Explaining regulatory commission behavior in the electric utility industry.
Nowell, Clifford
I. Introduction
A number of theoretical studies have examined regulated output price
and regulatory lag as policy tools of regulatory commissions. Bailey and
Coleman |6~ argue that regulatory lag mitigates the Averch-Johnson
effect |4~. Wendel |20~ uses a game-theoretic model to show that
regulators' and firms' strategies determine R and D
expenditures and regulatory lag. Bailey |5~ argues that firms engage in
R and D to earn excess profits because of regulatory lag, which is set
by regulators. Assuming cost plus regulation, Sweeney |19~ argues that
increased regulatory lag can retard adoption of new technologies;
Sappington |18~ presents a similar argument--increasing lag induces
waste. Bawa and Sibley |7~ assume that regulators directly adjust price
to affect rates of return and that regulatory lag is endogenously determined as a function of the difference between the actual and fair
rate of return. While we are aware of no econometric studies which
explain the length of regulatory lag, a number of authors have attempted
to explain the rate of return requested by the firm and that allowed by
the commission. Using a recursive econometric model, Joskow |11~ finds a
positive correlation between these two variables. This study was
criticized by Roberts, Maddala, and Enholm |17~ for not addressing the
sample selectivity bias and simultaneity issues. Hagerman and Ratchford
|10~ find that both economic and political variables are significant in
explaining the allowed rate of return, although the
elected-versus-appointed status of the commissioners is not important.
Costello |9~ obtains similar results regarding electric rates, although
Primeaux and Mann |6~ find weakly conflicting evidence.
While theoretical justification exists for the use of regulatory lag
as a policy tool, we believe this is the first attempt to formally model
and test this aspect of regulatory commission behavior. The remainder of
the paper is organized as follows. Section II presents a theoretical
model of a welfare-maximizing regulator who can choose both price and
the period of regulatory lag in order to meet a revenue requirement. The
implication of the model is that both the optimal price and lag are
dependent on a set of exogenous variables, and that lag and price
changes may be used as substitutes in order to meet the firms revenue
requirement. Section III presents the econometric models used to test
the theory. The data and results are reported in section IV. Finally,
conclusions are presented in section V.
II. Regulatory Lag and Regulated Price
Regulatory lag is defined as the time a regulatory commission
requires to rule on a utility's request for a rate increase. Within
the framework of a two-period model, we assume the utility, with an
allowed rate |p.sub.1~, files a request for rate relief at time
|t.sub.0~. At time |t.sub.1~ the commission rules on the company's
request and institutes the new rate, |p.sub.2~. The first period,
|t.sub.1~ - |t.sub.0~, is regulatory lag (LAG). The new set of rates is
in effect at time |t.sub.2~ when the utility again files for a rate
increase (and remains in effect until the new rate is enacted). Thus,
|t.sub.2~ - |t.sub.1~, represents the second period.
Demand for the utility's product is represented by the function
|q.sub.1~ = |q.sub.1~(|p.sub.1~, t) during the first period and
|q.sub.2~ = |q.sub.2~(|p.sub.2~, t) during the second period. In both
expressions, |q.sub.i~ represents the quantity demanded per unit of time
and |p.sub.i~ is the price per unit, i = 1, 2. Cross elasticities of
demand between the two periods are assumed to be zero.
The discounted present value of consumer surplus during the first
period is written as
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where ||Delta~.sub.1~ is the discount rate in the first period.
During this period, the utility's variable costs are assumed to
be rising, while capital costs are fixed. The firm's discounted
profits are
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where
V|C.sub.1~ = the variable cost function,
|Alpha~ = the rate of increase in variable costs during the first
period,
|r.sub.1~ = the price of capital during the first period,
|K.sub.1~ = the quantity of capital used during the first period.
Increases in variable costs reduce profits over time. The longer the
lag the greater the erosion of profits. Apparently, this occurred in the
late 1970s and early 1980s.
During the second period, discounted consumer surplus is
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
and discounted profit is
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
where the subscripts on variables used in (1) and (2) have been
incremented. For simplicity we assume that variable costs are constant
in period 2.
