers to gauge likely responses to the policy change. Their
findings suggest that a significant share of firms will be unaffected or
will face only a small increase in their wage bill and that job losses
are unlikely, at least in the short term. Hospitality, retail and other
low-paid sectors will be disproportionately affected. Of the employers
surveyed, 54 per cent expected to be affected by the NLW, but only 18
per cent to 'a large extent'. Those that expected to be
affected were asked to identify up to three responses from a list that
they were most likely to implement. The most popular responses were
'improve efficiency/raise productivity' and 'take lower
profits/absorb costs' which were identified by 30 and 22 per cent
of employers respectively. Reducing the number of employees and reducing
hours worked by staff were identified by 15 and 9 per cent of employers
respectively.
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
Productivity growth, in terms of output per hour worked, gained
momentum throughout most of 2015 before being almost entirely reversed
in the final quarter (figure 15), falling by 1.2 per cent compared to
the third quarter. Even in the service sector, which has seen the most
robust recovery in productivity since the crisis, output per hour fell
by 0.7 per cent. Conversely, output per worker and output per job have
stayed approximately constant in the fourth quarter, following three
quarters of growth. This seems to be driven, at least in part, by a
sudden increase in average hours worked of just over 1 per cent in the
three months to December 2015 (figure 16). Data from the three months to
February show that average weekly hours and total hours worked have both
declined. Weekly hours worked per employee were on a downward trend for
most of 2015 and we expect this trend to persist.
Following the drop in hourly productivity, we have revised down our
hourly productivity growth forecast for 2016 from 1.2 to 0.7 per cent,
and slightly reduced our forecast over the following four years. The
rate of transition from unemployment to employment reached its highest
level since 2007 at 29.8 per cent in the three months to December 2015.
Worryingly, the rate of transition from unemployment to inactivity has
also been increasing, reaching 19.2 per cent in the same period,
compared to an average of 17.7 per cent since 1997. The ratio of
vacancies to unemployment has been increasing rapidly since the start of
2014, but the rate of increase slowed towards the end of 2015 and the
number of vacancies per unemployed person fell in the three months to
February 2016. We expect the unemployment rate to fall to 5.2 per cent
this year and next before starting to decline.
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
Self-employment as a proportion of total employment, which tends to
move counter cyclically, has been fairly constant over the past two
years but increased slightly in the three months to February to 14.8 per
cent, compared to an average of 13.7 per cent over the past ten years.
Temporary employment as a proportion of total employment has been on a
downward trend throughout 2015, but has increased slightly in recent
months. The number of temporary workers who wanted but were unable to
find permanent employment has been declining and dropped to 33.0 per
cent in the three months to February from 35.2 per cent in the previous
three month period. Similarly, part-time employment as a proportion of
total employment has stayed at around 26 per cent since 2009, but
workers who work part- time because they cannot find full-time
employment has been declining since mid-2013. This implies a tightening
in the labour market which might not be reflected in unemployment data
as underemployment is reduced.
Public finances
The first outturn for fiscal year 2015-16 suggests only a gradual
reduction in the magnitude of public sector net borrowing. ONS public
finance data, which differs from the national accounts data we publish
in table A8, suggest borrowing fell from 91.7 billion [pounds sterling]
(5 per cent of GDP) in 2014-15 to 74 billion [pounds sterling] (4.1 per
cent of GDP) in 2015- 16. These figures are broadly in line with what we
had expected just three months ago. The government's primary target
is for the public sector to become a net lender to the rest of the
economy in 2019-20. This leaves less than four fiscal years to lower
borrowing by 4 per cent of GDP.
In the absence of any discretionary policy changes, our forecast
would suggest public sector net borrowing of around 10 billion [pounds
sterling] (1/2 per cent of GDP) in 2019-20. The government has used a
reprofiling of a corporation tax policy change and capital expenditures
over the period 2016- 17 to 2019-20 to ensure an absolute surplus is
achieved in 2019-20.
The secondary target, the Fiscal Mandate, is for public sector net
debt, as a per cent of GDP, to be lower in each and every year from
2015-16. According to current official estimates, this target has been
breached, by just 0.2 per cent of GDP. This is due to delays in assets
sales, namely the government's holdings of bank equities, because
of adverse market conditions.
Debt dynamics dictate that debt, as a share of income, will be on a
downward trajectory if borrowing relative to income is smaller than the
rate of growth of nominal income. However, in fiscal year 2016-17 we do
expect nominal GDP to report a growth figure smaller than borrowing, or
more precisely, the public sector's net cash requirement, as a
share of GDP. As a consequence, we expect public sector net debt, as a
per cent of GDP, to have increased by the end of 2016-17. Further out,
continued fiscal consolidation and a rebound in nominal GDP growth are
expected to enable public sector net debt, as a per cent of GDP, to
fall. As stated, given the additional policy changes announced in Budget
2016 and our outlook for the UK economy, we expect a fiscal surplus to
be achieved in 2019-20. Upon reaching this year, we expect public sector
net debt, as a per cent of GDP, to fall rather sharply, since running a
surplus means a reduction in the nominal amount of debt, not just the
relative magnitude of debt; falling to 79.1 per cent of GDP in 2019-20
and 76.6 per cent by 2020-21.
Saving and investment
The balance of payments on the current account is the net position
of saving and investment in the economy. Table A9 disaggregates this
into the household, corporate and government sectors. For each sector,
if investment exceeds saving, then that sector is a net borrower and
requires external finance from the rest of the economy. If in aggregate
investment is greater than saving, then finance from abroad is needed to
fund investment. The current account balance provides information on the
immediate funding needs of the economy and does not imply anything about
the optimality of levels of saving or investment.
Household saving rose sharply following the onset of the crisis to
peak at 8.8 per cent of GDP in the third quarter of 2010. Since then it
has declined and in the last quarter of 2015 reached 2.6 per cent of
GDP, the lowest level on record. (5) Real consumer wages fell by 1.8 per
cent in the final quarter of 2015 and accordingly we have lowered our
expectations for the level of real consumer wages in the near term. This
feeds into our forecast for household saving ratio, which we have
revised downwards by 0.1 to 0.2 percentage point in each year from 2016
until 2020. Saving, as a share of GDP, is projected to continue to fall
further in 2016. We expect this to be the trough for household saving.
