The real exchange rate under various systems of international capital taxation.
Hatzipanayotou, Panos
I. Introduction
International organizations, such as the Organization for Economic
Co-Operation and Development (OECD) and the European Community (EC),
have promoted, to varying degrees, the liberalization of capital
movements among their member countries.(1) The "Code of
Liberalization of Capital Movements," an agreement drawn in 1982 by
the OECD, sets different degrees of capital liberalization among its
member countries, depending on the nature of capital transactions (e.g.,
direct or portfolio investment). The Treaty of Rome (1957) recommended,
among other things, the liberalization of capital movements among the EC
countries (Chapter IV, articles 67-72). By and large, capital movements
in the EC have been liberalized since 1990. The remaining restrictions
in the capital markets of some member countries, such as Greece,
Ireland, Portugal, and Spain, were to be eliminated by the end of
1992.(2) These developments in the world capital markets have prompted a
renewed interest among trade theorists regarding the response of key
economic variables (e.g., national income, employment and welfare) to
the liberalization of capital movements.
With capital becoming more mobile internationally, capital flows in a
country depend, among other things, on the domestic and the foreign
capital tax rate, and on the prevailing system of taxing net repatriated
capital earnings in the capital-exporting countries. Frequently,
capital-exporting countries tax the net repatriated capital earnings
according to a system (i) of tax credits, under which tax payments by
foreign capital invested in a capital-importing country are credited
toward its tax liability to the source capital-exporting country,(3)
(ii) of tax deductions, under which payments by foreign capital invested
in a capital-importing country are deducted as a cost in calculating its
tax liability to the source capital-exporting country, and (iii) of
untaxed repatriated net capital earnings by the capital-exporting
country. Recently, Bond and Samuelson |4~ using a game theoretic
approach in a one-commodity two-country model, examine the welfare
effects of capital taxes under a system of capital tax credits and of
capital tax deductions. Slemrod |17~ using aggregate data from seven
countries (i.e., Canada, France, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, the U.K., and the U.S.) examines how the U.S. tax system in conjunction with
the tax system of a capital-exporting country affects the FDI in the
U.S. Slemrod's results support a negative relationship between
effective U.S. capital tax rates and FDI into the U.S. Disaggregating
the data by capital-exporting country, he does not find systematic
differences in the responsiveness of FDI, with respect to changes in
U.S. tax rates, from capital-exporting countries with a tax credit
system (i.e., Italy, Japan, and the U.K.), and the remaining
capital-exporting countries with a system of untaxed repatriated capital
earnings.(4) Hatzipanayotou and Michael |11~ in a model of a small
capital-importing and a small capital-exporting country, assuming free
trade and variable labor supply due to endogenous supply adjustments
examine, among other things, the employment and welfare effects of
capital taxes under a system of capital tax credits, tax deductions, and
untaxed repatriated net capital earnings.
The response of another key variable, the real exchange rate, to the
liberalization of capital movements is yet to be examined in a trade
theoretic context, despite its important analytical and policy
implications. Trade theoretic studies of the real exchange rate,
ignoring international capital mobility, have primarily examined its
response to trade restrictions (e.g., a higher tariff), and to exogenous shocks (e.g., income transfers, and an improvement in the terms of
trade). In the context of a small open economy, it has been concluded
that a higher tariff or an improvement in the terms of trade leads to a
real exchange rate appreciation |2; 6; 7; 13~.(5) Recent studies,
however, have shown that these conventional results may not necessarily
hold in more general models, such as the three-good (exported, imported
and nontraded goods) two-factor Heckscher-Ohlin model, or the three-good
specific factor model |5; 8~.(6) In such general models (e.g., the
three-good specific factor model), the higher tariff exerts two effects,
which work in opposite directions, on the real exchange rate. A
substitution effect, due to the induced production and consumption
distortions, and an income effect whenever the initial tariff is
non-zero. As a result, whether a higher tariff leads to a real exchange
rate appreciation or depreciation depends, among other things, on the
relative size of these two effects.
