Immigration, free movement and the EU referendum.
Portes, Jonathan
Immigration and free movement are central issues in the UK's
referendum on EU membership. Although free movement was a founding
principle of the EU, it only became of central economic and political
importance after the expansion of the EU eastward in 2004. For the UK,
the economic impacts of recent EU migration appear to have been
relatively benign, even for the low paid and low skilled. The UK's
recent 'renegotiation', which focused on the largely
irrelevant issue of 'benefit tourism', will make little
difference. A vote to Leave, however, will potentially take us into new
territory for UK immigration policy,
Keywords: immigration: free movement: European Union
JEL Classifications: F22; J61; N34
Introduction
Immigration has long been a salient and disputed issue in British
politics. This was the case 40 years ago; the government's decision
to admit a substantial number of refugees of Indian ethnicity from
former British colonies in East Africa was hotly disputed, and then as
now a large majority favoured much tighter restrictions on immigration
to the UK. But it scarcely figured as an issue in the 1975 referendum on
whether the United Kingdom should remain a member of the European Union
(then the European Economic Community). (1) Indeed, if anything, there
was actually a small negative correlation between attitudes to
immigration and to the EU (that is, those who thought immigration was
too high were slightly more likely to vote to stay in (Evans and Mellon,
2015).
Today, the opposite is the case. Negative attitudes to immigration,
and in particular free movement within the EU, are by far the strongest
predictor of opposition to UK membership. This is true in raw polling
data, but also when controlling for socio-demographic factors
(Vasilopoulou, 2016). This article examines the history of free movement
within the EU, and in particular the origins and impact of the decision
to allow immediate access to the labour market for workers from the new
Member States in 2004. It then considers the impact of the referendum;
first, it examines the motivation for and likely impact of the UK's
renegotiation of various provisions relating to free movement, and
second, possible options for changes to UK immigration policy in the
event of Brexit.
Free movement of workers
The EU was founded on four basic principles: free movement of
labour, capital, goods and services: these 'four freedoms'
were set out in the original Treaty of Rome, which spoke of the
"abolition, as between Member States, of obstacles to the free
movement of persons" (European Commission, 1957). While the primary
driver may have been a desire to promote European integration for its
own sake, the founders of the EU also believed that there were large
economic benefits. In fact, economic theory is ambiguous on whether
factor mobility (in this context, the free movement of labour and
capital) is a complement or a substitute to free trade (the free
movement of goods and services). In a standard Heckscher-Ohlin model,
they are pure substitutes. Either free trade or factor mobility will
increase the efficiency of resource allocation and will maximise overall
welfare; it is not necessary to have both.
Similarly, capital mobility may in some circumstances be a
substitute for labour mobility. But in more recent, and arguably more
realistic, trade models the picture is much less clear (see Venables,
1999, for a review). The general consensus among economists is that
labour mobility, like trade, is welfare-enhancing, although there may be
significant distributional effects. Ozden (2015) provides a useful
summary of the consensus view.
However, while the economic case may be strong in principle, other
free trade areas (for example the North American Free Trade Area) or
even customs unions do not typically involve free movement of people.
So, from a purely economic perspective, free movement was not a
necessary part of the European project; it would have been possible to
have a customs union, and an integrated economic space, without it; the
decision to make it one of the founding principles was a political as
well as an economic choice. Labour mobility was complementary not just
to the economic aspects of European integration but to its wider
political objectives. The commitment to free movement of workers set out
in the Treaty was bolstered by a further Directive in 1968.
The period from the late 1950s to the early 1970s saw strong
economic growth in most of the EU. Demand for labour was strong and
unemployment low. However, intra-EU labour mobility remained quite low,
compared to for example the US, although there were significant flows
from Italy to other EU countries, especially France. Labour demand was
therefore largely met by immigration from outside the EU, especially
Turkish 'guest workers' in Germany, North African migrants to
France and--although the UK was not yet an EU Member State--Commonwealth
migrants to Britain. (Kokkailainen, 2011).
So when the UK joined the EU in 1973, and subsequently voted to
remain a member in 1975, the potential impact on either UK immigration
policy, or the level and nature of immigration to the UK, appeared to be
relatively small. The economic crisis of the 1970s led to a sharp
reduction in labour demand, and most EU countries, including the UK,
attempted to reduce labour migration. Intra-EU mobility remained quite
low throughout the 1980s and 1990s. The accession to the Union of Spain
and Portugal in 1986 did not lead to a significant increase. Although
they had traditionally been countries of emigration, EU accession (and
large inflows of EU funding) led swiftly to rapid economic growth and
ample domestic demand for labour.
