Adjusted concavity and the output effect under monopolistic price discrimination.
Xinghe Wang
I. Introduction
The motive of engaging in third degree monopolistic price
discrimination is rather simple, but its welfare implication is not. A
necessary condition for price discrimination to improve welfare, as
demonstrated by Schmalensee |5~ and Varian |8~, is that output increases
under price discrimination. Because of this well-known result, a focal
point of analysis of the social impact of price discrimination has been
on the direction of change in output. The few general rules advanced to
determine output change under price discrimination can be applied to
three different situations: (i) all demand curves are linear, (ii)
demand curves fall into two groups with opposing general curvatures, and
(iii) all demand curves have similar general curvature.
Definite answers have been obtained for the first two cases.(1)
Regarding the third case, less complete results have been developed.
Robinson |4~ introduces the "adjusted concavity" criterion
that the direction of output change is determined by the relative size
of the adjusted concavity of the two demand curves valued at the simple
monopoly output levels. This criterion, as noted by Robinson herself and
further elaborated by Edwards |1~, depends critically upon the local
assumption that the demand elasticities in the two markets are not very
different.(2) Greenhut and Ohta |3~ confirm that, without the local
assumption, the adjusted concavity criterion could lead to a wrong
prediction of output change by constructing an example with two constant
elasticity demand functions. Formby, Layson, and Smith |2~ further show
that the adjusted concavity criterion always leads to a wrong prediction
for the class of constant elasticity demand functions. Schmalensee |5~
then claims that there is apparently no simple criteria to determine the
output effect of price discrimination for the general multiple markets
situation.(3) However, Shih, Mai, and Liu |6~ demonstrate that a general
criterion can be obtained.
The general criterion set forth by Proposition 2 in Shih, Mai, and
Liu requires information about the slopes of the marginal revenue functions at some output levels which are between simple monopoly and
discriminating output levels. A more applicable version--their Corollary 2.3--is obtained by imposing conditions on the rate of change of the
slope of the marginal revenue functions, which are conditions on the
third derivatives of the demand functions. Furthermore, their analysis
leads them to conclude that "Robinson's adjusted concavity ...
alone can not determine the output effect" |6, 157~.
In this paper, it is demonstrated that Robinson's adjusted
concavity can lead to definite conclusions on the output effect of price
discrimination. Specifically, if the maximum (minimum) value of adjusted
concavity over the range of output levels between the simple monopoly
and discriminatory outputs in each of the weak markets is less (greater)
than or equal to the minimum (maximum) value of adjusted concavity over
the corresponding ranges of output in all of the strong markets, then
total output under discrimination will be greater (less) than that under
simple monopoly when all demand curves are strictly convex (concave).
For the cases where the adjusted concavity condition is retained and the
general curvature of the demand curves is reversed, examples are
provided to show that definite answers can not be obtained.
II. Analysis
Consider a monopolist producing a homogeneous good at a constant unit
cost c and selling it in n separate markets with (inverse) demand
function |p.sub i~(|q.sub.i~) for market i (i = 1,....,n). If third
degree price discrimination is allowed, the firm chooses an output
|q.sub.i~ to maximize its profit ||Pi~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) =
||p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) - c~|q.sub.i~ in market i. Assume that all profit
functions are strictly concave (i.e., ||Pi~|double
prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is less than~ 0). The first order conditions
are
|p|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)|q.sub.i~ + |p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) - c = 0.
(1)
Dividing (1) by |p|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) and summing over i give
the total output
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where hat ( ) of a variable denotes its optimal value under price
discrimination.
Under simple monopoly, the firm chooses a total output q to maximize
its total profit |p(q) - c~q, where p(q) is the (inverse) aggregate
demand function. Assume that all markets are served under simple
monopoly. The first order condition gives the total output
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where bar (???) of a variable denotes its optimal value under simple
monopoly.