This paper examines the real exchange rate effect of liberalizing
capital movements, through reduced capital taxes under the three
alternative systems of taxing repatriated capital earnings, for a small
capital-importing and a small capital-exporting country. Two results
emerge from the present analysis. First, whether liberalization of
capital movements affects the real exchange rate depends on whether the
country is a net capital-exporter or a net capital-importer, and on the
prevailing capital tax system. Second, when changes in capital taxes
affect the real exchange rate, it is, as in the case of a higher tariff,
via a substitution and an income effect. But, contrary to the case of a
higher tariff, the substitution effect is only due to a production
distortion, while the income effect is due to changes in capital tax
revenue that is distributed to households as a lump-sum. The analysis
also stresses under which tax systems the real exchange rate effect of a
higher capital tax depends, among other things, on the foreign capital
tax rate.
Section II examines the real exchange rate effect of liberalizing
capital movements under the three alternative tax systems for a small
capital-importing country, and section III for a small capital-exporting
country. The last section offers some concluding remarks.
II. A Model of a Small Capital-importing Country
Consider a small capital-importing country that produces many traded
and nontraded goods, using an internationally mobile factor of
production, capital, and some nontraded factors. The country's
endowment of capital and of the nontraded factors are fixed. Commodity
trade is free and the domestic prices of the traded goods, which equal
the world prices, are given by the vector p. The relative prices of the
nontraded goods, given by the vector q, are endogenously determined in
order to equate domestic demand and supply of the nontraded goods.
Let r and r* denote the domestic and world rate of return to capital.
Similarly, positive (negative) values for |Rho~ and |Rho~* denote the
capital tax (subsidy) by the home capital-importing and the foreign
capital-exporting country. Three alternative systems of taxing the
repatriated earnings of the internationally mobile capital are
considered.
First, a system of capital tax credits under which the
capital-exporting country offers capital tax credits that reduce the
domestic tax liability of its capital invested abroad by the amount of
tax payments made in the capital-importing country. That is, a unit of
capital invested in the capital-importing country pays an amount r|Rho~
in taxes in the host country, and an amount max((|Rho~* - |Rho~)r, 0) to
the foreign capital-exporting country. Thus, a unit of capital earns a
net rate of return equal to r(l - max(|Rho~*,|Rho~)), when invested in
the home capital-importing country, and equal to r*(1 - |Rho~*), when
invested in the foreign capital-exporting country. Equilibrium in the
world capital market requires that
r(1 - max(|Rho~*, |Rho~)) = r*(1 - |Rho~*). (1)
Given the small country assumption (i.e., dp= dr* =d|Rho~* = 0), dr =
0 under a system of capital tax credits when p |is less than~ |Rho~*
since, in this case, equilibrium in the world capital market requires
that r = r*. That is, when |Rho~ |is less than~ |Rho~* under a system of
capital tax credits, reducing the domestic capital tax simply transfers
capital tax revenue from the home capital-importing to the foreign
capital-exporting country without affecting the domestic rate of return
to capital.(7) When p |is greater than~ |Rho~* under tax credits,
equation (1) shows that dr = |r/(1 - |Rho~)~d|Rho~. In this case,
changing the domestic capital tax affects the domestic after-tax rate of
return to capital.
The second system of international taxation of repatriated capital
earnings is that of tax deductions. Under this system, tax payments by
foreign capital in the capital-importing country are deducted as a cost
in calculating its gross tax liability in the capital-exporting country.
A unit of capital earns a net rate of return r(1 - |Rho~)(1 - |Rho~*),
when invested in the capital-importing country, and r*(1 -|Rho~*), when
invested in the foreign capital-exporting country. Equilibrium in the
world capital market requires that
r(1 - |Rho~) = r*. (2)
The last tax system considered is one of untaxed repatriated capital
earnings, under which equilibrium in the world capital market requires
that
r(1 - p) = r*(1 - |Rho~*). (3)
Utilizing the small country assumption under the last two capital tax
systems, dr = |r/(1 - |Rho~)~d|Rho~.