The commission must allow the utility an opportunity to earn a fair
rate of return. Financial markets determine a fair rate of return for
period 1, |S.sub.1~, and for period 2, |S.sub.2~. The regulator chooses
|p.sub.2~ and finally |t.sub.1~ to ensure that at least the fair return
is earned for the two periods. The regulatory constraint, which requires
that the utility's discounted average earned rate of return on
capital over the period (|t.sub.0~ - |t.sub.2~) equals or exceeds its
discounted authorized return for this period, is
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~.
We now model the behavior of a regulator who maximizes the welfare of
producers and consumers. Defining welfare over the two periods as the
sum of the discounted present value of the sum of consumer surplus and
profits, we can write the regulator's problem as
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~,
subject to (5) satisfied as an equality.
The welfare function is clearly concave in both of the arguments
|t.sub.1~ and |p.sub.2~. Thus, second-order conditions will require that
the curvature of the welfare function be greater than the curvature of
the fixed rate of return locus assuming that it also is concave. If
these conditions are met a unique maximum will be located somewhere
along the curve. The first-order conditions can be solved for the
optimal values, |t*.sub.1~ and |p*.sub.2~. They will be functions of
|Alpha~, |r.sub.1~, |r.sub.2~, |S.sub.1~, |S.sub.2~, |p.sub.1~,
|t.sub.2~, |K.sub.1~, |K.sub.2~, ||Delta~.sub.1~, and ||Delta~.sub.2~.
Social welfare may not be maximized to the extent that the political
motivation of the commissioners or the firm's requested |p.sub.2~
influence |t*.sub.1~ or |p*.sub.2~, ceteris paribus.
The rate of return constraint illustrates the tradeoff between
|t.sub.1~ and |p.sub.2~. If the commission waits longer to make a
decision in a rate case, a higher price must be granted to offset the
reduction of earnings due to increases in variable costs. The curvature
of the fixed rate of return locus will depend on the response of
quantity demanded to changes in price as well as the time period when
the utility files a new rate case in response to changes in price by the
commission. An increase in the exogenous variable |S.sub.2~ will shift
the iso-rate of return locus upward. In order to meet the new constraint
a commission may choose different combinations of |p.sub.2~ and
|t.sub.1~. The choice variables |p.sub.2~ and |t.sub.1~ can be used as
substitutes by the regulatory commission to ensure the utility earns a
specific rate of return. That is, higher required rates of return may be
associated with long periods of lag and large rate increases, or smaller
periods of lag and smaller rate increases.
III. Econometric Models And Data
Specification Issues
Turning now to our econometric model, we explain the allowed change
in revenues (AUTREV) instead of |p.sub.2~, and LAG instead of |t.sub.1~.
AUTREV is actually approved by the commission, while |p.sub.2~ would
have to be constructed as a weighted average based on revenues from each
aggregate category, rather than as a marginal price faced by the
consumer. LAG is defined simply as |t.sub.1~ - |t.sub.0~.
Three issues of econometric specification must be considered in
explaining AUTREV and LAG. The first is whether these variables are
jointly dependent and part of a simultaneous equations system. Testing
the hypothesis of simultaneity is not feasible, since the theory of
regulatory bargaining is inadequate to provide identification of such a
system or a set of potential instruments. All explanatory variables
affect both dependent variables based on our theory in section II. Thus,
we estimate reduced form equations for LAG and AUTREV. The second issue
is whether the estimators of the effects of explanatory variables on LAG
and AUTREV may be subject to self-selectivity bias. A firm requests
review only when the latent variable, U, measuring intensity of desire
for review exceeds some threshold. We measure this intensity with the
latent variable, U. Since variables describing a firm's financial
health are available only in this case, the observed counterpart of U is
truncated. Unless U is independent of LAG and AUTREV, we must explicitly
model sample selectivity to avoid bias.
We test for sample selectivity by estimating the latent truncated
variable model developed by Bloom and Killingsworth |8~. Estimated
parameters which measure sample selectivity bias are highly
insignificant at the .05 level using a one-tailed test.