The effect of price discrimination on output can be obtained by
comparing (3) with (2). To begin with, decompose the slope of the
aggregate demand function in (3) in terms of the slopes of individual
demand functions as follows. At the equilibrium price |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~, the output of each market |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~ is determined by |Mathematical Expression Omitted~. Let
|d.sub.i~(p) be the direct demand function for market i and
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~ be the direct aggregate demand
function. Since |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, (3) can be written as
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Subtracting (4) from (2) gives
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Thus, the change in total output due to price discrimination is
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where |L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is equivalent to~ ||p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) -
c~/|p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) is the Lerner index of market i,
||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is equivalent to~
-|p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)/||q.sub.i~|p|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)~ is the
demand elasticity for market i, and |R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is equivalent
to~ |q.sub.i~|p|double
prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)/|p|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) is the adjusted
concavity of market i. Thus, the output effect of price discrimination
is determined by the weighed sum of the change in output in each market,
where the weights are given by the product of the Lerner index, the
demand elasticity and the adjusted concavity in each market. This
indicates the complexity of determining the output effect of price
discrimination. In order to obtain some general rules, one will need to
place conditions on these elements.
As usual, weak markets are defined to be those where price decreases
under discrimination and strong markets those where price increases
under discrimination. Let W be the collection of weak markets and S the
collection of strong markets. Note that, in (5), for all weak markets
the upper limit of the corresponding integration exceeds the lower limit
and for all strong markets the lower limit exceeds the upper limit.
It is obvious that if all demand functions are linear (i.e.,
|p|double prime~.sub.i~ = 0, or equivalently, |R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = 0)
then the integrands in (5) all vanish and thus total output remains
unchanged under price discrimination. Since |L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) and
||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) are both positive, it is also easy to see
that if for all strong markets i, |R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is greater than
or equal to~ 0 (i.e., |p|double prime~.sub.i~ |is less than or equal to~
0), and for all weak markets i, |R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is less than~ 0
(i.e., |p|double prime~.sub.i~ |is greater than~ 0), then every integral
in (5) is negative, implying that total output expands under price
discrimination. Thus, the following well-known proposition is obtained.
PROPOSITION 1. (Robinson |4~, Schmalensee |5~, Shih, Mai, and Liu
|6~.) Suppose all markets are served under simple monopoly. If all
demand curves are linear then total output remains unchanged under price
discrimination. However, if the demand curves are concave in all strong
markets and strictly convex in all weak markets then total output
increases under price discrimination, and vice verse.
Proposition 1 can be used to predict the direction of output change
under price discrimination in the cases of linear demands or two groups
of demands with opposing general curvatures. However, the more concerned
case in the literature has been where all demands have the same general
curvature. To analyze this latter case, we first examine the (product)
function |L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~). A refreshment
of the inverse elasticity rule suggests that this function is related to
the marginal profit function and thus some of its properties can be
obtained from the concavity of the profit function. In fact, the
marginal profit function can be written as
||Pi~|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = |
q.sub.i~) - 1~. (6)
Since ||Pi~|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) is a decreasing function in
|q.sub.i~, by (1) and the fact that
|-|p|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)|q.sub.i~~ |is greater than~ 0, (6) implies
that ||L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) - 1~ |is greater
than~ (=, |is less than~) 0 if and only if |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~. Thus, |L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is
greater than~ 1 if i |is an element of~ W and |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~, and |L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is less
than~ 1 if i |is an element of~ S and |Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
When all demand curves are strictly convex (i.e.,
|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is less than~ 0 for all i), replacing
|L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) in (5) by 1 leads to
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Let |Mathematical Expression Omitted~; |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~, and |Mathematical Expression Omitted~; |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~. If |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, then
replacing |R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) in (7) by |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~ implies
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Since ||Pi~|double prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) =
2|p|prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) + |q.sub.i~|p|double
prime~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is less than~ 0 implies that
|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is greater than~ -2, it follows that |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~. Therefore, (8) leads to |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~.
When all demand curves are strictly concave (i.e.,
|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is greater than~ 0 for all i), similar derivation as above shows that if |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, where
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~; |Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
and |Mathematical Expression Omitted~; |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~, then (5) implies
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Since |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, it follows from (9) that
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~. The following proposition summarizes
these results.
PROPOSITION 2. Suppose all markets are served under simple monopoly.
If all demand curves are strictly convex (concave) and the maximum
(minimum) value of adjusted concavity in each of the weak markets is
less (greater) than or equal to the minimum (maximum) value of adjusted
concavity in all of the strong markets, i.e., |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~, then total output under discrimination will be greater (less)
than that under simple monopoly.
