External debt and policy controversy in Korea.
Cho, Jae Ho
I. Introduction
Korea has a reputation for being one of the fastest developing
countries in the world, experiencing rapid growth since 1963. Real GNP grew at an average annual rate of 9.0 percent between 1963-93. As a
result, Korea's status changed from an underdeveloped country in
the 1960s to an upper mid-level developing country in the 1990s. It is
well known that foreign debt and the government's active economic
policy played an important role in her economic growth.
In addition, the country has a dramatic history of external debt
problems. In the early 1980s, Korea was one of the largest debtor
nations in the world. Today many economists have come to the consensus
that Korea's external debt is no longer a major problem because
during the late 1980s the country experienced current account surpluses.
In 1987, in the period of current account surplus, the Korean
government revised a schedule for repaying existing debt, and started to
repay the debt intensively. At the time, there were different opinions
about dealing with the existing current account surpluses. Balassa and
Williamson [1] argued that the Korean government should implement an
adjustment policy by reducing the current account surpluses. On the
other hand, Dombusch and Park [4] did not consider an adjustment policy
to be necessary.
In the mid 1990s, the favorable external conditions including a
strong yen continue, and the Korean government is demanding a set of
structural reforms prior to the establishment of the WTO (World Trade
Organization). This paper discusses in detail the policy controversy
developed in 1987. With the lesson from the controversy we could get a
useful policy direction for the Korean economy in the period of the WTO.
This paper also provides the policy implication proposed by the Korean
government for those who want to understand the Korean economy and for
the policy makers who want to influence it.
This paper consists of four sections. Section II reviews the effect
of favorable conditions on the Korean economy in the period of 1980s,
and introduces the policy controversy among Balassa-Williamson,
Dornbusch-Park, and the Korean government in its dealing with the
current surpluses. To evaluate the policy controversy, section III
establishes the neoclassical growth model. After investigating the
nature of the model, a simulation for the Korean economy is conducted.
Section IV concludes with a summary of the Balassa-Williamson and the
Dornbusch-Park positions.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED]
II. The Impact of the "Three Lows" and Policy Controversy
Korea's successful pursuit of an export-led development strategy
has achieved rapid economic growth and industrialization since the early
1960s. Even though Korea's economic performance is striking
compared to other developing countries, in the 1970s the economy was
coupled with unfavorable factors such as two oil shocks, political
uncertainty, massive investment on heavy industries, and recession in
the world economy. Theses adverse effects slackened growth and led to
increasing foreign borrowing in the early 1980s. At that time, it seemed
that the country might have overborrowed by international standards.
Through successful change in policies in the early 1980s, the country
restored growth, lowered inflation, and reduced the current account
deficit. In addition, outward economic conditions became more favorable
in the mid 1980s because of the decline in oil prices, the decline in
world interest rate, and the appreciation of the Japanese yen, all of
which are often called the "three lows." Table I shows the
trends of the "three lows." The individual impact of the
"three lows" on the trade performance is the followings.
The Appreciation of the Japanese Yen
The strong yen had mixed effects on Korea's current account. A
positive effect was that the sharp appreciation of the yen against the
U.S. dollar increased the price competitiveness of major Korean exports
such as cars and electronics items in the U.S. market. On the other
hand, the strong yen increased the import price of capital goods from
Japan and in turn had adverse impacts on the current account. Such mixed
effects were characteristic of the appreciation of the Japanese yen. It
is clear that the effect on balance of payments in the mid 1980s was
positive.
The Fall in the Oil Price
Korea relies entirely on the import of crude oil. Payment for
imported crude oil has been a great burden on the country's
development. In fact, crude oil was one of the leading import items
during the development period. In the early 1980s the ratio of payment
for oil to total imports averaged about 25 percent. After the oil price
dropped from $34.1 per barrel in 1981 to about $13.9 in 1988, its ratio
was reduced to less than 10 percent even though oil consumption rose. As
a result, the 15 percent residual resulted in reducing the economic
cost, leading to reduced price levels. The falling oil price level also
improved price competitiveness of export products, generating an
increase in the real GNP. The positive effects of the fall in oil price
were partially offset by import increases occasioned by the rising real
GNP. The mixed effects can be examined by evaluating the decomposition of the current account. By applying this method, the author found that
falling oil prices had the strongest positive impact on the current
account surplus among the "three lows."