Finally, for 78 of the 96 rate cases which comprise the data set,
laws limiting the maximum lag were in effect. For these 78 cases the
mean allowed lag was 256.67 days with a standard deviation of 156.29.
Thus, two issues must be considered. First, LAG may be censored for some
observations and hence the likelihoods derived below would have to be
appropriately modified. In no case, however, was LAG equal to the
statutory limit and in 19 cases LAG exceeded this limit. Conversations
with state regulatory agency personnel indicated that these limits could
be either exceeded without penalty, because of mutual agreement, or
because multiple issues were being decided at one time. Hence, censoring is not relevant. Second, the presence of a limit may reduce LAG even if
no observations are censored. To test for this possibility we included a
dummy variable for the presence of a limit in estimating LAG. In all
cases the coefficient associated with this dummy variable was highly
insignificant. Thus, we omit this variable from further discussion.
Econometric Models Explaining LAG
Since we can expect LAG to be non-normally distributed, we examine
families of failure time models which incorporate such distributions.
Recent failure time studies include those of unemployment duration |11~,
career length |2~, and duration of terrorist incidents |3~. The problem
of estimating regulatory lag is a natural application of time to failure
analysis.
Table I characterizes our failure time data. The first column breaks
down the length of regulatory lag into ten equal intervals. Column two
shows the number of rate cases decided in each interval. Columns three
and four indicate the percent of cases not yet decided and the hazard,
respectively. The hazard is the probability that the regulatory
commission will end the period of regulatory lag at any time during the
interval, conditional upon not having reached a decision at the
beginning of the interval. The hazard is generally increasing throughout
time, implying that the longer the period of regulatory lag, the more
likely a decision will be rendered immediately. Note that only six
percent of all decisions are made in less than four months (112.8 days)
and only eight percent take longer than 13 months (394.8 days).
Several different densities have been used to describe failure time
data. The most common are the Weibull and exponential distributions. The
exponential regression model assumes a constant hazard rate, an
assumption which is obviously inappropriate based on the empirical
hazard. The Weibull model allows for a monotonic hazard, either
increasing or decreasing, and seems more appropriate for this
application. However, the empirical hazard is clearly non-monotonic. In
this paper we reject the exponential model and report the results of two
different proportional hazards models, the Weibull model and the
polynomial hazard model, which allows for a non-monotonic hazard. We
also examine the effects of modelling unobserved heterogeneity. The
likelihoods for these models are provided in the Appendix.
Table I. Duration Data
Time # Entering # Exiting Pct. Surviving Hazard
0-56.4 96 2 1.0 .0004
56.4-112.8 94 4 .979 .0008
112.8-169.2 90 6 .937 .0012
169.2-225.6 84 25 .875 .0062
225.6-282.0 59 17 .615 .0060
282.0-338.4 42 28 .438 .0177
338.4-394.8 14 7 .146 .0118
394.8-451.2 7 5 .073 .0197
451.2-507.6 2 1 .021 .0118
507.6-564.0 1 1 .014 .0355
Table II. Definitions, Means, and Standard Deviations
Standard
Variable Definition Mean
Deviations
LAG The time period (100's of days) between
when the firm files a rate request and the
commission institutes a new set of rates. 2.61 .92
AROR Rate of return authorized during current
rate hearing. 11.56 1.43
BUDGET Annual commission budget ($10 millions)
during the year of the rate hearing. .95 .86
INFL Growth in maintenance and operating
expenses in the year of rate hearing. .10 .11
INTERIM =1 if the commission gave interim rate
relief; =0 otherwise. .21 .41
PREFILE The length of time (in 100's of days) the
firm's rates had been in effect prior to
the time of filing. 2.41 1.77
APPOINT =1 if the commission is appointed;
=0 otherwise. .95 .22
TERM Length of term (years) of commissioners. 5.72 1.51
RATEBASE Rate base ($ billions) currently allowed
by the commission. 1.83 1.58
REQREV Change in revenues ($100 millions)
requested by the firm. 1.67 2.13
AUTREV Change in revenues ($100 millions)
authorized by the commission. .82 1.10
Data
Definitions, means, and standard deviations of the variables used to
explain LAG and AUTREV for our sample of electric utility rate hearings
are presented in Table II. For the variables which influence the
commission's choice of t and p in (6) we employ a dummy variable
indicating that interim rate relief was granted (INTERIM), the length of
time between previous rate adjustments (PREFILE), and the utility's
requested rate increase (REQREV). As a measure of |S.sub.2~, we employ
the authorized rate of return for the upcoming period (AROR). We utilize
the rate of growth in variable costs (INFL) to measure |Alpha~, and the
utility's ratebase (RATEBASE) to measure |K.sub.1~. As political
variables we employ the size of the commission's budget (BUDGET),
the commissioner's appointed status (APPOINT), and the length of
commissioner's terms (TERM). There is little evidence of serious
correlation among the explanatory variables. Most simple correlations
coefficients are less than .2 in absolute value. The only exception is
that between REQREV and RATEBASE, which is .67.