Proposition 2 can be applied, for example, to the class of constant
adjusted concavity demand curves, introduced by Shih, Mai, and Liu |6~,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~(i = 1,..., m, |a.sub.i~, |b.sub.i~ |is
greater than~ 0, R |is greater than~ -1), where R is the constant
adjusted concavity for all markets. Since |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~ and all demand curves are strictly convex (concave) if R |is
less than~ 0 (R |is greater than~ 0), Proposition 2 implies that total
output under discrimination will be greater (less) than that under
simple monopoly if R |is less than~ 0 (R |is greater than~ 0).
Proposition 2 indicates that Robinson's adjusted concavity
criterion, which applies only to situations where the demand
elasticities in different markets are nearly equal, can be partially
generalized to cover situations where the local assumption is relaxed.
Specifically, consider the case where the minimum value of adjusted
concavity in each of the weak markets is greater than or equal to the
maximum value of adjusted concavity in all of the strong markets (i.e.,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~). When all demand curves are strictly
concave, Proposition 2 implies that total output decreases under price
discrimination. When all demand curves are strictly convex, however,
total output does not necessarily decrease under price discrimination
(which differs from what Robinson's criterion would predict if it
were fully generalized), as shown by the examples in the next section.
Similar statements can be made for the case where |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~.
III. Examples
Examples 1 and 2 show that if |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ then
total output can either increase or decrease under price discrimination
when all demand curves are strictly convex; examples 3 and 4 show that
if |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ then total output can either
increase or decrease under price discrimination when all demand curves
are strictly concave.
Example 1
Consider the class of strictly convex demand functions
|p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = |a.sub.i~|e.sup.-|b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~~, |a.sub.i~,
|b.sub.i~ |is greater than~ 0 (i = 1,...,n). Assume that all markets are
served under simple monopoly (this is satisfied if, for example,
|a.sub.i~ = a |is greater than~ c for all i). Market i's demand
elasticity is ||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = 1/||b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~~
which is decreasing in |q.sub.i~; its adjusted concavity is
|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = -|b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~. Since weak markets have
relatively higher elasticity under price discrimination, it follows that
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~ for all i |is an element of~ W and for
all j |is an element of~ S. Thus, |b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~ |is less than~
|b.sub.j~|q.sub.j~ for all i |is an element of~ W, |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~, and for all j |is an element of~ S, |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~; it follows that |Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Since for any i, ||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = -1,
|L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) is decreasing in |q.sub.i~, and |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ (here |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ is the price
under simple monopoly), (5) implies
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Therefore, |Mathematical Expression Omitted~. This example shows that
if |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, total output can decrease under
discrimination when all demand curves are strictly convex.
Example 2
Consider the class of strictly convex (constant elasticity) demand
functions |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, ||Epsilon~.sub.i~ |is
greater than~ 1, |b.sub.i~ |is greater than~ 0 (i = 1,...,n) where
||Epsilon~.sub.i~ is the demand elasticity of market i. It is easy to
see that all markets are served under simple monopoly. Assume, without
loss of generality, that ||Epsilon~.sub.1~ |is less than~
||Epsilon~.sub.2~ |is less than~ |center dot~|center dot~|center dot~
|is less than~ ||Epsilon~.sub.n~ and that the number of strong markets
is s(|is less than~ n). This implies that markets 1 to s are the strong
markets and markets s + 1 to n are the weak markets. Since
|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = -(1 + 1/||Epsilon~.sub.i~), it is obvious that
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~. Formby, Layson, and Smith |2~ show
that, for a large variety of elasticities, total output increases under
discrimination. This example shows that if |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~, total output can increase under discrimination when all demand
curves are strictly convex.