The 1980s and early 1990s did see a renewed push for greater market
integration, launched, with the strong support of the UK, under the
umbrella of the 'Single Market'. However, the
Commission's 1985 White Paper, which identified obstacles to the
Single Market and set out proposals to address them, devoted only one
relatively anodyne page to free movement: the focus was very much on
product markets (European Commission, 1985).
So by 2000, although increasingly economically integrated in terms
of trade, and despite the political commitment to free movement, only
slightly over 1 per cent of EU citizens lived in a country other than
their country of birth, and the previous decade had seen only a very
modest upward trend (Varga and in't Veld, 2014). Approximately 2
per cent of the UK population was born elsewhere in the EU.
The potential downsides of this lack of mobility, despite the
formal right to free movement, became more salient as the EU moved
towards monetary union. The standard theory of optimal currency areas
suggested that the costs of giving up the exchange rate as an adjustment
mechanism (as a consequence of entering into an economic union) would be
reduced if other adjustment mechanisms, in particular labour mobility,
were able to operate (Mundell, 1961). There was therefore considerable
concern that the lack of labour mobility posed a threat to the efficient
operation of the incipient monetary union; this debate is summarised in
Varga and in't Veld (2014).
Partly in response to these concerns, the EU undertook a number of
initiatives designed to turn "free movement of workers" from a
formal right to one that appeared a realistic prospect to EU citizens.
In particular, the Free Movement of Citizens Directive (European
Commission, 2004) simplified, consolidated and considerably extended the
right to free movement for EU citizens, not just to take a job but to
look for one, and to be accompanied by family members (including non-EU
citizens) as long as those exercising free movement were not an
"undue burden". This also extended to non-discrimination
against EU citizens, except in limited and temporary circumstances, in
the operation of the benefit system.
The 2004 and 2007 accessions
The accession, in May 2004, of ten new Member States, including a
number of members of the former Soviet bloc (often referred to as the
Accession 8, or A8 or EU-8, states--Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic,
Slovakia, Slovenia, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania), radically changed
the dynamic of intra-EU labour mobility. As set out above, free movement
had (from an economic perspective) originally been motivated by, first,
theoretical arguments about optimal resource allocation; and, second, by
its potential to serve as an adjustment mechanism in the face of
asymmetric macroeconomic shocks. It had not been seen as operating in an
area where there were very large, persistent, structural differences in
wage levels, as was now the case.
Given these disparities, there was clearly a possibility of much
larger intra-EU flows than had previously been the case. A number of
Member States therefore took the opportunity permitted by the accession
treaties to impose 'transitional' restrictions on free
movement of workers.
The UK (together with Ireland and Sweden), however, did not. A myth
has since emerged that the main reason the UK government granted
immediate access was because of a supposed 'Home Office
forecast' that only 13,000 migrants would arrive. In fact, the
forecast in question (Dustmann et al., 2003) was independent external
research, commissioned but not produced by government, and was to a
certain extent already irrelevant by the time the decision was taken
(since it was conditional on all EU countries granting immediate labour
market access). Within government, there were three far more important
arguments for the decision.
First, the broader geopolitical one. The UK had long been the most
vigorous proponent of membership for the countries of the former Eastern
bloc; they were seen (correctly) as likely allies for the UK's
generally liberal positions in EU debates. So the decision was seen as a
way of cementing our relationship with them, and in particular the
Polish government.
Second, the broader economic and labour market impacts. The UK
labour market was buoyant; and all the analysis suggested that immigrant
workers--particularly the reasonably well educated and motivated ones
likely to arrive from the new Member States--were likely to boost the
UK's economy without doing much, if any, damage to the prospects of
native workers.
And third, the practicalities, given the UK's relatively light
touch approach to labour market regulation. There was no legal provision
which would have allowed the UK to deny the right of visa-free entry to
the citizens of the new EU member states: the only available option was
to prevent them from working legally as employees. The assumption within
government was therefore that the impact of imposing transitional
restrictions would be a very large increase in illegal working. This
hardly seemed like an attractive alternative.
In 2007, Bulgaria and Romania joined the EU; this too led to a
significant increase in flows, although this time Spain and Italy were
major destination countries. The UK and most other countries imposed
transitional restrictions, which were finally lifted in all EU countries
by 2014, so there is now complete free movement for the EU27 (some
Member States still impose restrictions on Croatian nationals).