The desire to improve household balance sheets should result in the
saving ratio rising over our forecast period. Investment by households
has increased only modestly over the past few years; rising from 4.3 per
cent of GDP in 2010 to 5.3 per cent in 2015, below the 6 per cent plus
levels seen pre-crisis. Housing investment is expected to outpace GDP
growth through to the end of our forecast horizon, resulting in
investment figures of around 6 per cent of GDP. However, these figures
are in nominal terms and are a reflection of rapid house price increases
in recent years rather than a robust increase in the volume of activity
in the housing market. With nominal housing investment expected to
outstrip saving, households will remain net borrowers from the rest of
the economy throughout our forecast period. However, the gap between
saving and investment is expected to narrow from 3.6 per cent of GDP in
2016 to under 2 per cent in 2020. Growth in gross disposable incomes of
the household sector ensures that this continued borrowing keeps the
household debt to income ratio stable over our forecast horizon.
Investment by companies fell markedly at the start of the crisis
and has been gradually increasing since late 2009. The corporate sector
has been a net lender to the rest of the economy since 2003 but we
expect this position to reverse this year and for the external funding
required to increase throughout our forecast period as investment
increases and savings continue to fall.
The government has been a net borrower since 2002 but the gap
between saving and investment increased substantially during the crisis
to reach a peak of 9.0 per cent of GDP in 2009. This was due to a large
drop in savings during 2008 and 2009 while government investment as a
share of GDP rose slightly. The amount of external finance required has
been declining as a share of GDP but remains substantial at 3.9 per cent
in 2015. Our projections for government consumption and investment are
based on the spending plans and policy changes detailed in the 2016
Budget. The government has announced discretionary policy changes that
tighten fiscal policy in order to re-establish a surplus by fiscal year
2019-20. However, our forecast for nominal GDP growth has been revised
downwards over the period 2016-20. Tax revenues depend on the magnitude
and composition of nominal demand within the economy. (6) With little
change to general government consumption plans since the November 2015
Comprehensive Spending Review, the outcome should be to lower the
expected path for government saving over our forecast horizon. However,
discretionary policy changes mean that government saving is expected to
be higher at the end of our forecast horizon.
The current account balance has deteriorated, in an almost
consistent fashion since 2011. This deficit reached a record 5.2 per
cent of GDP in 2015 as a whole. Unlike previous episodes of high current
account deficits, the trade balance has remained relatively stable. The
primary factor in the recent deterioration is a drop in net FDI
investment income which fell from a surplus of 3.3 per cent of GDP in
2011 to a deficit of 0.2 per cent in 2015. This has been driven in part
by exchange rate movements, and also by stronger growth in the UK than
in major partner countries, contributing to higher returns on foreign
investment in the UK than on UK investments abroad. Weaker commodity
prices may also have contributed to reduced income from FDI. Since
liabilities are more likely to be held in domestic currency than assets,
the recent depreciation of sterling has resulted in an increase in the
net asset position at the same time as current balances as a proportion
of GDP have fallen. We are forecasting the current account deficit to be
6.5 per cent of GDP in 2016 and 6.6 per cent in 2017 before narrowing
over our forecast period. Net assets are expected to be 1.0 per cent of
GDP in 2016, falling to -9.4 per cent in 2017 and continuing to fall,
averaging -23 per cent of GDP in 2018-20.
The implications of the recent deterioration of the current account
depend on how long we expect this phenomenon to last. Lane (2015)
suggests that this might be a transitory effect as a result of financial
engineering, whereby UK firms have been relocating their headquarters
abroad, perhaps to take advantage of lower taxes or a looser regulatory
environment, while economic activity continues to take place
domestically. The view of the IMF (2016) on the other hand, as outlined
in their recent Article IV report on the UK, is that while returns on
foreign assets are likely to recover, the shift in the net stock of FDI
is likely to have been driven by more permanent shifts such as the
reduction in UK corporate tax rates, making the UK a more attractive
place to invest thus increasing income flows from non- residents'
investment in the UK relative to income flows from UK residents'
investment abroad.
Medium-term projections
Following the Great Recession, the recovery of the UK economy has
been protracted, with economic growth below estimates of its potential
rate for a number of years. Our projections for the medium term, which
are dominated by the gradual process of returning to equilibrium, are
presented in table A10. These figures reflect our baseline forecast and
we understand that shocks, which are by definition unpredictable, will
undoubtedly move the economy away from this path. We represent this
uncertainty using fan charts (figures 3, 4 and 6).
One near-term risk with long-run implications that can easily be
identified is the event of a vote to leave the EU in the 23 June
referendum. What is more uncertain is the magnitude of the impact on the
UK, not least because we do not know which of the exit states will be
the path the UK economy eventually travels. Ebell and Warren, in this
Review, present a range of scenarios to illustrate the medium to
long-term economic effects of this shock materialising. The estimated
negative impacts on GDP of between 1.5 and 3.7 per cent are somewhat
smaller than those of other recent studies that they compare their
results to.
Since our February forecast we have changed our expectation of when
Bank Rate will first increase from August to November 2016, but also
predict a more rapid tightening in rates so that our medium term view
remains largely unchanged. We expect interest rates to normalise over
the forecast period and to be 3 1/2 per cent in 2021-25.
Critical to our forecast is the assumption of the return of
meaningful productivity growth, which is the key driver of long-run
growth in real consumer wages and improvements in the economic welfare
of the population. Following poor data outturns at the end of 2015, we
have revised down our expectation of whole economy per hour productivity
from 1.2 to 0.7 per cent in 2016. Our forecast is for productivity
growth to regain momentum over the following four years and we expect
robust growth of around 1.8 per cent per year in 2021-25.
Labour input has increased rapidly over the past few years due to
increases in both employment and hours worked. The rate of increase
slowed in 2015 and we expect this slowdown to persist as unemployment
nears its long-run level of 5-5 1/2 per cent and the population growth
rate declines, in part due to current government policy of targeting a
reduction in net immigration. This is likely to be offset somewhat by an
increase in the participation rate of those aged 65 and over as the
state pension ages for men and women are equalised, but this effect will
level off once the process of equalisation has finished in 2021. We
expect unemployment to remain at 5.2 per cent in 2016 but to overshoot
slightly, dipping below its long-run level as the economy rebounds
rapidly, before settling at around 5 per cent.
Recent weakness in commodity prices means that consumer price
growth is expected to be subdued, with annual inflation rates of 0.3 and
0.9 per cent in 2016 and 2017 respectively. Our forecast is for
inflation to pick up as these effects dissipate, overshooting the Bank
of England's 2 per cent target in 2019 before settling at 2.1 per
cent on average in 2021-5.