Utility depends on the consumption of the traded and nontraded goods,
all of which are normal. The aggregate expenditure function E(p, q, u)
captures the minimum expenditure required to achieve utility u at price
vectors p and q. The expenditure function is increasing and strictly
concave in prices. Its derivatives with respect to p (i.e., |E.sub.p~ =
|Delta~E/|Delta~p), and with respect to q (i.e., |E.sub.q~ =
|Delta~E/|Delta~q) are the vectors of compensated demand functions for
the traded and the nontraded goods. By choice of units,
|E.sub.u~(=|Delta~E/|Delta~u) = 1.
The domestic supply of capital in the capital-importing country is
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~, where |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~ is the domestic fixed endowment of capital, and K* (|is greater
than~ 0) is the stock of foreign capital invested domestically. Since
the country's capital endowment is fixed, dK = dK*. For the rest of
the analysis, nontraded factors are omitted since they do not affect the
results. Let R(p, q, K) be the country's gross domestic product
(GDP) function, showing the value of the maximum output produced at
price vectors p and q, and supply of capital K, given the endowment of
the nontraded factors. The GDP function is strictly convex in prices and
concave in K (i.e., |R.sub.KK~ |is less than~ 0).(8) Its derivatives
with respect to p (i.e., |R.sub.p~), and with respect to q (i.e.,
|R.sub.q~) are the vectors of supply functions of the traded and the
nontraded goods, and with respect to K (i.e., |R.sub.K~) is the value of
the marginal product of capital. The domestic rate of return to capital
is equated to the value of the marginal product of capital in every
domestic use. That is,
r = |R.sub.K~(p, q, K). (4)
Differentiating equation (4), holding p constant, gives the changes
in the domestic supply of capital due to changes in r and q as follows:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
In equilibrium, the country's expenditure equals revenue from
production minus net payments to foreign capital invested at home. The
expenditure-income identity is
E(p, q, u) = R(p, q, K) - r(1 - |Rho~)K*. (6)
Equilibrium in the nontraded good markets requires that demand for
the
nontraded goods equals supply of the nontraded goods. That is,
|Z.sub.q~(p, q, u, K) = Eq(p, q, u) - Rq(p, q, K) = 0, (7)
where |Z.sub.q~ denotes the vector of excess demands for the
nontraded goods.
Equations (4), (6) and (7) constitute a specialized long-run steady
state trade model, consistent with a complete intertemporal equilibrium and zero long-run growth. Specifically, since the domestic rate of
return to capital equals the value of its marginal product (i.e.,
equation (4)), capital markets are in long-run equilibrium, further
capital formation does not take place (i.e., dK = dK* = 0). Then
equation (6), which is the current account long-run equilibrium,
indicates that the merchandise trade deficit (i.e., E(p, q, u) - R(p,
q)) must equal the net payments to foreign capital invested at home,
(i.e., -r (1 - |Rho~)K*).(9) Lastly, within a general equilibrium context, equation (7) must hold at all times to determine the endogenous
nontraded goods prices.
Differentiating equations (6) and (7), and using (5), gives the
changes in the endogenous variables u and q due to changes in the
domestic rate of return to capital and the capital tax rate as follows:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where, since goods are normal in consumption, |E.sub.qu~
(=|Z.sub.qu~) is a vector with all positive elements denoting the
changes in the compensated demands for the nontraded goods due to
changes in income. The determinant of the left-hand side coefficient
matrix, |Mathematical Expression Omitted~) is negative if nontraded good
markets are Walras stable.(10)
The Real Exchange Rate Effect of Liberalizing Capital Movements
In this section, assuming that commodity trade is free, and that the
rate of return to the internationally mobile capital is taxed according
to various rules of international capital taxation, we establish
sufficient conditions under which liberalization of capital movements,
through the reduction of the tax on the domestic rate of return to
capital, by the small capital-importing country (i.e., d|Rho~ |is less
than~ 0) leads to an appreciation or depreciation of its real exchange
rate.
