EU membership, financial services and stability.
Armstrong, Angus
This paper examines whether EU membership enhances or diminishes
the UK's financial sector stability, and therefore its prominence
in global finance. The UK is host to the largest share of financial
services in the EU, despite being outside of the Eurozone. An important
reason is that, as a member of the EU, the UK has direct access to the
Eurozone's financial infrastructure. If the UK leaves the EU (and
EEA) banks and other financial services firms may continue to have
access to the Single Market, but they are unlikely to have direct access
to the Eurozone's infrastructure. Banks in the UK will no longer be
direct members the Eurozone's payments system. The swap arrangement
between the European Central Bank and Bank of England would have no
legal enforcement mechanism. Resolution of cross-border banks would be
more challenging with less incentive for a cooperative outcome. While
some may welcome the reduced size of the financial system, not without
reason, this could be achieved more effectively with domestic regulation
than by leaving the EU. Given the uncertainty that would follow a vote
to leave, there is a risk of capital flight.
Keywords: governance: financial infrastructure
JEL Classifications: E52; E58; F33; F36; G00; G001
"Respecting the powers of the central bank in the performance
of their tasks, including the provision of central bank liquidity within
their respective jurisdictions"
From the Agreement of the European Council Meeting, 18 and 19
February, 2016
The UK joined the European Economic Community in 1973, the same
year as the collapse of Bretton Woods. This was a system of closed
capital accounts and fixed exchange rates designed to overcome the
financial instability of the interwar years.
The demise of Bretton Woods led to a gradual opening up of capital
accounts. The UK led the way in 1979 by abolishing exchange controls. In
the same year, other members of the EEC created the European Exchange
Rate Mechanism of pegged exchange rates from the remains of the
'Snake in the Tunnel' system. Despite the movement of capital
being a fundamental freedom in the Treaty of the Functioning of the
European Union (TFEU, 1958) progress was slow due to excess capacity in
many countries and the new pegged exchange rate regime. The rise of
cross-border capital flows coincided with a revolution in IT that
transformed financial intermediation. Batch processing allowed bank
assets, long considered unsuitable for transfer, to be bundled up and
traded. International financial borders were torn down, enabling
financial institutions to merge into conglomerates operating around the
globe. The regulatory framework was designed in such a way as to support
financial sector growth. (1)
Continental Europe began to catch up. EU leaders either recognised
the need for more efficient financial markets, or accepted that they
could no longer defend domestic financial behemoths. Europe's
largest banks made strategic decisions to become global players. (2) The
EU Financial Services Action Plan (1998) accelerated the creation of a
single wholesale market allowing regulated financial firms of any Member
State to operate in the markets of any other Member State without any
further restrictions (so-called 'passporting'). (3)
With repeated financial crises culminating in the global financial
crisis, it is clear that global finance is a challenge to traditional
governance structures. (4) Lord King's famous remark that banks are
"global in life and national in death" indicates a profound
misalignment between incentives and responsibility. The lack of
congruence in traditional governance structures is expressed in many
ways e.g., Rodrik (2000), Schoenmaker (2013) and Avdjiev et al. (2015).
The common thread is an inconsistency between internationalism and
the policy domain of nation-states.
In the financial context, this inconsistency is between the global
financial institutions operating in multiple jurisdictions and with
multiple currencies, and the domestic governments which stand behind
them with their taxpayers' funds and domestic currencies. Our exam
question is therefore whether EU membership, and access to the
Eurozone's financial infrastructure, makes this global financial
governance problem more or less congruent with our nation state.
UK financial services
The UK, and the City of London in particular, has been a leading
financial centre for two centuries. Finance is one of the UK's most
important areas of economic activity. The Office of National Statistics
estimates that financial sector output is 8 per cent of national output,
although others suggest if relevant business services are included this
would be 12 per cent of output. (5) The UK is by far the largest net
exporter of financial services in the world with a trade surplus of over
3 per cent of GDP. (6) HM Government (2014) reports that financial
services contributed 12 per cent to PAYE Income Tax and 15 per cent to
corporation tax receipts in 2012-13. The distinguishing features of the
UK finance system are that it is: (a) large; (b) international, a
conduit for other EU nations; (c) multi-currency; and, (d) in large part
funded by foreign direct investment.