Our projections for monetary policy globally inform our forecast
for interest rate differentials which determine exchange rates in our
forecast. Following the recent depreciation of sterling, our expectation
of the level of the effective exchange rate in 2016 has been lowered by
around 3 per cent, compared to our forecast published three months ago.
We expect the effective exchange rate to remain broadly flat from 2017
until the end of our forecast period.
NOTES
(1) We make abundant use of the words risk and uncertainty.
Commonly, both terms are used interchangeably but they probably carry
different shades of meaning to each reader. For example, Knight (1921)
defined risk as an event in which the probability distribution of the
outcome is known and uncertainty to the case where that is unknown.
(2) This is the same model we use to produce the modal forecast
presented in this and the world chapter of this Review.
(3) Within the European Economic Area (EEA) a financial firm who is
authorised in one EEA state is entitled to exercise the right of
establishment (of a branch and/or agents) or via cross- border services
to provide permitted services in any other EEA member state (see
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/pra/Pages/
authorisations/passporting/default.aspx for more details).
(4) Household wealth has been buoyed by rapidly rising house
prices. At the end of 2015, household wealth had risen to the equivalent
of 7 1/2 years of incomes, from 6'A years of income at the end of
2013.
(5) Saving ratio data is available from 1964.
(6) As well as its cyclical position.
REFERENCES
Bank of England (2016),'Underwriting standards for buy-to-let
mortgage contracts', Consultation Paper, CP11/16.
CIPD and Resolution Foundation (2016),'Weighing up the wage
floor: employer responses to the National Living Wage', available
at: http://www.resolutionfoundation.org/wp-content/
uploads/2016/02/CIPD-NLW-report.pdf.
International Monetary Fund (2015), World Economic Outlook,
October.
--(2016),'United Kingdom Selected Issues', IMF Country
Report No. 16/58 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2016/cr
1658.pdf.
Kirby, S. and Meaning, J. (2014),'Exchange rate pass-through:
a view from a global structural model', National Institute Economic
Review, 230, pp. F59-64.
Knight, F. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, University of
Chicago Press.
Lane, P. (2015),'A financial perspective on the UK current
account deficit', National Institute Economic Review, 234,
November, F67-71.
Monetary Policy Committee (2016), Monetary Policy Summary, 1 April.
Appendix--Forecast details
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A10 OMITTED]
Table A1. Exchange rates and interest rates
UK exchange rates FTSE
All-share
Effective Dollar Euro index
2011 = 100
2010 100.19 1.55 1.17 2472.7
2011 100.00 1.60 1.15 2587.6
2012 104.17 1.59 1.23 2617.7
2013 102.91 1.56 1.18 3006.2
2014 110.94 1.65 1.24 3136.6
2015 118.25 1.53 1.38 3150.1
2016 112.93 1.45 1.29 2874.7
2017 114.00 1.48 1.29 2816.8
2018 113.76 1.49 1.28 2855.0
2019 113.56 1.51 1.26 2936.0
2020 113.34 1.52 1.25 3066.5
2015 Q1 115.02 1.51 1.34 3207.6
2015 Q2 117.69 1.53 1.39 3294.6
2015 Q3 120.39 1.55 1.39 3075.5
2015 Q4 119.89 1.52 1.39 3022.6
2016 Q1 113.54 1.43 1.30 2891.8
2016 Q2 110.01 1.43 1.25 2959.0
2016 Q3 114.09 1.48 1.30 2826.5
2016 Q4 114.08 1.48 1.30 2821.4
2017 Q1 114.05 1.48 1.30 2813.7
2017 Q2 114.03 1.48 1.29 2817.0
2017 Q3 113.99 1.48 1.29 2816.2
2017 Q4 113.93 1.48 1.29 2820.3
Percentage changes
2010/2009 -0.4 -1.2 3.8 21.2
2011/2010 -0.2 3.7 -1.2 4.6
2012/2011 4.2 -1.1 7.0 1.2
2013/2012 -1.2 -1.3 -4.5 14.8
2014/2013 7.8 5.3 5.4 4.3
2015/2014 6.6 -7.2 11.1 0.4
2016/2015 -4.5 -4.8 -6.6 -8.7
2017/2016 0.9 1.9 0.5 -2.0
2018/2017 -0.2 0.7 -1.2 1.4
2019/2018 -0.2 1.0 -1.3 2.8
2020/2019 -0.2 0.8 -1.3 4.4
2015Q4/14Q4 7.2 -4.2 9.4 -1.4
2016Q4/15Q4 -4.8 -2.5 -6.2 -6.7
2017Q4/16Q4 -0.1 0.3 -0.9 0.0
Interest rates
3-month Mortgage 10-year World (a) Bank
rates interest gilts Rate (b)
2010 0.7 4.0 3.6 1.4 0.50
2011 0.9 4.1 3.1 1.6 0.50
2012 0.8 4.2 1.8 1.4 0.50
2013 0.5 4.4 2.4 1.1 0.50
2014 0.5 4.4 2.5 0.9 0.50
2015 0.6 4.5 1.8 0.7 0.50
2016 0.6 4.6 1.6 0.8 0.75
2017 1.2 4.7 2.3 1.2 1.50
2018 1.9 5.0 2.8 1.8 1.75
2019 2.3 5.2 3.3 2.3 2.25
2020 2.7 5.5 3.6 2.6 2.75
2015 Q1 0.6 4.5 1.6 0.7 0.50
2015 Q2 0.6 4.5 1.9 0.7 0.50
2015 Q3 0.6 4.5 1.9 0.7 0.50
2015 Q4 0.6 4.5 1.9 0.7 0.50
2016 Q1 0.6 4.6 1.5 0.8 0.50
2016 Q2 0.6 4.6 1.4 0.8 0.50
2016 Q3 0.6 4.5 1.6 0.8 0.50
2016 Q4 0.8 4.6 1.8 0.9 0.75
2017 Q1 0.9 4.6 2.0 1.0 0.75
2017 Q2 1.1 4.7 2.2 1.1 1.00
2017 Q3 1.3 4.8 2.4 1.3 1.25
2017 Q4 1.5 4.9 2.5 1.4 1.50
Percentage changes
2010/2009
2011/2010
2012/2011
2013/2012
2014/2013
2015/2014
2016/2015
2017/2016
2018/2017
2019/2018
2020/2019
2015Q4/14Q4
2016Q4/15Q4
2017Q4/16Q4
Notes: We assume that bilateral exchange rates for the first quarter
of this year are the average of information available to 13 April
2016. We then assume that bilateral rates remain constant for the
following two quarters before moving in line with the path implied by
the backward-looking uncovered interest rate parity condition based
on interest rate differentials relative to the US. The exception is
the UK, where we assume a vote to remain a member of the EU induces
an unwinding of relative risk premia and an appreciation of sterling
in the third quarter of this year. We then assume sterling remains
constant in the final quarter of this year, (a) Weighted average of
central bank intervention rates in OECD economies, (b) End of period.