Impacts
The impact of accession on intra-EU migration flows was large and
sustained, with substantial increases in migration to all the major
economies of the existing EU, even the ones that did impose
restrictions, like Germany, but in particular the UK and Ireland.
Goodhart (2013) described the influx of A8 nationals to the UK as the
"biggest peacetime movement [of people] in European history.
Holland et al. (2011) found that enlargement tripled (relative to a
no-enlargement counterfactual) A8 migration to the EU-15. The main
drivers were economic: Kahanec et al. (2014) found that migration
responded both to structural economic differences between Member States,
and to short-term economic shocks; and that accession had led to
significant increases in mobility, albeit hampered in part by the
imposition of transitional restrictions. At an individual level, the
vast majority of migrants moved to work, attracted by either higher
wages or greater job opportunities. Location decisions were also
influenced by cultural factors and network effects (Galogski et al.,
2009).
The financial crisis and ensuing recession did temporarily reduce
flows to the UK in the 2008-12 period. However, since 2013, recovery in
the UK labour market, continuing economic difficulties in some eurozone
countries, and (in 2014) the ending of transitional restrictions on
Bulgarian and Romanian nationals have resulted in a further sharp rise
in the migration of EU citizens to the UK.
Over the past decade, then, the UK resident population originally
from other EU member states has more than doubled, to more than 3
million, and continues to rise rapidly. Even this may understate the
possible impacts on the UK labour market: over the past four years, more
than 2 million EU nationals have registered for UK National Insurance
numbers, required for (legal) access to employment. It is unclear
whether the disparity between this and the official immigration
statistics reflects very short-term and seasonal migration, or other
factors such as under-recording.
As noted above, the primary motivation for migration was work, and
most new migrants are in employment, with employment rates for intra-EU
migrants well above rates for natives. One notable feature of migrants
from the new Member States was that, although they were not necessarily
low skilled, they primarily moved into low skilled employment in
destination countries, and were concentrated in certain sectors (for
example, construction, retail, hospitality, domestic work, food
processing and agriculture) (MAC, 2014).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Standard theory predicts that a substantial movement of 'low
skilled' workers from relatively low wage/low productivity
economies to higher wage/productivity economies will (assuming that the
workers are employed in relatively low skilled jobs) result in:
* increased output, although impacts on per capita output will be
considerably smaller, and possibly ambiguous;
* an increase, possibly temporary, in the skill premium (the wage
of a skilled worker relative to an unskilled one) and hence in wage
inequality;
* depending on labour market institutions, a possible impact on
unemployment.
Public and policy concern has focused on the distributional
impacts--in particular potential negative impacts on employment and
wages for low skilled workers. Although the broad consensus in the
economic literature is that negative impacts of migration for native
workers are, if they exist at all, relatively small and short-lived
(see, for example, Constant, 2014) much of this literature is US-based;
there was almost no empirical literature on the economic impact of
immigration to the UK before 2004. Unsurprisingly, given the size of the
migratory flows, this deficiency has now been remedied. There is a now a
considerable literature on the impact on the UK economy and labour
market.
To the considerable surprise of many economists, including this
author, there is now a clear consensus that even in the short term EU
migration does not appear to have had a negative impact on the
employment outcomes of UK natives. A comprehensive literature review by
the UK government (Home Office and BIS, 2014) found that "To date
there has been little evidence in the literature of a statistically
significant impact from EU migration on native employment
outcomes".
While the evidence on wage impacts is less conclusive, the emerging
consensus is that recent migration has had little or no impact overall,
but possibly some, small, negative impact on low skilled workers.
Nickell and Salaheen (2015) find that a 10 percentage point rise in the
immigrant share leads to approximately a 1.5 per cent reduction in wages
for native workers in the semi/unskilled service sector; this would mean
that immigration since 2004 would have reduced wages for native workers
in that sector by about 1 per cent, or put another way would have
depressed annual pay increases by about a penny an hour.
Beyond the aggregate impacts on employment and wages, there may
also be other impacts on labour market institutions and structures,
positive and negative, particularly if migration results in labour
market segmentation (MAC, 2014).
There is indeed some evidence of dual or segmented labour markets
in some low paid sectors, for example food and drink manufacturing,
where migrants are disproportionately represented in the seasonal,
temporary or flexible workforce. The division is however, blurred with
migrants having a greater or lesser presence by sector, location and
over time (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016). Of course, the existence of
dual or segmented labour markets in low paid sectors pre-dates the
arrival of EU migrants: the food and drink sector, for example, relied
historically on women and itinerant workers in peak periods before it
had access to migrants (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016).