The first defining feature of UK finance is that the sector is big
with a wide variety of services provided. Table 1 shows the size of the
financial services on a residency basis (i.e. operating within the
national border) relative to national output. (7) Derivatives are
excluded. Banking is roughly split between domestic and foreign-owned
institutions. On a national basis, UK banking sector assets, including
overseas operations, are approximately 450 per cent of GDP. Stability of
domestic institutions matters for the national public sector balance
sheet. This is an important distinction between the UK and Luxembourg
that has a large but almost entirely foreign owned banking system. (8)
The diversity of financial services indicates that not all specialities
will be equally influenced by EU membership.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The second defining feature of UK finance is the large presence of
overseas firms. According to the Bank of England (2015), around half of
the world's largest financial firms, commercial and investment
banks, insurers, asset managers and hedge funds have their European
headquarters in the UK. The City has the largest share of EU investment
banking, wholesale finance, insurance, asset management and hedge funds
despite being outside of the Eurozone. (9) Having
'passporting' rights to the Single Market and access to the
financial infrastructure of the Eurozone is vital to hosting Euro
financial markets.
With so many international firms, the UK banking system is a
multi-currency area. This matters for the governance issues raised in
section 1. Panel (a) in figure 1 shows that less than half of UK banking
system assets are denominated in sterling. (10) Around 28 per cent of
assets are denominated in dollars and 20 per cent in euros. Yet panel
(b) shows that a greater proportion of loans and advances to UK
residents are from European banks compared to US and banks from other
nations. This suggests that the UK is a conduit for non-EEA firms
(especially from the US) carrying out banking in the rest of the EU via
the 'passporting' arrangement. (11)
The fourth defining feature is the amount of foreign direct
investment (FDI) related to the financial sector. Delivering financial
services usually requires a physical presence or ownership of a local
company. This implies a large amount of FDI in financial services. The
UK is the second largest hub (inward and outward) of FDI in the world
and by far the largest in the EU. Of the 937bn [pounds sterling] stock
of FDI in the UK in 2012, 43 per cent is from the EU and 40 per cent of
the total is related to financial services. (12) According to Ernst
& Young, 72 per cent of foreign investors consider access to the
Single Market as most important to the UK's attractiveness as a
destination for FDI. (13) FDI is traditionally seen as a committed form
of foreign capital. An important question is whether this is still true
today.
EU membership and governance
International financial regulation is guided by G20, the Financial
Stability Board and Global Standard Setting Bodies. This is an
appropriate governance structure, given the global nature of finance.
Representatives from the UK are influential voices in these
institutions. The implementation of the guidelines to the Single Market
is the responsibility of the European Commission (EC). Before the crisis
the EC issued directives about opening markets, setting minimum
regulatory standards, mutual recognition and consumer protection. After
the crisis the EC has relied increasingly on regulations which apply
directly to Member States and provisions for maximum harmonisation of
regulations across the EU. Some regulations are seen as intrusive and
inappropriate. (14)
The decision to establish a European Banking Union (EBU) will have
profound implications for the whole of the EU. The scope of the EBU is
well beyond anything which has been achieved between sovereign states in
the past. The UK was one of its strongest proponents as a means of
resolving the underlying tensions of the Eurozone crisis. However, there
is a clear concern that to deliver the EBU involves ever greater
integration. Financial regulation may be cast in the interests of
members of the EBU and not be in the interests of Member States outside
of the EU.