The Decline in the World Interest Rate
The world interest rate fell from 16.5 percent in 1981 to 6.8 percent
in 1986, which was good news for a heavily indebted country like Korea.
The decline in the interest rates reduced the debt burden of the Korean
government and of Korean banks. The lower burden of public debt improved
the budget balance, permitting debt repayment; it may also have led to
increased public consumption and investment expenditures. The lower
burden of private debt also increased the availability of funds for
investment purposes.
With the help of the "three lows," Korea posted its first
current account surplus in 1986, which amounted to some 4.9 percent of
GNP. The economic growth rate was recorded at 11.9%, 12.3% and 12.0% in
1986, 1987, and 1988 respectively. The consumer price index almost
stabilized at the 2-3 percent inflation in that period. Because of its
high economic performance, as reported in Table I, Korea's net
foreign debt declined in absolute terms.
In the late 1980s, given the large current account surplus,
government policy regarding management of external debt concentrated on
repayment of external debt. A number of proposed loans were rejected by
the government. Furthermore, the schedule for repaying existing debt was
revised. The original target for paying off outstanding debt in the
Sixth Five Year Plan (1987-91), established in 1986, was to owe $13.5
billion to foreign investors in 1991. In 1987, during the period of
current account surplus, this target was revised to result in a net
credit position by the end of 1991. This policy would be natural for a
heavily indebted country like Korea. But there was some disagreement
about such a presumably impatient plan. Balassa and Williamson [1, 45]
argued that such a rapid rundown in debt might incur a misallocation of
resources, and suggested that the country should increase investment and
consumption spending while keeping a modest current account deficit of 1
or 2 billion dollars because the marginal product of capital far
exceeded the world interest rate. They also suggested that the country
should take advantage of currently favorable external conditions to
start the adjustment process; resulting in much structural strength for
the Korean economy without going into recession. In addition, they
believed that Korea was overshooting the target, and that it should
continue to pursue the sustained growth policy for the long run while
keeping a modest current account deficit.
On the other hand, Dornbusch and Park [4] agreed that considering the
prevailing uncertainty in the word and domestic labor market development, the large Korean current account surplus might not last
long, and that the "three lows" would disappear soon.
Therefore, it seemed that the dramatic government action to eliminate
the surplus would be premature. They thought that such a large current
account surplus was a temporary phenomenon and it might incur trade
conflict with developed countries. Accordingly, they suggested that the
government trim the current account surplus to the point of possibly
evading U.S. trade friction. However, they stressed much more emphasis
on a bilateral adjustment through a rapid increase in imports rather
than on a broad-based policy as Balassa and Williamson suggested.
According to the policy argument, the critical question was if the
government plan for being in a creditor position by the end of 1991 was
an optimal strategy for the economy. It is clear that marginal
productivity exceeded the world interest rate in Korea in the 1980s.(1)
But this was not sufficient to solve the controversy. The answer should
be obtained formally. In the following section, a general dynamic
equilibrium approach will be presented. The dynamic model is used to
describe and simulate the current situation in the Korean economy which
will provide a clearer interpretation of the policy controversy.
III. A Dynamic Model and Simulation Results
The concept of current account reflects an intertemporal rather than
a static decision on levels of savings and investment. Therefore a model
for the policy argument should be dynamic and relevant to the Korean
Economy. A dynamic model based upon Blanchard and Fischer [2] will be
developed in this section.