The increased use of temporary work and flexible contracts in low
pay sectors such as hospitality and food manufacturing is due to
structural factors and competitive pressures on firms rather than labour
market strategies in themselves (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016). Given
that these pressures are part of the context in which they operate,
employers argue that the availability of migrants has allowed their
businesses to be competitive and to expand in a way which would not have
been possible given relatively low levels of unemployment in the past
decade (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016). The needs of employers in low
skilled sectors and of new migrants have been well-matched: migrants
take low skilled jobs in these sectors because they offer an easy entry
to the UK labour market, allowing them to work long hours through
overtime without long-term commitment (Anderson et al, 2006; Green et
al., 2013; Pauritus, 2014). The offer of temporary work with flexible or
'zero hours' contracts is, in contrast, unattractive to many
UK workers and problematic for those coming off unemployment benefits.
An additional feature of Eastern European migration in particular has
been a willingness to live and work throughout the UK, while previous
migrants have been drawn largely to the South East and to urban
conurbations (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016).
The consensus, then, is that the impact on the UK labour market has
been relatively benign. As one recent evidence review (Wadsworth and
Vaitilingam, 2015) summarised:
"On balance, the evidence for the UK labour market suggests
that fears about adverse consequences of rising immigration in general
and EU immigration in particular have still not, on average,
materialised. It is hard to find evidence of much displacement of UK
workers or lower wages, on average. Immigrants, especially in recent
years, tend to be younger and better educated than the UK-born and less
likely to be unemployed. But there have been some effects. The less
skilled may have experienced greater downward pressure on wages and
greater competition for jobs than others, but these effects still appear
to have been small."
Given the labour market impacts, fiscal impacts too might be
expected to be positive. Dustmann and Frattini (2014) found that
migrants from the EU to the UK made a significant positive contribution
to the public finances, even during periods when the UK as a whole was
running a fiscal deficit. Of course, it is hardly surprising that young
migrants in employment make an initial positive fiscal contribution;
proper assessment of fiscal impacts requires a lifecyle perspective
(Preston, 2014). In this context, there are various reasons to expect
the impact still to be positive (in particular, migrants tend to arrive
after they have left compulsory, publicly financed education). This
issue is discussed below in the section on the future impacts of
immigration policy changes.
However, positive net impact on public finances at the national
level does not preclude significant impact on demand (and hence cost) at
the local level, particularly if funding allocations do not adjust
quickly (or at all) to reflect pressures resulting from migration
(George et al., 2011). A notable recent example is the shortage of
primary school places in some parts of the UK (especially London); this
appears to be largely the result of poor planning on the part of central
government, given the rise in the number of young children resulting
from recent increases in migration (from both the EU and elsewhere).
Benefit tourism and the UK's renegotation
As far back as 1993, Conservative opponents of the European Union
focused on the issue of 'benefit tourism'. In his speech to
the Conservative Party Conference, the then Secretary of State for
Social Security, Peter Lilley, claimed (referring, apparently, to
Italian, French and German nationals):
"Community rules have opened up a new abuse: 'Benefit
Tourism'. People travelling around pretending to look for work, but
really looking for the best benefits. Not so much a Cook's tour as
a Crooks' tour. Gordon Brown claims our system is less generous
than elsewhere in Europe. Then why do they come and scrounge off us?
They certainly don't come here for the climate."
In fact, the UK government has been notably unable to substantiate
its position that 'benefit tourism' is a significant policy
concern. There is no evidence that access to the UK benefit system is a
major driver of migration flows. Overall, migrants are under-represented
among benefit claimants, and especially claimants of unemployment and
other out-of-work benefits. And while it is EU migrants who claim
significant amounts of 'in-work' benefits, which are available
to low paid workers, especially those with children, most do so only
after they have already been resident for several years, suggesting it
has little to do with their original migration decision (Portes, 2015).
The wider economic literature also supports the view that differences in
benefit entitlements are not a significant driver of migration
(Giuletti, 2014).
Nevertheless, migrant access to benefit entitlements was a key
issue in the UK's renegotiation. The 'emergency brake'
will allow the UK to phase in entitlements to in-work benefits for new
arrivals from the EU over a period of four years. But this arrangement
will be time-limited --after seven years it will expire entirely, and we
will be back to the status quo. The UK will also be allowed to reduce,
but not eliminate, child benefit payments paid to those with children
living abroad, initially for new arrivals but then from 2020 for
existing migrants too. It is generally accepted (even within the UK
government) that the impact of these provisions on benefit payments will
be small, and on migration flows negligible.
