Power and Economic Institutions: Reinterpretations in Economic History.
McCandless, Amy Thompson
Power and Economic Institutions raises numerous questions about the
assumptions of economic behavior and change made by neoclassical economists. The eight essays in the volume, revised versions of
conference papers presented at the 1986 Swedish Collegium for Advanced
Study in the Social Sciences, focus on the ways in which power
relationships and economic institutions shape economic thought and
action. The authors reject what they see as "a rationalistic and
utilitarian tradition within political economics . . . to model economic
behavior and change as an historical and deductive science based upon
abstract individuals maximizing utility under constraints" |p. 4~.
Bo Gustafsson, the editor of the volume, is a professor in economic
history at Uppsala University and director of the Swedish Collegium for
Advanced Study in the Social Sciences. The other contributors include
two of Gustafsson's colleagues at Uppsala and professors in
economics and economic history from India, England, and the United
States. Although Gustafsson's introduction provides a historical
framework for the economic theories discussed in the essays, the volume
lacks the thematic continuity and developmental organization of a
monograph.
The essay by Stephen A. Marglin, a professor of economics at Harvard
University, is the strongest piece of the eight. Marglin's chapter,
entitled
"Understanding Capitalism: Control versus Efficiency,"
compares the views of "mainstream" and "radical"
economists on various aspects of economic development. Because most of
the other contributors cite Marglin's work, this probably should
have been the lead essay.
Marglin makes no attempt to hide his bias. Unlike the mainstream
economists whom he criticizes, he does not believe that economics is
"a neutral, value-free science with eternal truths." He argues
that class is a much better unit of analysis than household and that the
workplace "operates by command rather than through markets"
|p. 228~. "Capitalism," he writes, "inherently tends to
appropriate control of process and product to the capitalist; and, by so
doing, denies meaningful and satisfying work to the typical worker"
|p. 233~. Although mainstream economists attribute the growth of the
factory system to its efficiency as a means of production, Marglin
believes that capitalists preferred factory organization to the putting
out system because it gave them far more control over their work force.
Despite his criticisms of capitalism, Marglin is not so naive to
think that the liberation of the workplace will naturally follow the
abolition of capitalism: "the commissar," he notes, "is
no less formidable an obstacle to workers' control than is the
capitalist" |p. 250~. He shares the view of other radical
economists that human liberation will only come when the
"participatory principles" of Western political democracy are
extended to the economy |p. 229~.
The other essays in the volume examine power and economic
relationships on a smaller scale than Marglin. Amit Bhaduri, an Indian
economist, considers the importance of class power relations to
understanding economic organization in traditional agricultural
societies. Bo Gustafsson looks at the ways in which medieval craft
guilds create functional markets for their membership. Stefano Fenoaltea
criticizes the "Whig" view of the scattered strip farming used
in Europe before the Industrial Revolution.
The most provocative piece is probably that by William Lazonick on
"Organizations and Markets in Capitalist Development."
Lazonick, a professor of economic history at Barnard College, Columbia
University, believes that the best remedy for the ailing British and
American economies is not a "return to unfettered
individualism" but rather the development of a "collective
capitalism" whereby "business enterprises use organizations
rather than markets to coordinate economic activities within
enterprises" |p. 253~. Organizational coordination, Lazonick notes,
has been the key to the Japanese domination of the international market.
"By supporting the development of educational institutions,
financial systems, communications networks and public sector research
and development organizations," the American and British
governments could similarly create more competitive, corporate forms of
business enterprise |p. 296~.
Power and Economic Institutions provides an interesting summary of
the literature on economic behavior and change for the undergraduate
studying for comprehensive examinations or for the graduate preparing
for preliminary examinations. Most professors will find its focus too
narrow to use as a supplemental reading in a course in economics or
economic history. Despite revisions and editing, the essays still read
like the conference papers they were, and seventy dollars is a lot of
money to pay for a conference proceedings!