Example 3
Consider the class of strictly concave demand functions
|p.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = |(|a.sub.i~ - |b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~).sup.1/2~,
|a.sub.i~, |b.sub.i~ |is greater than~ 0 (i = 1,...,n). Assume that all
markets are served under simple monopoly (this is satisfied if, for
example, |a.sub.i~ = a |is greater than~ |c.sup.2~ for all i). Market
i's demand elasticity is ||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = 2(|a.sub.i~
- |b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~)/(|b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~), which is decreasing in
|q.sub.i~; its adjusted concavity is |R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) =
|b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~/|2(|a.sub.i~ - |b.sub.i~|q.sub.i~)~, which is
increasing in |q.sub.i~. Note that
||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = 1 for all i. Since
weak markets have relatively higher elasticity under price
discrimination, i.e., |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ for all i |is an
element of~ W and for all j |is an element of~ S, it follows that
||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) |is greater than~
||Epsilon~.sub.j~(|q.sub.j~) for all i |is an element of~ W,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~, and for all j |is an element of~ S,
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~; this implies that |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~. Since for any i,
||Epsilon~.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~)|R.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) = 1,
|L.sub.i~(|q.sub.i~) is decreasing in |q.sub.i~, and |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~, (5) implies
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
Therefore, |Mathematical Expression Omitted~. This example shows that
if |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, total output can increase under
discrimination when all demand curves are strictly concave.
Example 4
Consider two strictly concave demand functions |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ and |Mathematical Expression Omitted~. The adjusted
concavities of markets 1 and 2 are |R.sub.1~(|q.sub.1~) = 1 and
|R.sub.2~(|q.sub.2~) = 2. Simple calculation yields:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
Therefore, both markets are served and |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~. Since market 1 is the weak market, market 2 is the strong
market, and |R.sub.1~(|q.sub.1~) |is less than~ |R.sub.2~(|q.sub.2~) for
all |q.sub.1~ and |q.sub.2~, this example shows that if |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~, total output can decrease under discrimination when
all demand curves are strictly concave.
IV. Concluding Remarks
This paper, using straightforward calculus, analyzed the effect of
third degree price discrimination on output. Several elements were
identified to determine this effect; these were the Lerner index, the
demand elasticity and the adjusted concavity. A general criterion was
then developed to determine the output effect of discrimination based on
the adjusted concavity concept suggested by Robinson sixty years ago.
This result adds to the existing rule advanced by Shih, Mai, and Liu
|6~ in providing general conclusions on the output effect of price
discrimination when all demand curves have the same general curvature.
In particular, the present analysis, for the first time, has shown that
convexity and concavity of the demand curves may have different
implications on the output effect of price discrimination. Furthermore,
Proposition 2 underlines the true reason why Greenhut and Ohta |3~ and
Formby, Layson, and James |2~ found counter-examples to Robinson's
adjusted concavity criterion, as illustrated in the argument developed
in Example 2.
1. The results, as summarized by Shih, Mai and Liu |6~, are
reproduced in Proposition 1 below.
2. As observed by Robinson |4, 193~, this local assumption amounts to
assuming linear marginal revenue curves. Shih, Mai and Liu |6, 154~
further elaborate on this point.
3. In the case of two markets, Edwards |1~ obtains several sufficient
global conditions on the rates of change of marginal revenue functions
to determine the direction of output change under discrimination; Smith
and Formby |7~ demonstrate the generality of the SMR-DMR criterion in
deciding the output effect of discrimination.
References
1. Edwards, Edgar O., "The Analysis of Output under
Discrimination." Econometrica, April 1950, 161-72.
2. Formby, John P., Stephen K. Layson and W. James Smith, "Price
Discrimination, 'Adjusted Concavity', and Output Changes under
Conditions of Constant Elasticity." Economic Journal, December 1983, 892-99.
3. Greenhut, Melvin L. and Hiroshi Ohta, "Joan Robinson's
Criterion for Deciding Whether Market Discrimination Reduces
Output." Economic Journal, March 1976, 96-97.
4. Robinson, Joan. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London:
Macmillan, 1933.
5. Schmalensee, Richard, "Output and Welfare Implications of
Monopolistic Third Degree Price Discrimination." American Economic
Review, March 1981, 242-47.
6. Shih, Jun-ji, Chao-cheng Mai and Jang-chao Liu, "A General
Analysis of the Output Effect under Third Degree Price
Discrimination." Economic Journal, March 1988, 149-58.
7. Smith, James W. and John P. Formby, "Output Changes under
Third Degree Price Discrimination: A Reexamination." Southern
Economic Journal, 1981, 164-71.
8. Varian, Hal R., "Price Discrimination and Social
Welfare." American Economic Review, September 1985, 870-75.