Since the UK has such a large financial sector, this is important
to our economic sovereignty. Moreover, because the Eurozone countries
have a qualified majority at the Council of Ministers they can, in
theory, caucus or act as a block or pass legislation in the group's
interest. (15) Prime Minister Cameron's renegotiation goes some way
to allay these fears. First, it reinforces the principle of
non-discrimination on the basis of currency. The UK has challenged three
areas of financial regulation before the European Court of Justice (ECJ)
and has had some important successes. (16) Second, the UK is permitted
to be a non-voting member of the Eurogroup and raise matters of serious
concern to the Council. However, there is no full answer to the threat
of caucusing by Eurozone nations. Further concessions to protect British
interests would come to be more like a veto as more Member States join
the EBU. (17)
Regulatory sovereignty
The important issue for the referendum is whether the UK would gain
more regulatory control by leaving the EU. Assuming that the UK intends
to continue as the hub of Eurozone finance, pursuing a separate
regulatory agenda is unlikely to be permitted and would undermine
financial stability. First, if the UK is to have access to the Single
Market for financial services it must be accepted as
'equivalent' in regulation terms. This judgement is in the
gift of the EU. Second, the UK would have no direct say in future EU
regulations. Third, there is limited scope for regulatory discretion for
any international financial centre. Shoenmaker (2013) shows that if
institutions operate across borders, regulatory decisions at a national
level tend to have spillovers to other nations creating potential
instability. (18)
Loss of access to the Single Market for financial services would be
problematic. If the UK leaves the EU and does not join the EEA (an
inferior outcome for the EU and the UK) then from a regulatory
perspective the UK would be a 'third country'. The UK could be
granted access to EU markets if its regulatory regime is considered
equivalent. Firms which sell to retail markets in Member States would be
required to establish an entity in each market. Firms which sell to
professional investors may be permitted if they are equivalent and
registered with the European Securities and Markets Authority. Banks
must also meet equivalence criteria of the Capital Requirements
Directive. Whether this proves to be a stable equilibrium over time
depends on whether the EU would seek 'line by line'
equivalence. Loss of access to the ECJ would make it difficult to appeal
any contentious ruling.
Because of the regulatory 'sword of Damocles' over market
access, non-EU financial institutions located in the UK are likely to
establish a subsidiary in a Member State of the rest of the EU. They
could then set up branches from that new subsidiary. As well adding to,
rather than reducing, their regulatory burden, the risk is that the UK
subsidiary becomes less important. EU banks operating in the UK may also
seek to establish a subsidiary if the UK leaves the EU. Because
subsidiaries in the UK are individually capitalised and do not allow
consolidated internal cash management they are a more expensive form of
banking. And the UK would have gained little, if any, regulatory
sovereignty.
EU membership and financial infrastructure
A necessary ingredient for stability is to make sure that the
financial infrastructure operates smoothly, in particular, that the
payments and settlements systems function efficiently at all times so
that non-cash transactions are settled promptly and with full
confidence. It is the threat of disruption to the financial
infrastructure which often forces a government's hand to intervene
to prop up failing firms.
Payments system
The payments system for the Eurozone is TARGET2. (19) The
Eurosystem operates as a 'hub-and-spoke' structure with the
ECB as the hub and Eurozone national central banks (NCBs) as the spokes.
(20) Commercial banks facilitate cross-border payments on behalf of
clients by registering debits and credits at their respective NCB. At
the end of each day the net amount is reported to the ECB and the
NCB's reserve account is adjusted accordingly.
A unique feature of TARGET2 is that participants are not always
nations in the Eurosystem. NCBs, banks and designated financial
institutions within the EEA are invited to join TARGET2 even if they are
not in the Eurozone. However, the risk to the Eurosystem is tightly
controlled as intraday day credit is usually limited for each
counterparty and there is no access to overnight credit for NCBs outside
the Eurosystem. The Bank of England (and NCBs of all nine non-Eurozone
countries) is a shareholder of the ECB but has declined to be a member
of TARGET2. (21)
Given the amount of euro-denominated finance carried out in the UK,
which must be settled and cleared each day, access to a reliable payment
services is critical. UK banks and other designated financial
institutions are permitted to be direct participants in TARGET2 even
though the Bank of England does not participate. Where there are
imbalances, they often use the NCB of a Eurozone Member State. For
example, Lloyds Bank London is reported to hold its euro reserves
account with the Dutch Central Bank. (22) Any use of central bank
finance is provided against collateral delivered by the Lloyds local
office.
How would this change if the UK were to leave the EU? If the UK
were to join the EEA there is no technical difference in access to
TARGET2. If the UK were to leave the EU and not join the EEA then banks
in the UK could no longer be direct members of TARGET2. They would have
to operate through subsidiaries (or perhaps branches assuming the UK is
deemed 'equivalent' in terms of regulation) within the EEA.
This would make euro banking via the UK more expensive. It would also
erode the attraction of the UK as a destination for non-EU institutions
to establish their EU headquarters. It would also be unusual to extend
direct access to institutions in countries outside the legal
jurisdiction of the EU.