Perhaps the real significance of the renegotiation is that it has
clarified that, as set out above, free movement remains a fundamental
principle within the EU; the UK has broadly accepted the status quo.
There is no treaty change, now or promised, and the main measures the UK
is entitled to impose are temporary and/or time-limited. That means the
dividing lines for the referendum are more clearly drawn. If the UK
votes to stay in, it will have accepted--however reluctantly--that
staying entails a commitment to free movement of workers in the EU, both
in principle and practice, and the resulting migration flows, with the
impacts described above. If, however, it votes to leave, then it could
potentially regain a considerable degree of flexibility. The next
section explores policy options and potential impacts in such an
eventuality.
Options for immigration policy after Brexit
The EEA option: modified status quo
Leaving the EU does not necessarily mean ending free movement. If
we wanted to preserve access to the EU single market--as many of those
who favour exit say they want--then the most obvious way to do so would
be for us to join Norway (and Iceland and Liechtenstein) as members of
the European Economic Area. But free movement actually applies to EEA
members on a similar basis as to EU members. Alternatively, we could
emulate Switzerland, and negotiate bilateral agreements for market
access. However, while the Swiss recently voted to impose quotas on EU
migration, this has so far proved unacceptable to the EU; negotiations
are continuing, but there is little prospect of a resolution before the
UK referendum.
It is of course by no means necessarily the case that, post-Brexit,
full freedom of movement would be a precondition for UK access to the
Single Market. And even if it were it might well be possible for the UK
to negotiate some restrictions that are not currently available (on
benefit entitlement, for example). But it is certainly at least
plausible that post-Brexit the best available option for the UK might
simply be a somewhat modified version of the status quo. In that case,
the impact on migration flows would be small--indeed, both Switzerland
and Norway have higher levels of migration from within the EU than the
UK does now.
If, however, we were no longer part of the EU free movement area, a
sensible immigration policy would look quite different to current
policy. There would be no rationale for, as we do now, offering
completely free access to the UK labour market for workers, skilled or
otherwise, from Bulgaria or Belgium, while imposing tight restrictions
on even highly skilled workers with a job offer or scarce skills from
India or Indonesia.
But this in itself does not say very much about what a post-Brexit
system would look like. While proponents of Brexit frequently talk about
an "Australian-style points system", this begs more questions
than it answers. In fact, as far back as 2008, the then government
claimed that this was exactly what it was introducing. As Randall Hansen
points out (Hansen, 2015), the countries with fully-fledged points
systems (Canada and Australia) introduced them as a way of targeting
growth in both overall population and human capital. So what might it
mean in practice for the UK?
A restrictive system
If immigration and free movement are indeed the determining factor
in the referendum result, there may be strong political pressure on a
post-Brexit government to deliver very large reductions in immigration
to the UK. Both inside and outside the government, those arguing for
Brexit have long made the case that it is EU membership that prevents
the government from delivering its popular pledge to reduce immigration
to "the tens of thousands". Without the 'excuse' of
freedom of movement, the government might be obliged to turn what is
currently little more than an aspiration into a serious policy
objective.
In practice, this would be extremely difficult. Migration Watch
(2016), for example, argues that applying the same migration rules to EU
nationals as currently apply to non-EU ones would reduce net migration
by about 100,000. It follows that further significant reductions in
non-EU migration--which is currently slightly higher than EU
migration--would be required to meet the government's pledge. The
economic consequences would be significant. As Nardelli (2015) points
out, in the short term a reduction in migration on this scale would
jeopardise the government's ability to achieve its fiscal targets.
Looking at the longer term, Lisenkova (2014), using an overlapping
generations model to project out the impacts of migration to 2060 for
the UK, finds that migration has significant positive impacts on both
GDP per capita and on the public finances over the very long term; a
reduction in migration levels of 50 per cent would require an increase
in the tax rate on labour income of about 2 per cent to preserve budget
balance. This impact is particularly strong for intra-EU migrants,
because of their young age structure and high activity rates.