Table A2. Price indices
2012=100
Unit Imports Exports Whole- World
labour deflator deflator sale price oil price
costs index (a) ($) (b)
2010 99.4 94.1 94.4 96.2 78.8
2011 98.9 100.5 99.8 98.9 108.5
2012 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 110.4
2013 100.6 100.9 102.6 100.8 107.1
2014 99.5 97.2 100.0 101.7 97.8
2015 100.8 91.5 94.8 101.9 51.8
2016 101.1 91.3 93.6 102.1 35.1
2017 101.4 94.8 94.2 102.6 41.6
2018 102.8 97.6 97.1 104.3 48.1
2019 104.9 99.7 99.7 106.8 49.0
2020 106.7 101.8 102.1 109.4 50.0
Percentage changes
2010/2009 1.5 3.9 5.4 1.5 27.6
2011/2010 -0.5 6.8 5.7 2.8 37.6
2012/2011 1.1 -0.5 0.2 1.1 1.8
2013/2012 0.6 0.9 2.6 0.8 -3.0
2014/2013 -1.0 -3.6 -2.6 0.9 -8.7
2015/2014 1.3 -5.9 -5.2 0.2 -47.0
2016/2015 0.4 -0.2 -1.3 0.2 -32.2
2017/2016 0.2 3.8 0.7 0.5 18.6
2018/2017 1.4 2.9 3.1 1.7 15.4
2019/2018 2.1 2.2 2.6 2.4 2.0
2020/2019 1.7 2.1 2.4 2.3 2.0
2015Q4/14Q4 1.1 -5.5 -5.4 0.1 -43.8
2016Q4/15Q4 -0.1 2.5 -0.4 0.5 -15.8
2017Q4/16Q4 0.6 3.2 3.2 0.8 33.2
Retail price
index
GDP
Consumption deflator All Excluding Consumer
deflator (market items mortgage prices
prices) interest index
2010 94.7 96.4 92.1 92.0 93.1
2011 98.2 98.4 96.9 96.9 97.2
2012 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
2013 102.3 102.0 103.0 103.1 102.6
2014 104.0 103.9 105.5 105.6 104.0
2015 104.2 104.1 106.5 106.7 104.1
2016 104.4 103.7 107.9 108.1 104.4
2017 105.4 103.6 110.9 109.9 105.3
2018 107.4 105.6 114.9 112.7 107.3
2019 109.9 108.2 118.8 116.0 109.7
2020 112.2 110.6 123.0 119.1 112.0
Percentage changes
2010/2009 4.6 3.1 4.6 4.8 3.3
2011/2010 3.7 2.1 5.2 5.3 4.5
2012/2011 1.8 1.6 3.2 3.2 2.9
2013/2012 2.3 2.0 3.0 3.1 2.6
2014/2013 1.7 1.8 2.4 2.4 1.4
2015/2014 0.2 0.3 1.0 1.0 0.1
2016/2015 0.3 -0.4 1.3 1.4 0.3
2017/2016 0.9 -0.1 2.8 1.7 0.9
2018/2017 1.9 2.0 3.6 2.6 1.9
2019/2018 2.3 2.4 3.3 2.9 2.3
2020/2019 2.1 2.2 3.6 2.7 2.1
2015Q4/14Q4 0.4 0.1 1.0 1.1 0.1
2016Q4/15Q4 -0.4 -1.0 1.6 1.3 0.3
2017Q4/16Q4 1.3 1.2 3.5 2.0 1.3
Notes: (a) Excluding food, beverages, tobacco and petroleum products,
(b) Per barrel, average of Dubai and Brent spot prices.
Table A3. Gross domestic product and components of expenditure
[pounds sterling] billion, 2012 prices
Final consumption Gross capital
expenditure formation
Households General Gross Changes in
& NPISH (a) govt. fixed inventories (b)
investment
2010 1062.3 339.4 259.2 4.8
2011 1063.3 339.7 264.3 -5.6
2012 1082.6 346.0 268.2 2.4
2013 1103.0 347.6 275.1 18.1
2014 1130.3 356.2 295.1 17.7
2015 1161.0 361.4 307.2 16.7
2016 1193.1 362.9 318.1 17.3
2017 1218.8 365.2 335.6 14.7
2018 1237.9 367.0 347.1 14.3
2019 1258.6 367.8 355.0 14.3
2020 1284.3 370.4 362.9 14.3
Percentage changes
2010/2009 0.0 0.2 5.0
2011/2010 0.1 0.1 2.0
2012/2011 1.8 1.8 1.5
2013/2012 1.9 0.5 2.6
2014/2013 2.5 2.5 7.3
2015/2014 2.7 1.5 4.1
2016/2015 2.8 0.4 3.6
2017/2016 2.2 0.6 5.5
2018/2017 1.6 0.5 3.4
2019/2018 1.7 0.2 2.3
2020/2019 2.0 0.7 2.2
Decomposition of growth in GDP (d)
2010 0.0 0.0 0.8 1.4
2011 0.1 0.0 0.3 -0.6
2012 1.2 0.4 0.2 0.5
2013 1.2 0.1 0.4 0.9
2014 1.6 0.5 1.2 0.0
2015 1.8 0.3 0.7 -0.1
2016 1.8 0.1 0.6 0.0
2017 1.4 0.1 1.0 -0.1
2018 1.0 0.1 0.6 0.0
2019 1.1 0.0 0.4 0.0
2020 1.3 0.1 0.4 0.0
Domestic Total Total Total Net GDP
demand exports final imports trade at
(c) expenditure (c) market
prices
2010 1660.3 470.5 2131.2 517.5 -47.0 1614.0