Our sample consists of 96 rate cases, which comprised all electric
utility rate cases from 1980-84, with non-missing data for our selected
covariates as reported in the Annual Report of Utility and Carrier
Regulation published by the National Association of Regulatory
Commissioners (NARUC) |14~. The 1980-84 interval was selected for
consistency with our theory, since every rate action reported by the
NARUC during this period was a request for higher rates. The data are
available from the authors upon request. We first examine the
hypothesized relationships between the explanatory variables and LAG.
AROR. The rate of return authorized by the commission for the
upcoming period signifies the opportunity cost of increasing the length
of regulatory lag. The larger the opportunity cost the shorter the
expected LAG.
BUDGET. On the one hand, the larger the annual budget of the
commission the better able and more quickly they should be able to
perform their rate review. On the other hand, we might expect
commissions with larger budgets to be more thorough in their
investigation, which would lead to larger periods of regulatory lag.
Overall, we have no strong expectations for this variable.
INFL. If LAG is used as a policy tool we would expect that in times
of high growth rates in a company's variable costs, LAG should be
short. Only in this way will the company have a realistic opportunity to
earn their authorized rate of return.
INTERIM. We expect that the granting of interim rate relief will
cause the commission to lengthen LAG, since at least partial
compensation has been provided.
PREFILE. Joskow |11~ has argued that one of a regulatory
commission's objectives is to minimize conflict and criticism.
During the rate hearing, the commissioners often receive negative
publicity for allowing rate increases. Hence, the commission may reward
the company for waiting longer before filing rate requests by acting
quickly on the company's request when it is filed. We therefore
expect a negative relationship between this variable and LAG.
APPOINT. We include APPOINT to examine whether the
elected-versus-appointed status of commissioners significantly affects
LAG, due presumably to different degrees of political responsiveness.
Previous work by Nelson |13~ and Hagerman and Ratchford |10~, examining
the decisions of state regulatory agencies, did not find this variable
to be significant, although Nowell and Tschirhart |15~ presented
conflicting evidence. If the capture theory of regulation were an
accurate description of regulatory behavior, we would expect to find
that elected commissioners are more responsive to the needs of the
regulated company and APPOINT should have a negative effect on LAG. If
the public interest theory of regulatory behavior were accurate,
however, we would expect this variable to have a positive impact.
Overall, our prior expectations about signs are weak. TERM. This
variable also measures the importance of political pressure on
commission decisions. We have weak expectations regarding its effect.
REQREV and RATEBASE. The size of the revenue request and the
utility's rate base should increase LAG only to the extent that the
commission staff is overburdened. Our expectations are weak regarding
the effects of these two variables.
The variables RATEBASE, INTERIM, INFL, AROR, PREFILE, and REQREV
should have a positive impact on AUTREV due to rate base regulation.
Joskow |11~ found that the requested rate increase is positively related
to authorized revenue. BUDGET will have a negative impact on AUTREV if
the commission takes an adversarial position. We have no strong prior
expectations for the remaining variables, TERM and APPOINT.