Central counterparties
Another important part of financial infrastructure is central
counterparties (CCPs). In response to the global financial crisis, G20
committed to standardising derivatives and moving trading from opaque
over-the-counter bilateral transactions to CCPs. An example is shown in
figure 2. The idea is that the CCP is 'buyer to every seller and
seller to every buyer': they stand between all counterparties. This
creates greater transparency, security and enhances risk management. The
figure shows how complex webs of bilateral transactions can be greatly
simplified by a CCP. Each counterparty is required to post collateral at
the CCP. In 2015 the value of pre-placed margin and default funds for
the four CCPs supervised by the Bank of England was 91 bn [pounds
sterling]. (23) While CCPs may seem a highly technical part of the
underpinning infrastructure of the financial system, there is no doubt
about the importance they play to London. The UK is the global centre of
derivatives and securities trading. These activities complement
international banking activities. Over half of interest rate derivatives
(the largest asset class) and one third of credit derivative are traded
on CCPs. However, the more that trade is concentrated on CCPs the more
they become systemically important financial institutions. CCPs in the
UK have access to the Sterling Monetary Framework including Discount
Window Facilities. In the Eurozone CCPs have access to TARGET2.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
A critical issue known as 'Location Policy' emerged as a
result of the ECB's Eurosystem Oversight Policy Framework.
According to the ECB Article 127 (2) of TFEU, one of the functions of
the Eurosystem is to "promote the smooth operation of payment
systems" and the means by which this is assigned is specified in
Article 22 of the Statute of the European System of Central Banks and
the ECB: "the ECB and NCBs may provide facilities, and the ECB may
make regulations, to ensure efficient and sound clearing and payment
systems within the Union and with other countries". (24) As it is
acknowledged that CCPs can be a source of systemic risk, as focal points
for credit and liquidity risk, an important question is where they
should be geographically located.
The quotation at the start of this paper suggests that if CCPs may
require euro liquidity, which is exclusively in the gift of the ECB,
they should be located in the jurisdiction of the Eurosystem. Indeed,
the ECB stated that CCPs with more than 5bn [euro] daily net credit
exposure (in euros) per main product would be located within the
Eurosystem jurisdiction. This is consistent with aligning the functions
of the state, central bank and currency discussed in section 1. However,
the UK requested a judicial review by the European Court of Justice
(Case T-49611). The court annulled the ECB's policy on the basis
that the TFEU granted competence for payment systems and not CCPs.
Swaps and incomplete contracts
How this issue was resolved is important for the EU referendum. The
Bank of England and ECB agreed to joint oversight of CCPs and reciprocal
currency swaps to facilitate multi-currency liquidity support. (25) This
extends the existing swap agreements between the Federal Reserve and
five major central banks. (26) Note that this is not a pre-commitment
and there is no notion of amount. (27) However, Prime Minister Cameron
re-affirmed the soundness of this liquidity support by negotiating a
'no discrimination' for Member States which do not use the
euro in an important clause in the European Council Agreement in
February 2016.
If the UK leaves the EU it would no longer be a shareholder of the
ECB, it would not have access to the ECJ and the principle of 'no
discrimination' would not come into force. It is difficult to see
why the ECB would be interested in renewing an arrangement it had not
wanted in the first place. In the words of Former Governor Noyer of the
Banque de France, "if Britain left the EU, the Euro Area
authorities could no longer tolerate such a high proportion of financial
activities involving their currency taking place abroad". (28)
Why should the ECB object to the swap agreement if the UK were to
leave the EU? The Fed maintains swap lines with other nations, but they
do not have anything like one-third of the US dollar wholesale markets.
The size of currency injections could complicate the euro reserves
market and obstruct the setting of monetary policy. It is therefore
unlikely that a major central bank would permit a swap line to support
such a volume of transactions to take place offshore and outside the
legal jurisdiction of the EU.
Even if the ECB were to commit to maintaining a swap line, there is
no way to commit credibly to the agreement. In a crisis the optimal
response by the ECB may be to act in the interests of EU citizens.
Outside of the EU the UK would have no capacity to call for a review.
Issues about the interpretation and application of the TFEU are outside
the jurisdiction of the EFTA Court (the Court of the EEA) and a
Memorandum of Understanding has no basis in international law. Large
financial institutions which may require access to emergency liquidity
will be aware of the legal uncertainty around this ongoing support.