2011 1668.0 498.0 2166.0 520.4 -22.4 1645.8
2012 1699.1 501.7 2200.8 535.6 -33.9 1665.2
2013 1743.8 507.8 2251.6 550.4 -42.6 1701.2
2014 1799.3 513.8 2313.1 563.6 -49.9 1749.7
2015 1846.3 539.8 2386.1 599.2 -59.4 1790.5
2016 1891.4 555.0 2446.4 627.7 -72.7 1826.2
2017 1934.2 597.0 2531.2 663.5 -66.5 1875.3
2018 1966.3 627.6 2593.9 678.4 -50.8 1923.0
2019 1995.6 653.9 2649.5 691.1 -37.2 1965.9
2020 2031.8 678.4 2710.2 708.9 -30.5 2008.9
Percentage changes
2010/2009 2.3 5.8 3.1 8.3 1.5
2011/2010 0.5 5.8 1.6 0.6 2.0
2012/2011 1.9 0.7 1.6 2.9 1.2
2013/2012 2.6 1.2 2.3 2.8 2.2
2014/2013 3.2 1.2 2.7 2.4 2.9
2015/2014 2.6 5.1 3.2 6.3 2.3
2016/2015 2.4 2.8 2.5 4.8 2.0
2017/2016 2.3 7.6 3.5 5.7 2.7
2018/2017 1.7 5.1 2.5 2.3 2.5
2019/2018 1.5 4.2 2.1 1.9 2.2
2020/2019 1.8 3.8 2.3 2.6 2.2
Decomposition of growth in GDP (d)
2010 2.4 1.6 4.0 -2.5 -0.9 1.5
2011 0.5 1.7 2.2 -0.2 1.5 2.0
2012 1.9 0.2 2.1 -0.9 -0.7 1.2
2013 2.7 0.4 3.1 -0.9 -0.5 2.2
2014 3.3 0.3 3.6 -0.8 -0.4 2.9
2015 2.7 1.5 4.2 -2.0 -0.5 2.3
2016 2.5 0.8 3.4 -1.6 -0.7 2.0
2017 2.3 2.3 4.6 -2.0 0.3 2.7
2018 1.7 1.6 3.3 -0.8 0.8 2.5
2019 1.5 1.4 2.9 -0.7 0.7 2.2
2020 1.8 1.2 3.1 -0.9 0.3 2.2
Notes: (a) Non-profit institutions serving households, (b) Including
acquisitions less disposals of valuables and quarterly alignment
adjustment. (c) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (d)
Components may not add up to total GDP growth due to rounding and the
statistical discrepancy included in GDP.
Table A4. External sector
Exports Imports Net Exports Imports Net
of of trade in of of trade in
goods goods goods services services services
(a) (a) (a)
[pounds sterling] billion, 2012 prices (b)
2010 287.4 396.5 -109.1 183.0 120.9 62.1
2011 306.8 401.1 -94.3 191.1 119.3 71.9
2012 304.3 410.8 -106.5 197.4 124.8 72.6
2013 302.5 420.6 -118.1 205.3 129.9 75.4
2014 302.6 434.9 -132.3 211.1 128.7 82.5
2015 322.4 461.4 -139.0 217.3 137.8 79.6
2016 332.4 485.3 -152.9 222.6 142.3 80.2
2017 362.5 515.5 -153.0 234.5 148.0 86.5
2018 381.1 527.0 -145.9 246.5 151.4 95.1
2019 396.5 536.4 -139.9 257.4 154.7 102.7
2020 411.1 550.2 -139.1 267.3 158.7 108.6
Percentage changes
2010/2009 11.3 11.6 -1.7 -0.7
2011/2010 6.8 1.2 4.4 -1.3
2012/2011 -0.8 2.4 3.3 4.6
2013/2012 -0.6 2.4 4.0 4.0
2014/2013 0.0 3.4 2.8 -0.9
2015/2014 6.6 6.1 2.9 7.1
2016/2015 3.1 5.2 2.4 3.3
2017/2016 9.0 6.2 5.3 4.0
2018/2017 5.1 2.2 5.1 2.3
2019/2018 4.0 1.8 4.4 2.2
2020/2019 3.7 2.6 3.8 2.6
Export World Terms Current
price trade (d) of trade (e) balance
competitiveness (c)
2012=100 % of GDP
2010 94.1 92.6 100.3 -2.8
2011 98.1 98.1 99.3 -1.7
2012 100.0 100.0 100.0 -3.3
2013 100.4 102.5 101.7 -4.5
2014 104.1 106.7 102.8 -5.1
2015 103.2 110.9 103.6 -5.2
2016 96.9 116.5 102.5 -6.5
2017 95.7 123.0 99.4 -6.6
2018 96.1 128.1 99.5 -5.5
2019 96.4 133.2 100.0 -4.5
2020 96.2 138.3 100.2 -3.9
Percentage changes
2010/2009 2.2 10.1 1.4
2011/2010 4.2 5.9 -1.0
2012/2011 2.0 1.9 0.7
2013/2012 0.4 2.5 1.7
2014/2013 3.6 4.1 1.1
2015/2014 -0.8 3.9 0.7
2016/2015 -6.2 5.0 -1.1
2017/2016 -1.2 5.5 -3.0
2018/2017 0.4 4.2 0.2
2019/2018 0.3 4.0 0.4
2020/2019 -0.2 3.8 0.3
Notes: (a) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (b) Balance
of payments basis, (c) A rise denotes a loss in UK competitiveness.
(d) Weighted by import shares in UK export markets, (e) Ratio of
average value of exports to imports.