Table III. Estimated Parameters(a) for Proportional Hazards Models for Lag
(asymptotic standard errors in parentheses)
Polynomial
Independent Variable Weibull
Hazard-Heterogeneity
Intercept 4.0730(b) 6.6423(b)
(.3248) (1.2323)
AROR -.0380 -.2774(b)
(.08345) (.1391)
BUDGET .6910(b) 2.2125(b)
(.2599) (.7023)
INFL -1.5128 -.6107
(1.3996) (2.3360)
INTERIM .8061(b) .7098
(.3091) (.6105)
PREFILE .2833(b) -.4876(b)
(.09047) (.1896)
APPOINT .6999 -3.2788(b)
(1.0023) (1.5919)
TERM .0920 -.1331
(.1199) (.2002)
Global |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ 271.16 255.32
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~ -107.55 -100.60
Notes:
a. Estimated parameters for the Weibull model |(based on ln(LAG)~ are
multiplied by -1 to allow direct analysis of the effects of each covariate on
LAG.
b. Significant at .05 level using a two-tailed t-test.
IV. Results
Estimated coefficients and asymptotic standard errors as well as
estimated values for the likelihood functions for the model explaining
LAG are reported in Table III. Estimated coefficients (reported as
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~ for the Weibull and |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~ for the polynomial hazard models) allow direct
analysis of the impact of each variable on LAG. The estimated shape
parameter for the Weibull (not reported) indicates a strongly and
significantly increasing hazard. The polynomial hazard model with
unobserved heterogeneity is somewhat preferable to the Weibull model
based on |Mathematical Expression Omitted~. An asymptotic chi-square
test that |Beta~ = 0 (global ||Chi~.sup.2~) is strongly rejected for
both models. A number of important differences in estimated coefficients
are observed between the two models.
The estimated coefficient for BUDGET is positive and significant in
both models indicating that larger budgets are associated with longer
LAG. Experimentation with budget per case yielded no significant
differences. As expected, the coefficient on PREFILE was negative and
significant in both models. The implication is that, all else equal,
commissioners reward companies which have waited longer periods of time
between rate hearings by shortening LAG. Estimated coefficients on the
variables AROR and APPOINT were negative in both cases, TABULAR DATA
OMITTED but only significantly so in the polynomial hazard model. Thus,
some evidence exists that shorter periods of lag are associated with
larger increases in allowed rates of return. Although few commissioners
are elected, the positive sign associated with the variable APPOINT is
consistent with appointed status significantly reducing LAG. As
anticipated, the coefficient on INTERIM is positive, although only
significantly so in the Weibull model, which indicates that commissions
may indeed place less emphasis on shortening LAG when interim rate
relief has been granted.
Two variables, the size of the utility and political affiliation of
the commissioners', were initially included but subsequently
dropped from all equations, since they were found to be highly
insignificant. In addition, the covariates REQREV and RATEBASE were
highly insignificant in the LAG equation and subsequently dropped.
The contribution of individual regressors to the log hazard is
measured using "beta coefficients," defined as the estimated
coefficient times the ratio of the sample standard deviations of the kth
explanatory variable to that of the log hazard. Examining variables with
significant coefficients from the polynomial hazard regression model we
obtain ratios of 4.78 for BUDGET, 2.15 for PREFILE, and 1.83 for APPOINT
relative to AROR. This indicates that BUDGET contributes the greatest
amount of explanatory power and AROR the least amount. Finally, we
regress AUTREV on the same set of explanatory variables reported for the
LAG equation plus REQREV and RATEBASE. Our results for the AUTREV
ordinary least squares regression are given in Table IV.
Estimated coefficients for REQREV and RATEBASE are significant with
the expected signs. The coefficient on the political variable APPOINT is
also positive and significant, indicating that appointed commissioners,
all else equal, are more likely to authorize larger rate increases than
their elected counterparts.
Jointly interpreting the results of the equations explaining AUTREV
and LAG yields some interesting insights. First, while BUDGET does not
seem to impact AUTREV, it does seem to have a positive effect on LAG.