EU membership and resolution
While a large and international financial system can bring economic
rewards, it also carries risks if there are failures. Chancellor Osborne
describes this as the 'British dilemma', where we enjoy the
benefits of the largest global financial centre but the inherent risks
are too big for our relatively small tax base. The dilemma is sharper
today given our high level of public debt and limited capacity for
future support.
Whatever cooperation agreements may exist between governments to
cooperate in resolving cross-border institutions, history shows that
they act in their taxpayers' interests, often irrespective of the
spillover to other countries. For example, even among founding members
of the Eurozone, cooperation proved lacking in the Fortis Bank failure,
whose losses were finally divided according to national boundaries. (29)
The obvious way to resolve this incongruence is to remove the
dependence on national taxpayers. In 2009 the G20 set out a requirement
to reform financial regulation, including new resolution regimes which
would allow institutions to fail without disrupting key economic
functions and without recourse to taxpayers. The UK introduced its
Special Resolution Regime (SRR) in 2009, which has been enhanced by
transposing the EU-wide Bank Resolution and Recovery Directive (BRRD).
(30) The SRR covers UK incorporated banks, building societies,
subsidiaries of foreign firms, some investment firms and central
counterparties. Branches of foreign firms may be resolved under the UK
regime in some circumstances, although the UK government is currently
consulting on this issue.
The UK's resolution authority is the Bank of England's
Prudential Regulatory Authority (PRA). The PRA has the authority to
write-down existing equity or convert ('bailin') existing
unsecured debt into equity to re-capitalise an ongoing firm or cover
losses in a failed firm. Of course, bail-in implies a loss for the asset
holders. Given the size of UK financial institutions, it is important
that shareholders and unsecured creditors are geographically spread
otherwise the losses would simply be passed within the economy. The key
assumption is that contagion from 'bail-in' is less than from
'bail-out'.
If 'bail-in' proves ineffective in a systemic event, or
there are residual losses, then the UK taxpayer remains the fiscal
backstop. If in the next systemic crisis 'bail-in' is at least
partially successful, then this will reduce the losses facing the
taxpayer. In a systemic event it would be highly improbable the
government balance sheet would be unused. (31) Therefore, the
'British Dilemma' may, in fact, be unresolved.
Resolution and coordination
Eurozone countries and other Member States which choose to join the
Banking Union implement the BRRD through the Single Resolution Mechanism
(SRM) for significant and cross-border banks. This has two advantages.
First, the SRM, while a complex decision process, requires that
resolution decisions are taken with regard to all participants and not
national lines and has a non-discrimination requirement. This in theory
removes the risk of inefficient spillovers from the national resolution
of cross-border banks. Second, a pre-financed Single Resolution Fund
(SRF) will be created to mutualise any residual losses. This
risk-sharing mechanism is designed to reduce transferring from large
failed banks to the sovereign. This in principle is an attractive
solution to the 'British Dilemma'.
This raises the question of whether the UK should join the Banking
Union. Denmark, the only other EU nation along with the UK to have a
permanent opt-out of the Eurozone, has signalled its intention to join.
This involves transferring responsibility for financial regulation of
most large UK institutions from the Bank to the ECB under the Single
Supervisory Mechanism. This would entail some loss of discretion over
macro and micro-prudential policy. Moreover, the UK would not be able to
join the Governing Council which is the highest decision making
authority of the ECB. This would be a large transfer of power without
the UK having a seat at the decision table.
Resolution of large EU-wide institutions would require close
cooperation between the ECB and the Bank of England. Each institution
would be representing their own constituents. There may be disagreements
about the optimal approach and ultimately loss sharing. However, within
the EU it is reasonable to expect the ECB and UK authorities would have
a more collegiate relationship. Moreover, the UK would have the right of
access to the ECJ to challenge any perceived discriminatory behaviour on
the basis of currency. Being inside the EU does not solve the
'British Dilemma' but it may make any loss sharing more
equitable.
Capital flight
The question set at the start of this paper is whether EU
membership strengthens or diminishes financial stability and therefore
enhances the UK's role as a global financial centre. If the UK
leaves the EU (and does not join the EEA) it is likely that it will no
longer have direct access to the EU's financial infrastructure.