Table A5. Household sector
Average (a) Compensation Total Gross
earnings of personal disposable
employees income income
[pounds sterling] billion,
2012=100 current prices
2010 97.1 819.2 1373.1 1062.3
2011 98.1 830.9 1400.1 1079.4
2012 100.0 850.1 1448.6 1127.9
2013 101.5 873.2 1476.0 1145.7
2014 101.6 888.8 1510.8 1172.1
2015 103.4 921.0 1569.5 1213.5
2016 105.1 942.7 1612.4 1243.0
2017 107.3 970.5 1663.0 1281.8
2018 110.4 1009.0 1739.3 1339.0
2019 114.1 1053.2 1829.0 1404.1
2020 117.9 1094.4 1925.0 1476.3
Percentage changes
2010/2009 3.3 3.0 4.4 5.2
2011/2010 1.0 1.4 2.0 1.6
2012/2011 1.9 2.3 3.5 4.5
2013/2012 1.5 2.7 1.9 1.6
2014/2013 0.1 1.8 2.4 2.3
2015/2014 1.7 3.6 3.9 3.5
2016/2015 1.6 2.4 2.7 2.4
2017/2016 2.1 2.9 3.1 3.1
2018/2017 2.9 4.0 4.6 4.5
2019/2018 3.3 4.4 5.2 4.9
2020/2019 3.3 3.9 5.2 5.1
Real Final
disposable consumption
income (b) expenditure
Total Durable
[pounds sterling] billion,
2012 prices
2010 1122.1 1062.3 88.2
2011 1099.3 1063.3 89.6
2012 1127.9 1082.6 95.2
2013 1120.2 1103.0 99.2
2014 1127.4 1130.3 107.9
2015 1164.9 1161.0 115.9
2016 1190.3 1193.1 121.5
2017 1216.2 1218.8 125.0
2018 1246.2 1237.9 128.6
2019 1277.4 1258.6 132.0
2020 1315.3 1284.3 135.5
Percentage changes
2010/2009 0.6 0.0 -2.6
2011/2010 -2.0 0.1 1.6
2012/2011 2.6 1.8 6.3
2013/2012 -0.7 1.9 4.2
2014/2013 0.6 2.5 8.7
2015/2014 3.3 2.7 7.4
2016/2015 2.2 2.8 4.9
2017/2016 2.2 2.2 2.9
2018/2017 2.5 1.6 2.9
2019/2018 2.5 1.7 2.6
2020/2019 3.0 2.0 2.6
Saving House Net
ratio (c) prices (d) worth to
income
ratio(e)
per cent 2012=100
2010 11.6 99.3 6.3
2011 9.1 98.4 6.5
2012 8.7 100.0 6.6
2013 6.3 103.5 6.6
2014 5.4 113.9 7.2
2015 4.2 121.5 7.5
2016 3.5 129.8 7.6
2017 3.6 135.1 7.4
2018 4.6 137.4 7.1
2019 5.5 139.9 7.0
2020 6.3 142.7 6.8
Percentage changes
2010/2009 7.2
2011/2010 -1.0
2012/2011 1.6
2013/2012 3.5
2014/2013 10.0
2015/2014 6.7
2016/2015 6.8
2017/2016 4.1
2018/2017 1.7
2019/2018 1.8
2020/2019 2.0
Notes: (a) Average earnings equals total labour compensation divided
by the number of employees, (b) Deflated by consumers' expenditure
deflator, (c) Includes adjustment for change in net equity of
households in pension funds, (d) Office for National Statistics,
mix-adjusted, (e) Net worth is defined as housing wealth plus net
financial assets.
Table A6. Fixed investment and capital
[pounds sterling] billion, 2012 prices
Gross fixed investment
Business Private General Total
investment housing (a) government
2010 140.4 63.2 55.7 259.2
2011 147.3 64.4 52.6 264.3
2012 154.8 64.5 48.9 268.2
2013 158.4 70.2 46.5 275.1
2014 165.8 80.0 49.2 295.1
2015 174.5 82.8 49.9 307.2
2016 180.0 87.0 51.1 318.1
2017 190.7 92.8 52.1 335.6
2018 197.4 97.5 52.2 347.1
2019 201.8 101.0 52.2 355.0
2020 204.4 103.2 55.3 362.9
Percentage changes
2010/2009 6.0 5.4 2.3 5.0
2011/2010 4.9 1.9 -5.4 2.0
2012/2011 5.1 0.2 -7.1 1.5
2013/2012 2.3 8.9 -4.9 2.6
2014/2013 4.7 14.0 5.8 7.3
2015/2014 5.2 3.5 1.5 4.1
2016/2015 3.2 5.1 2.4 3.6
2017/2016 5.9 6.7 2.0 5.5
2018/2017 3.5 5.1 0.2 3.4
2019/2018 2.3 3.5 0.0 2.3
2020/2019 1.3 2.2 5.9 2.2
User Corporate Capital stock
cost profit
of share of Private Public (b)
capital (%) GDP (%)
2010 15.4 23.4 3059.5 853.9
2011 14.9 24.4 3074.1 853.3
2012 13.4 23.9 3093.0 900.3
2013 12.4 25.1 3109.0 882.0
2014 12.4 25.8 3135.2 926.3
2015 13.5 25.2 3169.5 967.0
2016 13.3 24.4 3210.7 998.6
2017 13.7 24.5 3264.8 1023.7
2018 14.1 25.4 3326.0 1046.3
2019 14.5 26.0 3390.4 1068.3
2020 14.5 26.7 3454.8 1092.7
Percentage changes
2010/2009 0.3 4.1
2011/2010 0.5 -0.1
2012/2011 0.6 5.5
2013/2012 0.5 -2.0
2014/2013 0.8 5.0
2015/2014 1.1 4.4
2016/2015 1.3 3.3
2017/2016 1.7 2.5
2018/2017 1.9 2.2
2019/2018 1.9 2.1
2020/2019 1.9 2.3
Notes: (a) Includes private sector transfer costs of non-produced
assets, (b) Including public sector non-financial corporations.
Table A7. Productivity and the labour market
Thousands
Employment ILO Population
unemployment Labour of
Employees Total (a) force working
(b) age (c)
2010 25017 29229 2497 31725 40683
2011 25117 29376 2593 31969 40944
2012 25214 29697 2572 32268 40880
2013 25516 30043 2476 32519 40915
2014 25939 30726 2027 32753 41037
2015 26427 31190 1780 32970 41252
2016 26614 31473 1715 33187 41408
2017 26826 31710 1734 33444 41538
2018 27110 32027 1685 33712 41632
2019 27384 32340 1634 33974 41718
2020 27542 32533 1680 34212 41823
Percentage changes
2010/2009 -0.3 0.2 3.9 0.5 0.6
2011/2010 0.4 0.5 3.8 0.8 0.6
2012/2011 0.4 1.1 -0.8 0.9 -0.2
2013/2012 1.2 1.2 -3.7 0.8 0.1
2014/2013 1.7 2.3 -18.1 0.7 0.3
2015/2014 1.9 1.5 -12.2 0.7 0.5
2016/2015 0.7 0.9 -3.7 0.7 0.4
2017/2016 0.8 0.8 1.1 0.8 0.3
2018/2017 1.1 1.0 -2.8 0.8 0.2
2019/2018 1.0 1.0 -3.0 0.8 0.2
2020/2019 0.6 0.6 2.8 0.7 0.3
Productivity Unemployment, %
(2012=100)
Claimant ILO
Per hour Manufacturing rate unemployment
rate
2010 99.4 99.4 4.6 7.9
2011 100.9 102.2 4.7 8.1
2012 100.0 100.0 4.7 8.0
2013 100.4 99.4 4.3 7.6
2014 100.4 100.3 3.0 6.2
2015 101.4 98.2 2.3 5.4
2016 102.1 99.2 2.2 5.2
2017 104.1 101.7 2.2 5.2
2018 105.8 103.8 2.1 5.0
2019 107.3 106.2 1.9 4.8
2020 109.0 109.0 2.0 4.9
Percentage changes
2010/2009 1.2 7.9
2011/2010 1.5 2.7
2012/2011 -0.8 -2.1
2013/2012 0.4 -0.6
2014/2013 0.1 0.9
2015/2014 1.0 -2.1
2016/2015 0.7 1.0
2017/2016 2.0 2.5
2018/2017 1.6 2.0
2019/2018 1.3 2.3
2020/2019 1.6 2.7
Notes: (a) Includes self-employed, government-supported trainees and
unpaid family members, (b) Employment plus ILO unemployment,
(c) Population projections are based on annual rates of growth from
2014-based population projections by the ONS.