At a sectoral level, the consequences of restrictions for some
industries that rely on migration from within the EU to fill low skilled
jobs would be very large. At least in theory, it is possible to
construct a plausible economic rationale; while restrictions would cut
growth in the short term, it might over time incentivise firms into
productivity-enhancing investment or training. However, there is little
or no evidence that occupational or sectoral usage of migrant labour is
associated with lower levels of training (MAC, 2008). Other research has
focused on migration from outside the EU and in relation to higher-level
skills, but has similar findings (George et al., 2012; CIPD, 2014). In
low paid sectors the difficulty of attracting and retaining young people
appears to act as a disincentive to training, rather than the
availability of migrants (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016).
In the event of much stricter restrictions on low skilled labour
migration, employers would have a variety of alternative options,
including increasing efforts to recruit local UK workers, young people
or older workers (Ruhs and Martin, 2008; SQW, 2010, George et al.,
2012). Employers rarely state a preference for migrants or have in place
a purposeful strategy to recruit them, and some employers in low paid
sectors constantly review their recruitment strategies and possible
alternatives to EU migrant labour (Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp, 2016).
However, employers identify problems with both the supply and quality of
UK born workers, particularly in periods of (as now) low unemployment
(Green et al., 2013; CIPD, 2014, 2015; McCollum and Findlay, 2015; Rolfe
and Hudson-Sharp, 2016). Employers in low skill sectors are also aware
that various features of the jobs they offer, including low wages,
unsocial hours, temporary work, low status and poor promotion
opportunities, are unattractive to UK workers. It is likely that some
sectors might therefore suffer significant recruitment difficulties. The
incentives for irregular migration and illegal working would of course
also increase significantly.
The evidence on the impact on wages suggests that there a
restrictive policy might have some (relatively small) positive direct
impact on wages for low skilled workers, although little or none for
medium and highly skilled workers. However, the impact on incomes would
be more than offset by the wider negative economic and fiscal impacts.
Lisenkova (2014) suggests that the small positive impact on unskilled
wages from lower migration is more than offset by the tax rises (or
public spending cuts) resulting from the negative fiscal impacts, so
real post-tax incomes would fall.
Equalisation--liberal
However, whether for political or economic reasons, some proponents
of Brexit have argued that it would allow a more liberal approach to
non-EU migration. For example, Migration Watch also claim that lower EU
migration would "make room" for Syrian refugees, while Ukip
now favours a significant increase in skilled migration from outside the
EU to accompany a reduction in EU migration. This would mean that
immigration continued to run at historically fairly high levels; it
could, however, support a rebalancing from unskilled jobs to skilled
migration. What would be the likely impacts?
If appropriately structured, a relaxation of controls on skilled
migration could potentially relieve some of the barriers to growth
imposed by current government policy. At the moment, the quota for Tier
2 skilled workers is preventing some companies from recruiting for
skilled jobs, and the government intends to further tighten
restrictions, despite the evidence that such restrictions are likely to
further damage productivity and growth (MAC, 2016).
A particular issue would be the impact on relatively low paid, but
skilled, occupations in the public sector, such as nurses. Current
restrictions on non-EU migrants have led to significant staff shortages.
If a new system precluded EU migrants as well in these sectors, this
would make things even worse; if, on the other hand, it allowed more
non-EU migrants as well, matters might improve.
As noted above, the consequence for some sectors that rely heavily
on migration from within the EU to fill relatively low skilled jobs
could be significant.
The impacts on wages would be stronger and, for the unskilled, more
positive in this scenario. Rebalancing towards higher skilled migration
could, in principle, both raise wages for the lower skilled and improve
the fiscal impacts of migration, boosting post-tax incomes.
Conclusion
Few would have predicted the centrality of free movement in the
Brexit debate; its importance was certainly not anticipated by either
supporters or opponents of the EU even a decade ago, let alone at the
time of British entry. While the economic impacts of recent EU migration
appear to have been relatively benign--even for the low paid and low
skilled--it remains the most important issue for many, perhaps most,
likely voters, and the 'renegotiation', which focused on the
largely irrelevant issue of 'benefit tourism', has not changed
that. This means that a vote to Remain will unequivocally be a vote for
the status quo in this area. A vote to Leave, however, will take us into
new territory for UK immigration policy, with potentially significant
consequences; as yet, we have almost no detail on what those might be.
NOTE
(1) For simplicity I will refer to the 'EU' throughout.
REFERENCES
Anderson, B., Ruhs, M., Rogaly, B., and Spencer, S. (2006),
'Fair enough? Central and Eastern European migrants in low-wage
employment in the UK', COMPAS, available from: http://www.
irr.org.uk/pdf/Fair_Enough.pdf (accessed: 3 I July 2015).