Second, higher AROR and PREFILE shorten LAG but have no significant
impact on AUTREV. Third, when the firms' REQREV is large,
regulatory commissions apparently do not hasten their decisions on the
belief that the opportunity cost of waiting is high. Rather, LAG is
likely to remain constant and the commission will reward the firm
through a larger increase in rates. Since LAG and AUTREV are influenced
by different economic factors; the regulatory commission appears to
employ LAG and AUTREV as substitute policy tools.
We find that appointed commissioners tend to be associated with both
shorter LAG and larger AUTREV, both of which tend to benefit the firm
rather than maximizing social welfare. Apparently when commissioners are
elected by the public they tend to make decisions on LAG and AUTREV that
are more beneficial to society.
V. Conclusion
Regulatory lag has long been identified as a medium through which
regulatory commissions may be able to affect the behavior of the firm.
We explain the period of regulatory lag using maximum likelihood methods
which incorporate a variety of assumptions about the hazard and the
presence of unobserved heterogeneity. We find evidence to suggest that
commissions do use lag and authorized rate increases as substitute
policy tools, which is consistent with economic theory. As the period
since the previous filing for review increases and the market dictates a
high rate of return, the commission typically shortens regulatory lag
rather than providing larger rate increases. Further, elected and
appointed commissioners seem to behave differently in their decisions on
both regulatory lag and authorized price increases.
Appendix
Defining the pdf and cdf of |t.sub.i~ (LAG) as f(|t.sub.i~) and
F(|t.sub.i~), the survivor function is S(|t.sub.i~) = 1 - F(|t.sub.i~).
Further, the baseline hazard, which is the instantaneous probability of
failure at time t given survival to time t, is defined as
||Lambda~.sub.o~ (|t.sub.i~) = |f.sub.o~ (|t.sub.i~)/|S.sub.o~
(|t.sub.i~) = -d ln |S.sub.o~ (|t.sub.i~)/d|t.sub.i~, where the
o-subscript indicates baseline functions, which are independent of
covariates. We consider the well-known proportional hazards
specification which assumes that the hazard, |Lambda~(|t.sub.i~), at
time t for unit i(i = 1,..., n) is |Lambda~(|t.sub.i~, |x.sub.i~,
|Beta~) = ||Lambda~.sub.o~(|t.sub.i~)||Mu~.sub.i~, where ||Mu~.sub.i~ =
|Phi~(|x.sub.i~, |Beta~) measures observed heterogeneity among units,
|x.sub.i~ is a (K X 1) vector of observations on K explanatory variables
for unit i, and |Beta~ is a (K X 1) vector of population parameters.
Henceforth, we suppress |x.sub.i~ and |Beta~ as arguments of |Lambda~
for simplicity.
Note that ||Mu~.sub.i~ affects the hazard ||Lambda~.sub.i~
proportionally and that the baseline hazard fully describes
||Lambda~.sub.i~ when ||Mu~.sub.i~ = 1. We assume that ||Mu~.sub.i~ =
exp(|x|prime~.sub.i~|Beta~) to assure ||Mu~.sub.i~ |is greater than or
equal to~ 0. Further, we assume that the regressors |x.sub.i~ are time
invariant.
We define the unconditional survivor function as |Mathematical
Expression Omitted~. Again suppressing |x.sub.i~ and |Beta~, the
unconditional probability of failure at time t for unit i is
f(|t.sub.i~) = |Lambda~(|t.sub.i~)S(|t.sub.i~), where no observations
are censored. A popular choice of parametric form for ||Lambda~.sub.o~
(|t.sub.i~) has been the Weibull, where |Mathematical Expression
Omitted~.
The polynomial hazard model is considerably more flexible than the
Weibull model, since it allows for a non-monotonic hazard with
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~, where ||Mu~.sub.i~ =
exp(-|x|prime~.sub.i~|Beta~).