In a multi-commodity (i.e., many traded and nontraded goods) model,
the country's real exchange rate (|Pi~) can be defined as a
fixed-weight index number of the relative prices of nontraded goods
(i.e., x|prime~q) to a price index of traded goods (i.e., |p.sub.T~)
|14~. That is, |Pi~ = x|prime~q/|p.sub.T~, where x is the vector of
base-period production and consumption of nontraded goods. Since prices
of traded goods are constant, changes in |Pi~ are due to changes in the
fixed-weight index number of the relative prices of nontraded goods.
That is,
d|Pi~ = x|prime~dq/|p.sub.T~.(9)
Equation (9) indicates that an increase (decrease) in the
fixed-weight index number of the relative prices of the nontraded goods
|i.e., x|prime~dq |is greater than~ 0(|is less than~ 0)~, leads to an
appreciation (depreciation) of the real exchange rate.
Consider the real exchange rate effect of a lower capital tax under a
system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is less than~ |Rho~*. Since
changes in the real exchange rate are due to changes in the fixed-weight
index number of the relative prices of nontraded goods, equations (8)
can give the effect of the lower capital tax on the relative prices of
nontraded goods as follows:
|Delta~dq = - rK*|E.sub.qu~d|Rho~. (10)
In this case, the lower capital tax transfers capital tax revenue
from the home capital-importing to the foreign capital-exporting
country. Since all goods are normal, the induced lower capital tax
revenue reduces the domestic demand and relative prices of the nontraded
goods, and causes a depreciation of the real exchange rate.
Next, consider the real exchange rate effect of a lower capital tax
under a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is greater than~
|Rho~*, or under the other two systems of taxing the repatriated
earnings of the internationally mobile capital considered by this
analysis. In these cases, the lower capital tax raises the after-tax
domestic rate of return to capital, its domestic use, and capital tax
revenue for the capital-importing country. Since dr = |r/(1 -
|Rho~)~d|Rho~, equations (8) give the effect of the lower capital tax on
the relative prices of nontraded goods as follows:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Equation (11) shows that the lower capital tax, which increases the
domestic use of capital, affects the relative prices of nontraded goods
directly through changes in production (i.e., |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~), and indirectly through changes in consumption (i.e.,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~) due to changes in capital tax
revenue. The lower capital tax by increasing the domestic use of capital
increases capital tax revenue and through its indirect consumption
effect has a positive effect on the demands and relative prices of the
nontraded goods. The lower capital tax through its production effect
increases (decreases) the production of the capital (non-capital)
intensive nontraded goods.(11)
To get better intuition about this result, consider the case of a
single nontraded good. The lower capital tax, which increases the
domestic use of capital and the capital tax revenue, raises the
consumption of the nontraded good, exerting a positive effect on its
relative price. If also the nontraded good is non-capital intensive
(i.e., |R.sub.qK~ |is less than~ 0), then, since by assumption
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~, the lower capital tax reduces its
production, causing an additional increase in its relative price and an
appreciation of the real exchange rate (i.e., |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~). But, if the nontraded good is capital intensive (i.e.,
|R.sub.qK~ |is greater than~ 0), the lower capital tax increases its
supply, exerting a negative effect on its relative price. Thus, the
relative price of the nontraded good increases (may decrease) and the
real exchange rate appreciates (may depreciate), if the nontraded good
is non-capital (capital) intensive.
This ambiguity in the effect of a lower capital tax on the real
exchange rate, due to the substitution effect in production and the
negative income effect in consumption, resembles the recent results of
trade theoretic studies regarding the effects of a higher tariff on the
real exchange rate. For example, Edwards and van Wijnbergen |8~ in a
three-good (exported, imported and nontraded goods) specific factor
(i.e., capital) model demonstrate that a higher tariff produces a
substitution and an income effect, which work in opposite directions, on
the relative price of the nontraded good and on the real exchange rate.