CIPD (2014), The Growth of EU Labour. Assessing the Impact on the
UK Labour Market, CIPD
http://www.cipd.co.uk/binaries/thegrowth-of-eu-labour-assessing-impact-uk-labour-market_2014. pdf.
--(2015), Labour Market Outlook, Autumn 2015 report. Constant, A.F.
(2014), 'Do migrants take the jobs of native workers?' IZA
World of Labor, available at https://www.gov.uk/government/
publications/impacts-of-migration-on-uk-native-employment-ananalytical-review-of-the-evidence.
Dustmann, C., Casanova, M., Fertig, M., Preston, I. and Schmidt,
C.M. (2003), The Impact of EU Enlargement on Migration Flows, Home
Office Online Report 25/03.
Dustmann, C. and Frattini, T. (2014), The fiscal effects of
immigration to the UK', Economic Journal, 124(580).
European Commission (1957), http://europa.eu/eu-law/decision
making/treaties/index_en.htm
--(1985), Completing the Internal Market, White Paper from the
Commission to the European Council, available at http://europa.
eu/documents/comm/white_papers/pdf/com 1985 0310_f_ en.pdf.
--(2004), Free Movement of Citizens Directive, available at http://
eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:32
004L0038&from=EN.
Evans, G. and Mellon, J. (2015), 'Immigration and the EU:
attitudes and perceptions, myths and realities', presentation to
NIESR Conference on Immigration and the EU-UK relationship, available at
http://www.niesr.ac.uk/sites/default/files/civicrm/
persist/contribute/files/Presentation%208th%20december%20 NIESR.pptxview
at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ fandd/2015/03/ozden.htm#author
for a good summary of the consensus view on the economics of
international civicrm/
persist/contribute/files/Presentation%208th%20december%20 NIESR.pptxview
at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ fandd/2015/03/ozden.htm#author
for a good summary of the consensus view on the economics of
international migration.)
http://www.migrationwatchuk.org/briefing-paper/371.
Galogski, B., Leschke, J. and Watt, A. (2009), EU Labour Migration
Since Enlargement Trends, Impacts and Policies, Ashgate Publishing,
available at http://books.google.co.uk/books/about/EU_Labour_
Migration_since_Enlargement.html.
George, A, Lalani, M., Mason, G., Rolfe H. and Rosazza, C. (2012),
'Skilled immigration and strategically important skills in the UK
economy', Migration Advisory Committee
George, A., Meadows, P., Metcalf, H. and Rolfe H. (201 I), Impact
of Migration on the Consumption of Education and Children's
Services and the Consumption of Health Services, Social Care and Social
Services, Report to the Migration Advisory Committee, London: MAC,
available at: http://www.ukba.homeoffice.
gov.uk/sitecontent/documents/aboutus/workingwithus/
mac/27-analysis-migration/02-research-projects/impact-ofmigration?view=Binary.
Giuletti, C. (2014), 'The welfare magnet hypothesis and the
welfare take-up of migrants', IZA World of Labour, available at
http:// newsroom.iza.org/de/wp-content/uploads/2014/06/welfaremagnet-hypothesis-and-welfare-take-up.pdf.
Goodhart, D. (2013), National Citizen Preference in an Era of EU
Free Movement, Submission to the Government's Review of the Balance
of Competencies, July (updated December), available at
www.demos.co.uk/files/DavidGoodhartSubmissionJuly2013.pdf.
Green, A., Atfield, G., Adam, D., Staniewicz, T. (2013),
Determinants of the Composition of the Workforce in Low Skilled Sectors
of the Economy, Warwick Institute for Employment Research report to MAC
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/file/257272/warwick-insti.pdf.
Hansen, R. (2015), 'An Australian points system for
Britain?', King's College London, available at
http://ukandeu.ac.uk/an-australianpoints-system-for-britain/.
Holland, D., Fic, T., Rincon-Aznar, A., Stokes, L. and Paluchowski,
P. (2011), Labour Mobility Within the EU--the Impact of Enlargement,
London, National Institute of Economic and Social Research.
Home Office and Department for Business and Skills (2014),
'The impacts of migration on uk native employment: an analytical
review of the evidence', https://www.gov.uk/government/
publications/impacts-of-migration-on-uk-native-employmentan-analytical-review-of-the-evidence: http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/ download/paO 15.pdf.