The Dynamic Model
The model for a small economy consists of dynamic budget constraints and a lifetime utility function. The economy is composed of a single,
infinitely-lived representative economic agent. The economic agent
maximizes the utility function under the budget constraint and produces
a single good by means of a constant returns technology. The production
of a good is divided into consumption, investment spending, net export,
and net interest payments on existing debt. The current account deficit
denoted by the change in debt, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], is
equal to net interest payment minus net exports of goods. Investment
spending is the sum of the investment itself, i(t), plus the adjustment
cost, [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The adjustment cost function
z(,) is linearly homogeneous in investment goods and capital stock. The
rate of capital depreciation ([Delta]) is positive. The world interest
rate is assumed to be constant. Repudiation risk, potential liquidity
constraints, and insolvency risk are assumed away. Based upon these
conditions, the agent determines optimal consumption and investment
subjected to dynamic budget constraints. The agent's optimization
problem is given by,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Rho] is the agent's rate of time preference, f([k.sub.t])
is a neo-classical production function, and [Tau] is a shift parameter.
The first order conditions can be easily derived.(2) With slight
modifications of the first order conditions and budget constraints, a
dynamic system can be reduced into four differential equations.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
The existence and uniqueness of the steady state are ensured by the
assumptions already made regarding the utility (concave) and budget
constant (convex). An imposer feature of this system is that it is
"block recursive," implying that the dynamics of (q, k) are
independent of shocks originating from consumption - current account
dynamics. At a neighborhood around the equilibrium, the dynamics of (q,
k) can be rewritten as,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Since the determinant of the sub matrix for [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], is negative, one negative eigenvalue, denoted by [Theta], is
such that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Delta], r, [Tau], [Psi][prime](0), [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted], and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] represents the steady stare value of capital. Thus,
the long run equilibrium is a saddle point.
Assuming that the economy starts out with initial stocks ([k.sub.0],
[b.sub.0]), the stable dynamic paths followed by k and q are given by(3)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Finely, the steady state values me given by(4)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Dynamic Effects of Change in Parameters
One can analyze the dynamic effects of changes in the parameters in
the model. This section places emphasis on the change in two key
parameters: a shift parameter of productivity level, [Tau], and the
world interest rate, r. As discussed later, the effects of these two
parameters are closely related to that of the "three lows" on
the Korean economy in the mid 1980s. These effects should be also
distinguished between a temporary and a permanent one because Dornbusch
and Park considered the "three lows" as a temporary phenomenon
while Balassa and Williamson as a permanent phenomenon. Depending on the
duration of the impacts, the response of the economy is different.
Response to Permanent Shocks. A permanent increase in productivity
level ([Tau]) and a drop in interest rates (r) increase the new steady
state value of capital and change the value of the characteristic root,
which, when the changes occur, lead to the upward jumps in the shadow
price of capital (q), investment (i), output (f(k)), and consumption (c)
instantaneously (and permanently). For the formal proofs for this, the
reader is referred to Cho [3].
Response to Temporary Shocks. Suppose that at time (t = 0), [Tau]
increases and r decreases, but both are expected to be restored to their
original levels at time (t = T). As soon as the shocks occur, the shadow
price (q) and investment (i) will jump instantaneously (and
temporarily). As a result of the initial rise in (q) and (i), capital
and external debt begin to accumulate analogous to reasons noted in
connection with the permanent shocks. At the same time consumption will
increase by precisely the same amount as if the shocks were permanent.
The accumulation of capital and debt will serve as initial conditions
for the dynamic beyond time (t = T) when the shocks revert permanently
to their original level. They then will determine the new steady state
of equilibrium. With no new information being received at the time (t =
T), the control variables will not jump any more.
The "Three Lows," Openness Policy, and Output Function
Given the dynamic system established above, we can return to the
policy controversy developed in 1987. As discussed previously, the
economy had quickly overcome the debt problem and had recorded current
account surpluses in the mid 1980s. Clearly, the recovery of the economy
was mainly due to two factors: favorable external conditions such as the
"three lows" and the outward oriented policy sustained since
the 1960s. The outward oriented policy under the "three lows"
had such a great impact on economic expansion that the economy recovered
from the ill effects caused by the domestic and the foreign recessions
of the 1970s.