The substitution effect, which draws resources out of the production of
the nontraded good and increases its consumption, puts upward pressure
on the relative price of the nontraded good. The income effect, which
comes into play assuming initially a non-zero tariff, reduces welfare
and expenditure, and puts downward pressure on the relative price of the
nontraded good. As a result, the real exchange rate, defined as the
domestic price index of the traded to the nontraded good prices,
depreciates (may appreciate) if the income effect dominates (is smaller
than) the substitution effect. As a result, the real exchange rate
appreciates if the substitution effect dominates the income effect, that
is, if initially the economy is not very distorted (e.g., a small
departure from free trade). Similarly, a higher capital tax (i.e.,
d|Rho~ |is greater than~ 0), leads to a real exchange rate appreciation
if the nontraded good is capital intensive, and the substitution effect
dominates the income effect.
PROPOSITION 1. Consider a multi-commodity model of a small
capital-importing country, and assume that (i) nontraded good markets
are Walras stable, and (ii) goods are normal in consumption. Then, under
a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is less than~ |Rho~*,
liberalization of capital movements, through a lower capital tax by the
small capital-importing country, induces a real exchange rate
depreciation. Under a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is
greater than~ |Rho~*, of capital tax deductions, or of untaxed
repatriated capital earnings, the real exchange rate effect of a higher
capital tax depends on the factor intensity of the nontraded goods.
Specifically, in the case of a single nontraded good, the lower capital
tax raises (may reduce) its relative price and causes an appreciation
(possible depreciation) of the real exchange rate, if the nontraded good
is non-capital (capital) intensive.
Substituting equation (11) into (9) shows that under a system of tax
deductions, or of untaxed repatriated capital earnings, the effect of a
higher capital tax on the real exchange rate depends, among other
things, on the domestic capital tax rate but, it is independent of the
foreign tax rate. Under a system of capital tax credits, the effect of a
higher capital tax on the real exchange rate, in addition to the
domestic tax rate, it also depends indirectly on the foreign capital
tax.
III. A Model of a Small Capital-exporting Country
In this section, we establish sufficient conditions under which
liberalization of capital movements, through a lower capital tax by a
small capital-exporting country, leads to a real exchange rate
appreciation, assuming that commodity trade is free, and that the rate
of return to the internationally mobile capital is taxed according to
the various rules of international taxation discussed in the previous
section.
Under all three capital tax systems, the capital-exporting country
taxes its capital uniformly whether it is invested at home or
abroad.(12) When a unit of capital is invested domestically, it earns a
net rate of return r(1 - |Rho~). When it is invested abroad, it earns a
net rate of return |Rho~*(1 - max(|Rho~*, |Rho~)) under a system of
capital tax credits, r*(1 - |Rho~*)(1 - |Rho~) under a system of capital
tax deductions, and r*(1 - |Rho~*) under a system of untaxed repatriated
capital earnings. Equilibrium in the world capital market under a system
of capital tax credits requires that
r(1 - |Rho~) = r*(1 - max(|Rho~,|Rho~*)). (12)
Under a system of capital tax deductions, it requires that
r = r*(1 - |Rho~*), (13)
and under a system of untaxed repatriated capital earnings, it
requires that
r(1 - |Rho~) = r*(1 - |Rho~*). (14)
Since the country is small in world markets, then under a system of
capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is greater than~ |Rho~*, or under a
system of capital tax deductions, equations (12) and (13) show that a
higher capital tax does not affect the domestic rate of return to
capital (i.e., dr = 0). Under a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~
|is less than~ |Rho~*, or when repatriated capital earnings are untaxed
by the capital-exporting country, equations (13) and (14) show that
changes in the capital tax affect the domestic after-tax rate of return
to capital (i.e., dr = |r/(1 - |Rho~)~d|Rho~).