Kahanec, M., Pytlikova, M. and Zimmermann, K.F. (2014), 'The
free movement of workers in an enlarged European Union: institutional
underpinnings of economic adjustment', IZA discussion paper 8456,
available at http://ftp.iza.org/dp8456.pdf.
Koikkalainen, S. (2011), Free Movement in Europe: Past and Present,
Migration Policy Institute, April, available at http://www.
migrationpolicy.org/article/free-movement-europe-past-andpresent.
Lisenkova, K. (2014), 'The long-term economic impact of
reducing migration in the UK', National Institute Economic Review,
229, August, R22-30.
McCollum, D. and Findlay, A. (2015), "Flexible' workers
for 'flexible' jobs? The labour market function of A8 migrant
labour in the UK', Work Employment & Society, 29 (3), pp.
427-43.
Migration Advisory Committee (2008), Identifying Skilled
Occupations Where Migration Can Sensibly Fill Labour Shortages, London:
Migration Advisory Committee (MAC).
--(2014), 'Migrants in low skilled work':
https://www.gov.uk/ government/publications/migrants-in-low-skilled-work.
--(2016), 'Review of Tier 2: Balancing migrant selectivity,
investment in skills and impacts on UK productivity and
competitiveness', London: Migration Advisory Committee.
Migration Watch (2016), 'UK immigration policy outside the
EU', available at
http://www.migrationwatchuk.org/briefingpaper/371.
Mundell, R.A. (1961), 'A theory of optimum currency
areas', American Economic Review, 51.
Nardelli, A. (2015), 'Osborne reliant on rising immigration
levels to achieve budget surplus', The Guardian, December,
available at http://www.theguardian.com/uk-news/20 I 5/dec/0 I /
osborne-reliant-on-rising-immigration-levels-to-achieve-budgetsurplushttp://www.migrationpolicy.org/article/free- movement-
europe-past-and-present.
Nickell, S. and Salaheen, J. (2015), The impact of immigration on
occupational wages: evidence from Britain', Staff Working Paper No.
574, available at http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/research/
Pages/workingpapers/2015/swp574.aspx.
Ozden, C. (2015), 'A long commute', IMF, Finance and
Development, 52, I, March, available at
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ fandd/2015/03/ozden.htm.
Pauritus, V. (2014), "'Economic migrants" or
"middling transnationals"? East European migrants'
experiences of work in the UK', International Migration, 52 (I),
pp. 36-55.
Portes, J. (2014), 'Benefit Tourism: the Commission gives us
some facts': http://niesr.ac.uk/blog/benefit-tourism-commission-givesus-some-facts#.VKP-gysa-gw.
Preston, I. (2014), 'The effect of immigration on public
finances', 5 November, VOX EU: http://www.voxeu.org/article/
immigration-and-public-finances.
Rolfe, H. and Hudson-Sharp, N. (2016), The Impact of Free Movement
on the Labour Market: Case Studies of Hospitality, Food Processing and
Construction, London: NIESR.
Ruhs, M. and Martin, P. (2008), 'Numbers vs. rights:
trade-offs and guest worker programs', International Migration
Review, 42(I), pp. 249-65.
SQW(20I0), Immigration and Employers' Incentives and
Behaviour, Report to Migration Advisory Committee (MAC).
Varga, J. and in't Veld, J. (2014), The potential growth
impact of structural reforms in the EU. A benchmarking exercise,
European Economy Economic Papers 541, available at http://ec.europa.
eu/economy_finance/publications/economic_paper/2014/pdf/ ecp539_en.pdf.
Vasilopoulou, S. (2016), 'Explaining UK euroscepticism:
freedom of movement, employment, welfare and the UK referendum',
University of York, Political Quarterly (forthcoming).
Venables, A.J. (1999), 'Trade liberalization and factor
mobility: an overview', in Faini, R.C., de Melo, J. and Zimmermann,
K. (eds), Migration: The Controversies and the Evidence, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, pp. 23-48.
Wadsworth, J. and Vaitilingam, R. (2015), Immigration, the European
Union and the UK Labour Market, LSE, CEP Policy Analysis, available at
http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/pa015.pdf.
Jonathan Portes, National Institute of Economic and Social
Research. E-mail:
[email protected]. This paper draws heavily on
Rolfe and Hudson-Sharp (2016, forthcoming). I am grateful to Heather
Rolfe (NIESR) and Catherine Barnard (University of Cambridge) for
helpful comments. Funding in support of this research was provided by
the ESRC's UK in a Changing Europe programme, of which the author
is a Senior Fellow.