The essence of the policy controversy is about whether or not it was
optimal for Korea to reduce its foreign debt levels. To answer the
question under the established framework, one could introduce the
impacts of the "three lows" on the outward oriented economy
into the model. Then the remaining questions are why and how the
"three lows" and the outward oriented policy contribute to an
increase in productivity and economic growth in the period of the
"three lows." For these questions, we need to review the
recent development theory briefly.
Recently much of the literature has used cross country regression to
search for empirical linkages between long run growth rates and a
variety of openness variables. For this study, many economists have
developed exogenous and endogenous growth models as well, but
qualitatively the derived results are likely to be the same. They find a
positive and robust relationship between growth and openness variables.
Specifically, a study developed by Romer [6] argues that the theoretical
ties between growth and trade seem to run through improved productivity.
This study implies that openness to trade results not only in raising
output but also in improving the marginal product of capital through
creation of new investment opportunities. In this sense, openness to
trade and new investment spending become complementary factors of
production, determining the productivity of the economy. Absence of
complementarity would mean a lower rate of growth of productivity or
marginal product of capital, hence lower investment incentives with high
export opportunities and expansion, a result that is not consistent with
existing empirical evidence.
Based upon this theoretical background in which most of the
theoretical research has explicitly focused on the Asian miracles
including Korea, it is not difficult to infer that the effect of more
variation in Korea's trade performance engendered by the
"three lows" is thought to be related to the variation of the
technological factor.
Returning to the model for the analysis of these effects, the
production function in the above model can be modified. Under the
assumption that the "three lows" significantly affected
Korea's economic growth and productivity through the increase in
trade performance, the reduced form can be disentangled by introducing
the price (terms of trade) effect on the production function in the
model. The world interest rate is already included in the model.
Given a simple model in which the price effect on output is included,
the output function in terms of labor in efficiency units, [y.sub.t]
[equivalent to] [Y.sub.t]/[L.sub.t] exp([Lambda]t), is derived as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where A is a constant, [P.sub.x] and [P.sub.n] are the price of a
tradable good and imported oil in terms of the price of import, and
[Alpha], [Beta] are the share of capital and oil import respectively.
The derivation of Korea's net output function is in Appendix A.
Concerning the effect of the "three lows" on the economy,
it is important to describe the [Tau] function using parameter values.
Given terms of trade and other parameters values (see the next section),
the trend of the [Tau] function is shown in Figure 1. It has been
continuously increasing from 1986. The trend is consistent with the
assumption of productivity improvement during "the three lows"
period. Since [Alpha] + [Beta] [less than] 1, the net output function
has a concave shape consistent with the assumption made in the model in
the previous section.
Simulation Results
The model is used to simulate the Korean economy from 1981 to 1992 to
evaluate the policy controversy. The historical simulation is carried
out respectively for two periods: before "the three lows"
period (1981-85) and during "the three lows" period (1986-92).
Given actual parameter values in Table II, the simulation for the period
before "the three lows" will be calibrated to obtain other
appropriate parameter values which cannot be directly obtained from the
data. Then using these parameter values as well as the new values of the
productivity and the world interest rates after the shocks, the model
will simulate the economic performance for the period during the
"three lows." The simulation for this period is divided into
two cases, i.e., the cases of permanent shock and temporary shock. The
duration of the temporary shock is assumed to have lasted for 4 years -
from 1986 to 1989. This assumption is based upon the observation that
the [Tau] function continuously increased during that period and then
slightly declined from 1990. The duration of the permanent shock is
assumed to have continued from 1986 for the entire period of the
simulation.