In equilibrium, the country's expenditure-income identity is
E(p, q, u) = R(p, q, K) - r*(1 - |Rho~*)K*, (15)
where K*(|is less than~ 0) is the country's capital exports, and
r*(1 - |Rho~*)K* denotes the net payments to domestic capital invested
in the foreign capital-importing country. Equilibrium in the
country's nontraded good markets, requiring that the demand equals
supply of nontraded goods, is again given by equation (7). Equation (9)
captures the changes in the capital-exporting country's real
exchange rate.
Using equation (5), the differentiation of equations (15) and (7)
captures the changes in the country's utility, and relative prices
of the nontraded goods due to changes in the domestic rate of return to
capital. That is,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
The determinant (|Delta~|prime~) of the left-hand side coefficient
matrix is negative, if the nontraded good markets are Walras stable.
The Real Exchange Rate Effect of Liberalizing Capital Movements
Since dr = 0 under a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is
greater than~ |Rho~*, or under a system of capital tax deductions, a
decrease in the domestic capital tax does not affect the gross rate of
return to capital, its domestic use, and the country's repatriated
net earnings of home capital invested abroad. Income and consumption in
the capital-exporting country remain unchanged, and so do the relative
prices of nontraded goods and the real exchange rate (i.e.,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~).
Under a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is less than~
|Rho~*, or under a system of untaxed repatriated capital earnings, dr =
|r/(1 - |Rho~)~d|Rho~. Also, using the equilibrium condition for the
world capital market (i.e., equations (12) and (14), respectively), r -
r*(1 - |Rho~*) = r|Rho~. Substituting this result into equations (16),
the effect of the lower capital tax, under these two capital tax
systems, on the relative prices of the nontraded goods is given as
follows:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
The right-hand side of equation (17) is identical to that of equation
(11) in the case of a small capital-importing country under a system of
tax credits when |Rho~ |is greater than~ |Rho~*, or under the other two
systems of international capital taxation. Similarly, the change in the
country's real exchange rate due to the higher capital tax, is
given after substituting (17) into (9). The example of a single
nontraded good can be used again for interpreting the effect of a higher
capital tax on the small capital-exporting country's real exchange
rate.
PROPOSITION 2. Consider a multi-commodity model of a small
capital-exporting country, and assume that (i) nontraded good markets
are Walras stable, and (ii) goods are normal in consumption. Then,
liberalization of capital movements, through a lower tax on repatriated
capital earnings by the small capital-exporting country, has no effect
on the real exchange rate under a system of capital tax credits when
|Rho~ |is greater than~ |Rho~*, or under a system of capital tax
deductions. Under a system of capital tax credits when |Rho~ |is less
than~ |Rho~*, or of untaxed repatriated capital earnings, the real
exchange rate effect of a lower capital tax depends on the factor
intensity of the nontraded good. Specifically, in the case of a single
nontraded good, a lower capital tax raises (may reduce) its relative
price and causes an appreciation (possible depreciation) of the real
exchange rate if the nontraded good is non-capital (capital) intensive.
Similar to the case of a small capital-importing country, the effect
of a lower capital tax on the relative prices of nontraded goods and the
real exchange rate depends indirectly on the foreign capital tax under a
system of capital tax credits. It is independent of the foreign capital
tax under a system of capital tax deductions, or of untaxed repatriated
capital earnings.
IV. Conclusions
Prompted by recent developments in the world capital markets, a
voluminous trade theoretic literature has examined the effects of
capital taxes on key economic variables such as employment and welfare.
