From Slavery to Agrarian Capitalism in the Cotton Plantation South: Central Georgia, 1800-1880.
McCandless, Amy Thompson
Using six counties in central Georgia as a microcosm of economic
development in the U.S. cotton belt, Joseph P. Reidy describes the
social and political repercussions of the transformation from slave to
free labor in the years between 1800 and 1880. Reidy, an associate
professor of history at Howard University, compares economic
developments in central Georgia to those in other slave holding areas of
the Americas, arguing that "events in the South can only be
understood in the larger hemispheric context of slave
emancipation". Thus, he places slavery in the U.S. South in a
global historical framework in order to explain the economic, social,
and political changes which accompanied its abolition.
Reidy begins by examining the antebellum economic relationships of
yeoman settlers, cotton planters, and slaves during central
Georgia's frontier period. In the pioneer phase before the cotton
boom of the 1830s, class differences were muted, as whites and blacks
worked side by side to eke out a subsistence from the soil. Labor
relations were precapitalist; the mutual exchange of goods and services among friends and family was common; the task system gave slaves free
time to grow their own food and to produce artifacts for barter or for
sale. Yeoman were proud of their economic and political independence.
Even the cotton planter was "in the world market but not of
it". Although planters were involved by necessity in the
international cotton trade, they generally opposed capitalist
institutions and relationships.
The expansion of cotton production and the concomitant importance of
the capitalist world market led to changes in economic organization.
Gang labor replaced the task system. Small subsistence farmers lost out
to large commercial planters. The slave holding elite gained increasing
control over the economic and political institutions of central Georgia.
As economic differences among whites increased, planters pointed to
slavery as the savior of republican equality. Unlike the North, where
differences between labor and capital threatened to tear asunder the
social fabric, Georgian planters such as T.R.R. Cobb argued that the
South united diverse economic interests into one by combining labor and
capital in the person of the slave. Because black slaves provided a
mudsill class, all whites were equal.
Reidy questions the egalitarianism of slave society. Although U.S.
planters did not control Southern yeoman as the Brazilian planters did
their European clients, he argues that they had far greater economic,
social, and political power over other Europeans than Northern
capitalists. Similarly, planters in the U.S. South attempted to control
the labor of their slaves to a far greater extent than their Caribbean
and South American counterparts. The "slaves' producing and
marketing goods without the mediation of the master posed a potential
threat . . . the entering wedge of free labor".
The outbreak of war in 1861 brought tremendous changes to the
Southern economic system. Reidy thinks that the Confederate
vice-president, Alexander H. Stephens, correctly identified slavery as
the "cornerstone of the rebellion". The South was not only
fighting to preserve its peculiar institution, but it also depended upon
the provision of goods and services by slaves to defeat the North. The
Confederate utilization of slave labor undermined traditional economic
and social relationships, however: the shift from cotton production to
food staples left slaves with more free time to engage in their own
economic activities; the mobilization of white men increased the demand
for slave artisans and industrial workers.
The Southern defeat meant the end of slavery and the need to create
new economic, social, and political relationships. In the years between
1865 and 1880, "the planters evolved by several routes into an
agrarian bourgeoisie and the freedpeople into a rural proletariat".
Southern planters of the late 19th century, much like the English
landowners of the 18th century, systematically curtailed landless laborers' access to resources which had traditionally provided them
subsistence. In addition to developing bourgeois concepts of private
property, planters also sought to transform sharecropping into
"another mode of wage labor". They used the legal and
political power which they possessed to achieve economic hegemony.
The freedmen and women of Georgia vigorously opposed efforts to turn
them into a rural proletariat. They conceived of sharecropping as a form
of "co-partnership" whereby those who owned and those who
worked the land made joint decisions about the crop. They developed
their own institutions and leaders to assert their independence from
their former masters. And, most significantly, they realized the
importance of the suffrage and attempted to make the political system
responsive to their needs. But the landed and commercial elite managed
to reestablish their control over the political system and to deny the
emancipated slaves the economic and social independence they desired.
African Americans' efforts to create their own institutions and
to control their own lives renew the age-old historic debate between
proponents of economic determinism and of the so-called "Great Man
Theory" of history. Although he criticizes those who see people at
the mercy of world market forces, Reidy concedes that the
"plantation workers of central Georgia . . . struggled mightily
(but ultimately without success) to resolve the contradiction between
the political ideals of human equality and the persistent reality of
economic inequality . . .".
Reidy's comparative approach to Southern history is not new.
Marxist historians have long emphasized the importance of the capitalist
world market to developments in the agrarian South. Historians of
diverse persuasions have argued that slavery in the U.S. needs to be
placed in a global historical framework. Both Eugene Genovese and
Elizabeth Fox-Genovese have examined slave holding in the larger context
of the Atlantic world. Stanley Mintz has studied slave societies in the
Caribbean; Peter Kolchin has compared American slavery and Russian
serfdom. Reidy does a good job of integrating these and other
comparative studies into his work; he draws numerous parallels between
the circumstances of slaves in central Georgia and those of bound
laborers elsewhere in the world.
His treatment of the Southern yeoman is less satisfying. The bulk of
his economic analysis involves planters and slaves. Although he notes
the ways in which capitalist developments hurt the small holder, Reidy
barely alludes to the white laborer's efforts to control his own
fate. Nor does he explore the role of racism in keeping white and black
laborers apart.
The comparative perspective of Reidy's book compensates for many
of its shortcomings. College students are often extremely provincial in
their approach to economic development and historical change. From
Slavery to Agrarian Capitalism in the Cotton Plantation South would be
an excellent monograph to use in a U.S. history survey or in a seminar
on the American South. Amy Thompson McCandless College of Charleston