Due to unobserved heterogeneity, units with identical |x.sub.i~ and
|t.sub.i~ will have different hazard rates. The conditional hazard given
unobserved heterogeneity is |Lambda~ (|t.sub.i~|where~|Upsilon~~) =
||Lambda~.sub.o(|t.sub.i~)||Mu~.sub.i~|Upsilon~, where for all
individuals the random variable |Upsilon~, 0 |is less than~ |Upsilon~
|is less than~ |infinity~, represents unobserved heterogeneity, has
c.d.f. F(|Upsilon~), E(|Upsilon~) |is less than~ |infinity~, and
variance |Mathematical Expression Omitted~. Following Lancaster |12~ and
Atkinson and Tschirhart |2~, we assume that |Upsilon~ follows the gamma
distribution. See Atkinson and Nowell |1~ for more details.
References
1. Atkinson, Scott E. and Clifford Nowell. "Flexible Estimation of the Hazard in Failure Time Models: An Explanation of Regulatory
Lag." Mimeo, 1992.
2. ----- and John Tschirhart, "Flexible Modelling of
Time-to-Failure in Risky Careers." Review of Economics and
Statistics, November 1986, 558-66.
3. -----, -----, and Todd Sandler, "Terrorism as
Bargaining." Journal of Law and Economics, 1987, 1-21.
4. Averch, Harvey and Leland L. Johnson, "Behavior of the Firm
Under Regulatory Constraint." American Economic Review, December
1962, 1052-69.
5. Bailey, Elizabeth E., "Innovation and Regulation."
Journal of Public Economics, August 1974, 285-95.
6. ----- and Roger D. Coleman, "The Effect of Lagged Regulation
in an Averch-Johnson Model." Bell Journal of Economics, Spring
1971, 278-92.
7. Bawa, Vijay S. and David S. Sibley, "Dynamic Behavior of a
Firm Subject to Stochastic Regulatory Review." International
Economic Review, October 1980, 627-42.
8. Bloom, David E. and Mark R. Killingsworth, "Correcting for
Truncation Bias Caused by a Latent Truncation Variable," Journal of
Econometrics, January 1985, 131-35.
9. Costello, Kenneth W., "Electing Regulators: The Case of
Public Utility Commissioners." Yale Journal on Regulation, January
1984, 83-105.
10. Hagerman, Robert L. and Brian T. Ratchford, "Some
Determinants of Allowed Rates of Return on Equity to Electric
Utilities." Bell Journal of Economics, Spring 1978, 48-65.
11. Joskow, Paul L., "The Determination of the Allowed Rate of
Return in a Formal Regulatory Hearing." Bell Journal of Economics,
Autumn 1972, 632-44.
12. Lancaster, Tony, "Econometric Methods for the Duration of
Unemployment." Econometrica, July 1979, 939-56.
13. Nelson, Randy A., "An Empirical Test of the Ramsey Theory and Stigler-Peltzman Theory of Public Utility Pricing." Economic
Inquiry, April 1982, 277-90.
14. National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners. Annual
Report of Utility and Carrier Regulation. Washington, D.C. 1978-1984.
15. Nowell, Clifford and John Tschirhart, "The Public Utility
Regulatory Act and Regulatory Behavior." Journal of Regulatory
Economics, March 1990, 21-36.
16. Primeaux, Walter J., Jr. and Patrick C. Mann, "Regulator
Selection Methods and Electricity Prices." Land Economics, February
1986, 1-13.
17. Roberts, R. Blaine, G. S. Maddala, and Gregory Enholm,
"Determinants of the Requested Rate of Return and the Rate of
Return Granted in a Formal Regulatory Process." Bell Journal of
Economics, Autumn 1978, 611-21.
18. Sappington, David, "Strategic Firm Behavior Under a Dynamic
Regulatory Adjustment Process." Bell Journal of Economics, Spring
1980, 360-72.
19. Sweeney, George, "Adoption and Cost-Saving Innovations by a
Regulated Firm." American Economic Review, June 1981, 437-47.
20. Wendel, James, "Firm-Regulator Interaction with Respect to
Firm Cost Reduction Activities." Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn
1976, 631-40.