This paper, in order to examine the real exchange rate effects of
liberalizing capital movements, develops a many traded and nontraded
goods general equilibrium model of a small capital-importing and a small
capital-exporting country. Commodity trade is free, the supply of
nontraded factors is fixed, and the supply of another factor, capital,
is variable due to international mobility. The rate of return to capital
is taxed according to a system of tax credits, of tax deductions, or of
untaxed repatriated capital earnings. The analysis shows that whether
liberalization of capital movements, through reduced capital taxes under
the three tax systems, affects the real exchange rate depends on whether
the country is a net capital-exporter or a net capital-importer, and on
the prevailing capital tax system. For the cases where the lower capital
tax affects the real exchange rate, the analysis establishes sufficient
conditions leading to a real appreciation or real depreciation.
For a small capital-exporting country, liberalization of capital
movements through a lower capital tax has no effect on the real exchange
rate under a system of capital tax deductions, and of tax credits when
the domestic capital tax exceeds the foreign tax rate. Assuming that (i)
non-traded good markets are Walras stable, and (ii) all goods are
normal, then a real exchange rate depreciation due to the lower capital
tax occurs in the small capital-importing country when under a system of
tax credits the domestic capital tax is smaller than the foreign tax
rate. Under assumptions (i) and (ii), the lower capital tax may lead to
a real exchange rate appreciation, depending on the factor intensity of
the nontraded goods, under a system of untaxed repatriated capital
earnings by either country, under a system of capital tax deductions by
the small capital-importing country, and under a system of tax credits
when the domestic capital tax by the small capital-importing
(capital-exporting) country exceeds (is smaller than) the foreign tax
rate. Under these capital tax systems, in the case of a single
non-capital (capital) intensive nontraded good, a lower capital tax
leads to an appreciation (possible depreciation) of the real exchange
rate.
Finally, in either the small capital-importing or capital-exporting
country, the effect of liberalizing capital movements through a lower
capital tax, on the real exchange rate indirectly depends on the foreign
capital tax under a system of capital tax credits. Under the other two
systems of international capital taxation, the effect of a higher
capital tax on the real exchange rate is independent of the foreign tax
rate.
1. Out-(-in)ward foreign direct investment (FDI) has also surged
dramatically to (from) the U.S. in recent years. In 1988, FDI into the
U.S. was $57.00 billion compared to an average of $18.5 billion during
1980-85. Outward FDI from the U.S. was $54.00 billion in 1987 compared
to an average of $10.00 billion during 1977-1984.
2. Greece and Portugal are exempted, if needed, to eliminate the
restrictions on capital markets by the end of 1995.
3. It is a long standing policy of the U.S., on equity grounds, to
avoid the double taxation of foreign earned income by U.S. residents,
and, on efficiency grounds, to maintain "capital-export
neutrality" which requires that capital taxes should not influence
the country location of capital. Thus, U.S. residents are allowed to
credit capital tax payments made in the foreign (i.e., host) country
against their U.S. tax liability according to the fraction:
((foreign-source taxable income) / (worldwide taxable income)) (U.S. tax
liability). The U.S., however, retains the right to tax foreign earned
income if the foreign tax rate is lower than the U.S. tax rate |18~.
4. Slemrod |17~ offers two alternative explanations for his second
result. Either inaccurate data which cannot pick-up important
differences in FDI behavior that do in fact exist, or sophisticated
financial strategies by firms in foreign tax credit capital-exporting
countries, through which they can defer indefinitely the home country
taxation of their repatriated capital earnings.
5. These and other authors make explicit reference to either one or
to both results.
6. Hazari et al. |12~ using a Harris-Todaro model of a small
developing economy, and Edwards and Ostry |9~ using a model with taxes
on international lending and borrowing, also demonstrate that the
conventional results may not always hold.
7. Capital taxes imposed by a capital-importing country to capture
capital tax revenue otherwise collected by the source capital-exporting
country are referred to as "soak-up" taxes |3~.
8. In models with international capital mobility, free trade may lead
to complete specialization in production and trade. Strict concavity of
the GDP function with respect to K is assumed in order to avoid this
problem.