For a simulation, the structure of the model and parameter values can
be specified. The utility function is assumed to be logarithmic and
u([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t]) = [L.sub.t] ln([C.sub.t], [L.sub.t]). The
investment function [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] is of a familiar
form [I.sub.t][1 + [Phi]([I.sub.t]/[K.sub.t])], where [Phi] is a
coefficient of adjustment cost and is linear. Also, all variables are
divided by labor in efficiency units ([y.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[Y.sub.t]/[L.sub.t] exp([Lambda]t)) rather than labor units, where
[Lambda] is the Harrod neutral technological progress. It can also
easily be shown that the modified model has the same characteristic of
dynamics as the previous one in section III. The only differences are in
the form of expression. The equations for simulations and methods are
described in Appendix B.
There are several parameters in the model. The first, the world
interest rates (r) in the model is defined as the interest rate paid by
Korea. The average of the actual interest rate paid by Korea during
1981-85 is 9.0%. In the case of the permanent shock since 1986, 7% is
assumed to hold for the entire period of simulation. In the temporary
case, it is assumed that an interest rate of 7% continues during 1986-89
and then increases to 8.0% in 1990. The value of [Tau] in equation (6),
as shown in Figure 1, is calculated by 0.58 in 1985 which increases to
0.70 in 1986 because of the "three lows." In the permanent
case, this value is assumed to maintain its level for the entire period
of simulation. In the temporary case, it is assumed to be 0.70 during
1986-89 and then decreases to 0.64.
The coefficient of the adjustment cost function ([Phi]) and the rate
of technological progress ([Lambda]) are chosen to be 1.5 and 4.5%
respectively based upon the results of the calibration of actual and
optimal investments and consumption. These values are assumed to be the
same for the entire period of the simulation. The growth rate of
employee population (n) and the rate of depreciation are given to be
2.0% and 5%. Capital share ([Pi] = [Alpha]/(1 - [Beta])) and constant
term (A) in equation (6) are estimated to be 0.31 and 2.0
respectively.(5) These values are obtained through the estimation of the
production function. Finally, in equation (2) for the characteristic
root ([Theta]), [Psi][prime](0) is chosen to be 0.06 in consideration of
optimal investment and actual investment.
The values of parameter r and [Tau] are summarized in Table II. In
another empirical study of the Korean economy, Park and An [5] assumed
the values of capital share, adjustment cost coefficient, the rate of
technological progress, and the rate of depreciation are assumed to be
0.35, 1.5, 4%, and 5% respectively. These values are similar to those in
this paper. Given the structure of the dynamic model and the parameter
values, the simulation for the Korean economy before the "three
lows" (1981-85) can be carried out as illustrated in Figure 2 and
Figure 3(a). Before the "three lows," the simulation results
in the root mean square percent errors of investment, capital stock,
GDP, consumption, and debt to be 3.5%, 2.2%, 3.8%, 3.5% and 4.3%
respectively. Therefore, assuming the above parameters, the simulated
data before the "three lows" trace the actual data quite
accurately.(6)
Response to Permanent Shocks. During the "three lows," the
simulation is conducted in both the temporary and the permanent cases.
Given the parameter values in Table II, the initial levels of
([Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Theta]) are calculated using the
steady state condition and equation (2) (For details, see Appendix B.)
From the calculation, the steady state level of capital based upon the
1985 parameter's values is 10.42 in efficiency labor units and it
increases to 17.13. The characteristic root decreases from -0.064 to
-0.071. The new steady state levels of ([Mathematical Expression
Omitted], [Theta]) in turn determine the new optimal paths of control
variables. Given the new values of steady state capital stock and
characteristic root after the positive permanent shocks, the sizes of
the jump of control variables are calculated as follows. The initial
levels of the variables are derived in Appendix B. Investment spending
calculated by labor in efficiency units in 1985 is 1.14; it then rises
to 1.63 in 1986. By the same token, [q.sub.0] is calculated as 1.18 in
1985 and it then jumps to 1.48 in 1986. Also the shift in consumption is
calculated from 2.90 in 1985 to 3.30 in 1986. Finally, the simulated
level of GDP due to the permanent shocks jumps from 4.39 in 1985 to 5.34
in 1986. These results are summarized in Table III.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED]
Response to Temporary Shocks. Using the same procedure as the
permanent case, the new steady state level of capital and the
characteristic root are calculated as 12.74 in efficiency labor unit and
-0.066 respectively. The size of the jump of the control variables are
calculated in Table III.