Table A8. Public sector financial balance and borrowing requirement
[pounds sterling] billion, fiscal years
2013-14 2014-15 2015-16 2016-17
Current receipts: Taxes on 375.9 390.3 403.3 422.1
income
Taxes on expenditure 222.5 230.6 239.3 247.9
Other current receipts 24.6 25.9 25.9 22.6
Total 623.0 646.7 668.6 692.7
(as a % of GDP) 35.5 35.3 35.6 36.5
Current expenditure: Goods 352.0 358.8 362.5 366.1
and services
Net social benefits paid 222.8 228.7 230.7 230.6
Debt interest 36.9 33.4 34.3 34.9
Other current expenditure 51.3 50.3 50.4 54.1
Total 663.0 671.2 677.9 685.7
(as a % of GDP) 37.8 36.6 36.1 36.1
Depreciation 36.0 37.0 37.9 39.7
Surplus on public sector -75.9 -61.5 -47.3 -32.7
current budget (a)
(as a % of GDP) -4.3 -3.4 -2.5 -1.7
Gross investment 63.2 66.5 66.8 70.7
Net investment 27.2 29.6 28.9 31.0
(as a % of GDP) 1.5 1.6 1.5 1.6
Total managed expenditure 726.2 737.7 744.7 756.4
(as a % of GDP) 41.3 40.3 39.7 39.8
Public sector net borrowing 103.1 91.0 76.2 63.7
(as a % of GDP) 5.9 5.0 4.1 3.4
Financial transactions 27.0 6.9 44.0 -2.6
Public sector net cash 76.1 84.1 32.2 66.3
requirement
(as a % of GDP) 4.3 4.6 1.7 3.5
Public sector net debt (% of 81.7 83.8 84.2 85.0
GDP)
GDP deflator at market prices 102.5 104.0 104.3 103.4
(2012= 100)
Money GDP 1755.9 1832.0 1876.4 1900.2
Financial balance under -5.6 -5.6 -4.3 -3.3
Maastricht (% of GDP) (b)
Gross debt under Maastricht 86.2 88.2 89.2 89.6
(% of GDP) (b)
2017-18 2018-19 2019-20 2020-21
Current receipts: Taxes on 432.8 456.9 490.7 514.2
income
Taxes on expenditure 255.7 265.7 278.0 289.8
Other current receipts 22.2 22.1 23.1 24.1
Total 710.7 744.7 791.7 828.1
(as a % of GDP) 36.2 36.2 36.8 36.9
Current expenditure: Goods 373.1 378.1 381.3 389.5
and services
Net social benefits paid 227.4 230.2 236.1 249.0
Debt interest 35.5 36.2 36.8 36.9
Other current expenditure 55.5 57.7 60.0 62.2
Total 691.5 702.2 714.1 737.6
(as a % of GDP) 35.2 34.2 33.2 32.8
Depreciation 41.5 43.3 45.1 47.0
Surplus on public sector -22.4 -0.8 32.5 43.5
current budget (a)
(as a % of GDP) -1.1 0.0 1.5 1.9
Gross investment 72.1 72.9 74.3 83.7
Net investment 30.6 29.6 29.2 36.8
(as a % of GDP) 1.6 1.4 1.4 1.6
Total managed expenditure 763.6 775.1 788.4 821.4
(as a % of GDP) 38.9 37.7 36.7 36.6
Public sector net borrowing 52.9 30.4 -3.3 -6.8
(as a % of GDP) 2.7 1.5 -0.2 -0.3
Financial transactions -1.7 -8.7 -10.1 -25.6
Public sector net cash 54.6 39.1 6.8 18.8
requirement
(as a % of GDP) 2.8 1.9 0.3 0.8
Public sector net debt (% of 84.3 82.3 79.1 76.6
GDP)
GDP deflator at market prices 104.0 106.3 108.8 111.2
(2012= 100)
Money GDP 1963.0 2055.6 2150.6 2245.8
Financial balance under -3.0 -1.9 -0.3 0.2
Maastricht (% of GDP) (b)
Gross debt under Maastricht 90.2 88.0 84.1 80.2
(% of GDP) (b)
Notes: These data are constructed from seasonally adjusted national
accounts data. This results in differences between the figures here
and unadjusted fiscal year data. Data exclude the impact of financial
sector interventions, but include flows from the Asset Purchase
Facility of the Bank of England. Housing associations are currently
classified as public sector only in the net debt data, (a) Public
sector current budget surplus is total current receipts less total
current expenditure and depreciation, (b) Calendar year.