This will erode prospects for financial stability and diminish the
UK's current status as the global financial centre.
Well functioning financial markets are public goods: the benefits
extend well beyond the home nation. In the event of a decision to leave
the EU, we expect this would be recognised by UK and rest of the EU
negotiators. Rather than reaching for the 'mutually assured
destruction' button, negotiators have every incentive to maintain
the status quo as far as possible. This means that the UK would
transpose and adopt EU regulation with no meaningful gain in
'regulatory sovereignty'. The EU would reciprocate by
accepting UK regulations as equivalent and permit full
'passporting' to the Single Market. Whether this is a stable
equilibrium is an open question.
The UK would be likely to lose access to the EU's financial
infrastructure. This is always the responsibility of the central bank.
The quotation at the start of this paper (repeated in Governor
Carney's evidence to the Treasury Select Committee) clearly
respects the legal authority of central banks. UK incorporated banks
would require a branch in the EU, and non-EU banks resident in the UK
would require an EU subsidiary. CCPs are also likely to migrate. Any
replacement swap agreement would have no legal basis and therefore be of
uncertain value. (32) Finally, the UK would no longer be a shareholder
or member of the ECB. This may reduce the incentive for cooperation in
the event of resolving a substantial cross-border financial institution.
Some financial institutions are likely to move elsewhere in the EU.
This is a form of capital flight, although it is difficult to judge as
there are no EU cities with a similar expertise and support in financial
services. The outcome is likely to be less efficient intermediation and
a higher cost of capital. Bank of England Governor Carney has suggested
that the referendum poses a risk to domestic financial stability. (33)
There are a number of factors which suggest that this is indeed a risk.
First, there is uncertainty around the financial arrangements in the
event of a vote to leave the EU. Both sides may like to maintain the
status quo, but this will be complicated by legal and political
uncertainty. Second, the UK has a current account deficit of almost 7
per cent of GDP even with a healthy surplus in financial services trade.
Third, the stock of FDI in the UK related to the financial sector is
likely to be near [pounds sterling]250bn. (34) Uncertainty over
financial services may make funding of the current account deficit more
challenging.
NOTES
(1) The original Basle capital regulations were essentially an
instrument of industrial policy designed to slow down the growth of
Japanese banks.
(2) For example, the attempted takeover by Pirelli, advised by
Goldman Sachs, of Continental AG encouraged Deutsche Bank to become a
global investment bank.
(3) The Single European Act (1986) was also key to the creation of
a Single Market.
(4) Jorda et al. (2011) present a dataset of banking crises for the
fourteen wealthiest nations. Between 1950 and 1980 there were two crises
and between 1980 and 2008 there were seventeen crises.
(5) TheCityUK (2016).
(6) UNCTAD database and ONS Pink Book.
(7) These measures exclude interbank assets and liabilities so
avoids double counting.
(8) This was discussed at an LSE roundtable (Schelkle and Lokdam,
2015). Unlike Luxembourg, the UK has a large domestic banking system. As
long as the government may act as a backstop, the state must supervise
and be the lender of last resort. Transferring oversight and decision
making for such a large contingent liability would be a considerable
diminution of sovereign power.
(9) See TheCityUK (2016).
(10) MFIs are banks and non-bank financial institutions excluding
the central bank.
(11) In 2014 there were 348 banking companies in the UK; 248 are
incorporated overseas, of which 170 are from outside of the European
Economic Area (EEA).
(12) OECD.stat FDI series https://stats.oecd.org.
(13) Reported in Bank of England (2015).
(14) For example, the Bank of England willl not extend the
application of the EU's bonus cap to smaller companies, and the
Alternative Investment Fund Managers Directive (AIFMD) is widely thought
to introduce unnecessary regulations on hedge funds.
(15) The European Financial Stability Mechanism (which the UK
contributes to) was used to make an urgent loan to Greece despite an
earlier decision not to use the fund to support Eurozone countries.
(16) These are over the location of CCPs (upheld), bankers bonuses
(rejected) and a financial transaction tax (postponed).
(17) The UK has a 'double-lock' on voting at the European
Banking Authority. This requires a majority of both Eurozone and
non-Eurozone members to agree a decision.