9. In the literature of international finance, the portfolio balance
(PB) approach for the determination of the exchange rate has widely
considered the interaction between capital flows and the real exchange
rate in multi-period models through adjustments in assets and product
markets, and through the intertemporal allocation of savings,
investment, and labor supply |1; 10~. The present model is consistent
with the long-run equilibrium of the PB models, where wealth adjustments
have been completed through assets (de)accumulation, the real exchange
rate has moved to its long-run equilibrium level, and the current
account is balanced.
10. If the right-hand side of equation (7) is replaced by
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~, the vector of excess demands for
nontraded goods, then the sign of |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ is
derived by combining equations (6) and the modified (7). Walrasian
stability states that |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ must be a
negative semi-definite matrix, which requires |Delta~ to be negative.
11. We define the nontraded good to be capital (non-capital)
intensive if an inflow of capital increases (decreases) its production,
i.e., |R.sub.qk~ |is greater than~ 0(|is less than~ 0).
12. This implies that the capital-exporting country can fully tax the
foreign-source income of domestic capital invested abroad. Razin and
Sadka |16~ examine the optimum rules of taxing capital in a
capital-exporting country in the presence of free international capital
mobility and difficulties in taxing foreign-source capital income.
References
1. Allen, Polly and Peter Kenen. Assets Markets and Exchange Rates:
Modeling an Open Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980.
2. Balassa, Bela. Development in Semi-industrial Economies. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1982.
3. Bond, Eric, "Optimal Tax and Tariff Policies with Tax
Credits." Journal of International Economics, May 1991, 317-29.
4.----- and Larry Samuelson, "Strategic Behavior and the Rules
of International Taxation of Capital." Economic Journal, December
1989, 1099-11.
5. Clague, Christopher, "Tariffs, Transfers and the Real
Exchange Rate." Southern Economic Journal, July 1986, 155-69.
6. Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos. "Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade in
the Argentine Republic: 1913-76," in Trade, Stability, Technology
and Equity in Latin America, edited by M. Syrquin and S. Teitel. New
York: Academic Press, 1983.
7. Dornbusch, Rudinger. Open Economy Macroeconomics. New York: Basic
Books, 1980.
8. Edwards, Sebastian and Swender van Wijnbergen, "Tariffs, the
Real Exchange Rate and the Terms of Trade: On Two Popular Propositions
in International Economics." Oxford Economic Papers, September
1987, 458-64.
9. Edwards, Sebastian and Jonathan Ostry, "Terms of Trade
Disturbances, Real Exchange Rates, and Welfare: The Role of Capital
Controls and Labor Market Distortions." Oxford Economic Papers,
January 1992, 20-34.
10. Hallwood, Paul and Ronald MacDonald. International Money: Theory,
Evidence and Institutions. Oxford: Blackwell, 1986.
11. Hatzipanayotou, Panos and Michael Michael. "Variable Labor
Supply, Employment, and Welfare Under Various Rules of International
Taxation of Capital." Working Paper No. 93-123, The University of
Connecticut, March 1993.
12. Hazari, Bharat, Sisira Jayasuriya and Pasquale Sgro,
"Tariffs, Terms of Trade, Unemployment and the Real Exchange
Rate." Southern Economic Journal, January 1992, 721-31.
13. Johnson, Harry, "A Model of Protection and the Real Exchange
Rate," Economica, May 1969, 119-38.
14. Neary, Peter, "Determinants of the Equilibrium Real Exchange
Rate." American Economic Review, March 1988, 210-15.
15. Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development. Code of
Liberalization of Capital Movements. Paris, 1982.
16. Razin, Assaf and Efraim Sadka, "Efficient Investment
Incentives in the Presence of Capital Flight." Journal of
International Economics, August 1991, 171-81.
17. Slemrod, Joel. "Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment in
the United States: Evidence from a Cross-country Comparison," in
Taxation in the Global Economy, edited by A. Razin and J. Slemrod.
Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1990.
18. U.S. Congress. Tax Reform Act of 1986. Washington, D.C., 1987.