Table A9. Saving and investment
As a percentage of GDP
Households Companies General government
Saving Investment Saving Investment Saving Investment
2010 8.5 4.3 10.7 8.9 -5.6 3.2
2011 6.4 4.3 12.2 8.9 -4.2 2.9
2012 6.2 4.4 11.2 9.2 -4.5 2.7
2013 4.4 4.7 10.8 9.6 -2.8 2.5
2014 3.7 5.1 11.4 9.8 -2.7 2.6
2015 2.9 5.3 10.9 9.7 -1.4 2.5
20/6 2.4 5.5 9.0 9.7 -0.3 2.5
2017 2.5 5.8 9.1 10.0 0.0 2.4
2018 3.2 6.0 8.7 10.1 1.0 2.3
2019 3.8 6.1 7.6 10.1 2.5 2.2
2020 4.4 6.1 7.1 10.0 3.1 2.4
Whole economy Finance from abroad (a)
Net
Saving Investment Total Net factor national
income saving
2010 13.6 16.4 2.8 -1.3 0.2
2011 14.5 16.1 1.7 -1.3 1.2
2012 12.9 16.2 3.3 -0.1 -0.4
2013 12.4 16.9 4.5 0.9 -0.9
2014 12.4 17.5 5.1 1.7 -0.9
2015 12.3 17.5 5.2 1.8 -0.7
20/6 11.2 17.6 6.5 2.1 -1.9
2017 11.7 18.2 6.6 1.7 -1.4
2018 12.9 18.4 5.5 1.6 -0.2
2019 13.9 18.4 4.5 1.3 0.9
2020 14.5 18.4 3.9 1.2 1.5
Notes: Saving and investment data are gross of depreciation unless
otherwise stated, (a) Negative sign indicates a surplus for the UK.
Table A10. Medium and long-term projections
All figures percentage change unless otherwise stated
2012 2013 2014 2015
GDP (market prices) 1.2 2.2 2.9 2.3
Average earnings 1.9 1.5 0.1 1.7
GDP deflator (market prices) 1.6 2.0 1.8 0.3
Consumer Prices Index 2.9 2.6 1.4 0.1
Per capita GDP 0.5 1.5 2.1 1.5
Whole economy productivity (a) -0.8 0.4 0.1 1.0
Labour input (b) 1.9 1.8 2.7 1.3
ILO unemployment rate (%) 8.0 7.6 6.2 5.4
Current account (% of GDP) -3.3 -4.5 -5.1 -5.2
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 44.1 41.1 40.7 40.0
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 8.2 5.5 5.6 4.4
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 77.3 80.5 82.7 84.6
Effective exchange rate
(2011 = 100) 104.2 102.9 110.9 118.2
Bank Rate (%) 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
3 month interest rates (%) 0.8 0.5 0.5 0.6
10 year interest rates (%) 1.8 2.4 2.5 1.8
2016 2017 2018 2019
GDP (market prices) 2.0 2.7 2.5 2.2
Average earnings 1.6 2.1 2.9 3.3
GDP deflator (market prices) -0.4 -0.1 2.0 2.4
Consumer Prices Index 0.3 0.9 1.9 2.3
Per capita GDP 1.3 2.0 1.8 1.6
Whole economy productivity (a) 0.7 2.0 1.6 1.3
Labour input (b) 1.3 0.6 1.0 0.9
ILO unemployment rate (%) 5.2 5.2 5.0 4.8
Current account (% of GDP) -6.5 -6.6 -5.5 -4.5
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 39.6 39.2 38.0 36.9
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 3.3 2.9 1.8 0.2
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 84.9 84.9 83.7 81.1
Effective exchange rate
(2011 = 100) 112.9 114 113.8 113.6
Bank Rate (%) 0.5 1.0 1.7 2.1
3 month interest rates (%) 0.6 1.2 1.9 2.3
10 year interest rates (%) 1.6 2.3 2.8 3.3
2020 2021-25
GDP (market prices) 2.2 2.2
Average earnings 3.3 3.3
GDP deflator (market prices) 2.2 2.1
Consumer Prices Index 2.1 2.1
Per capita GDP 1.5 1.6
Whole economy productivity (a) 1.6 1.8
Labour input (b) 0.5 0.4
ILO unemployment rate (%) 4.9 5.2
Current account (% of GDP) -3.9 -3.5
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 36.6 36.9
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) -0.3 0.0
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 78.2 68.9
Effective exchange rate
(2011 = 100) 113.3 112.5
Bank Rate (%) 2.5 3.6
3 month interest rates (%) 2.7 3.8
10 year interest rates (%) 3.6 4.1
Notes: (a) Per hour, (b) Total hours worked.
Simon Kirby *, with Oriol Carreras **, Jack Meaning ** and Rebecca
Piggott **
* NIESR and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail:
[email protected].
**NIESR. Thanks to Jessica Baker and James Warren for helpful comments
and suggestions. Unless otherwise stated, the source of all data
reported in the figures and tables is the NiGEM database and forecast
baseline. The UK forecast was completed on 27 April 2016.
Table 1. Summary of the forecast
Percentage change
2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
GDP 1.2 2.2 2.9 2.3 2.0
Per capita GDP 0.5 1.5 2.1 1.5 1.3
CPI Inflation 2.9 2.6 1.4 0.1 0.3
RPIX Inflation 3.2 3.1 2.4 1.0 1.4
RPDI 2.6 -0.7 0.6 3.3 2.2
Unemployment, % 8.0 7.6 6.2 5.4 5.2
Bank Rate, % 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Long Rates, % 1.8 2.4 2.5 1.8 1.6
Effective exchange rate 4.2 -1.2 7.8 6.6 -4.5
Current account as % of GDP -3.3 -4.5 -5.1 -5.2 -6.5
PSNB as % of GDP (a) 7.4 5.9 5.0 4.1 3.4
PSND % of GDP (a) 79.5 81.7 83.8 84.2 85.0
2017 2018 2019 2020
GDP 2.7 2.5 2.2 2.2
Per capita GDP 2.0 1.8 1.6 1.5
CPI Inflation 0.9 1.9 2.3 2.1
RPIX Inflation 1.7 2.6 2.9 2.7
RPDI 2.2 2.5 2.5 3.0
Unemployment, % 5.2 5.0 4.8 4.9
Bank Rate, % 1.0 1.7 2.1 2.5
Long Rates, % 2.3 2.8 3.3 3.6
Effective exchange rate 0.9 -0.2 -0.2 -0.2
Current account as % of GDP -6.6 -5.5 -4.5 -3.9
PSNB as % of GDP (a) 2.7 1.5 -0.2 -0.3
PSND % of GDP (a) 84.3 82.3 79.1 76.6
Notes: RPDI is real personal disposable income. PSNB is public sector
net borrowing. PSND is public sector net debt, (a) Fiscal year,
excludes the impact of financial sector interventions, but includes
the flows from the Asset Purchase Facility of the Bank of England.
Housing associations are not currently classified as public sector
only in the public sector net debt figure.