(18) An exception is tighter rules on domestic markets such as
property.
(19) Second generation of Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross
settlement Express Transfer system.
(20) The Eurosystem is both the ECB and Eurozone NCBs.
(21) While the Bank has the third largest shareholding of the ECB
in notional terms, the paid-up capital is much smaller and covers only
operating costs.
(22) See Jones (2014).
(23) Bank of England (2016), Supervision of Financial Market
Infrastructure Report. The four CCPs supervised by the Bank are CH
Clearnet Ltd, ICE Clear Europe, LME Clear and CME Clearing Europe.
(24) Quotes from the TFEU and Eurosystem Statutes are from ECB
(2011).
(25) Swap agreements are necessary for long dated securities,
otherwise central banks could use the spot market.
(26) The big-6 of the international monetary system are the Federal
Reserve, Bank of Japan, Bank of England, European Central Bank, Bank of
Canada and Swiss National Bank.
(27) Pre-commitment would violate sovereign control of a central
bank.
(28) See Noyer (2016).
(29) See for example Schoenmaker (2013). Another example of closure
of a globally integrated bank having cross-border consequences is Lehman
Brothers. Immediately before filing for bankruptcy its global cash
management system withdrew cash from its systemically important branch
in London which then had to close on the same day.
(30) EU Directives set out the end result that each Member State
must adhere to, but the national authority has discretion over how this
is achieved.
(31) In the last crisis the largest direct intervention was the
Treasury's Asset Protection Scheme negotiated in February 2009 and
the nadir of the crisis. This 'insured' UK banks against
tail-risk on certain hard to price assets. The initial insurance cover
was around [pounds sterling]250bn of market value assets.
(32) The Bank of England famously had a swap agreement with the
Bundesbank which failed so spectacularly in 1992.
(33) Evidence to Treasury Select Committee 8th March, 2016.
(34) The stock of EU FDI in the UK is [pounds sterling]469bn and 30
per cent of recent flow is in the financial sector.
REFERENCES
Avdjiev, S., McCauley, R. and Shin, H. (2015), 'Breaking free
of the triple coincidence in international finance', BIS Working
Papers No 524.
Bank of England (2015), EU Membership and the Bank of England,
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/
speeches/2015/euboe211015.pdf.
--Resolution Framework, http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/
financialstability/Pages/role/risk_reduction/srr/framework.aspx.
Burrows, O. and Low, K. (2015), 'Mapping the UK financial
system'. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Q2.
European Central Bank (2011), Eurosysem Oversight Policy Framework,
http://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/
eurosystemoversightpolicyframework2011 en.pdf.
HM Government (2014), Review of the Balance of Competences between
the United Kingdom and the European Union: The Single Market: Financial
Services and the Free Movement of Capital.
Jones, R. (2014), 'Who said payment systems are simple?',
European Banking Federation, http://enews.ebf-fbe.eu/2014/01
/who-saidpayment-systems-are-simple-legal-issues-arising-from-the-
structure-of-target-2/.
Jorda, O., Schularick, M. and Taylor, A. (2011), 'Financial
crises, credit booms, and external imbalances: 140 years of
lessons', IMF Economic Review, 59, 2, pp. 340-78.
Noyer, C. (2016), Benefits of Britain's Membership, OMFIF, The
Bulletin, http://www.omfif.org/analysis/commentary/2016/march/
benefits-of-britains-membership/.
Rodrik, D (2000), 'How far will international economic
integration go?', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), pp.
177-86.
Schelkle, W. and Lokdam, H. (Rapporteurs) (2015), 'Financial
regulation and the protection of eurozone outs', London School of
Economics.
Schoenmaker, D. (201 3), Governance of International Banking,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
TheCityUK (2016), A Practioner's guide to Brexit, www.thecityu
k.com.
Angus Armstrong, National Institute of Economic and Social Research
and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail:
[email protected].
Table 1. UK financial sector by residency (2014)
[pounds per
sterling] bn cent of GDP
UK banks 3,631 200
Foreign banks 3,374 186
Finance companies and SPVs 480 26
Pension funds 1,430 79
Insurance 1,830 101
Unit, investment trusts and ETFs 880 48
Hedge funds & private equity 760 42
12,385 682
Source: Table B1 Bank Stats and Burrows and Low (2015).