Switching the unit from an efficiency unit to an actual value, the
shift in optimal investment spending, capital stock, and GDP are
depicted in Figure 2 (The units in x-axis and y-axis are year and
trillion won respectively). In the permanent case, the transitional
dynamics in Figure 2 show higher levels of simulated data, denoted by a
line, for GDP, investment, and capital stock than do the actual data,
denoted by a dotted line, in the late 1980s.
The trends of dynamic paths of the economic variables are consistent
with the results derived in section III. Specifically, for the period
1986-89, the simulated path of investment exceeds the actual path of
investment, and the trend of investment has reversed for 1990-92. During
the period of 1986-89, the path showed that investment spending was not
sufficiently raised in the period of the high level of productivity.
Instead the government concentrated on the repayment of external debts.
So this policy resulted in a reduction of the private firm's
motivation for new investment. The growth rates of equipment investment
(the machinery purchases among equipment investment) in 1986, 1987, and
1989 were 19.0% (5.6 trillion won), 13.0% (6.0 trillion won), and 15.2%
(8.9 trillion won). The levels of the machinery purchase contrasted with
the 18.3 trillion won in 1990, and 20.2 trillion won in 1991 when the
government started adjustment policy. In comparison, in the period of
1976-78 when there was a world recession, the average growth rate of the
equipment investment was 40%. These facts thus imply that investment
spending including manufacturing did not increase as much as the
domestic productivity improvement as a result of the "three
lows."
During the period of 1990-92, the trend has reversed i.e., the actual
investment exceeds the simulated. This was mainly caused by the early
1990s overinvestment in construction due to real estate speculation.
According to the data, the growth rate of construction investment in
1986 was 3.1 percent, which rose to 29.1 percent in 1990, and in a year
the investment of housing grew 61.5% in 1989. As a result, construction
investment in the early 1990s far exceeded equipment investment. This
overinvestment in construction was not caused by the improvement in
productivity but was caused by the skyrocketing increase of capital gain
in the real estate market. This phenomenon originated in the
misallocation of resources, pointed out by Balassa and Williamson [1].
The Korean government's mismanagement of its current account
surplus resulted in the construction boom in the early 1990s.
In the temporary case, the transitional dynamics in Figure 2 show
lower levels of simulated data, denoted by a long dotted line, for
consumption, investment, GDP, and capital stock than do the actual data
in the late 1980s. These results imply that the temporary case does not
fit well with the actual data.
Finally, as depicted in Figure 3(a) the simulated level of net
foreign debt, deflated by the GDP deflator in terms of the won currency,
increased for the first part of the boom period and then declined
slightly. The large gap between the optimal and actual debt was caused
by the government's repayment of the external debt during that
period. Furthermore, in the early 1990s the simulated data for debt, in
the temporary case, tends to rise as the "three lows" are
assumed to have disappeared at the end of 1989.
One can also examine the trend of the ratio of net debt to GDP. The
upper line in Figure 3(b) which declines, represents the trend of the
ratio of debt to GDP when the actual level of consumption is used in the
simulation. It implies that if the Korean economy had followed an
optimal path of investment in 1986-89 given the actual level of
consumption, the ratio of net debt to GDP eventually could have
decreased without active government intervention against the external
debt problem. This means that the economy could have an increase in
structural strengthening if the economy had higher levels of investment
spending by taking advantages of the improvement in productivity during
the "three lows" period. This view confirms the Balassa and
Williamson position. On the other hand, Dornbusch and Park [4, 433]
argued that "Korea's investment rate is more than 30 percent
of GNP. There is little to suggest that capital imports are necessary
because capital is in short supply." This view is neither supported
by the result of the simulation nor by the recent study concerning the
correlation amongst the openness policy, output growth, and
productivity. Even during 1977-79, when Korea suffered from unfavorable
external conditions, the average investment rate was recorded at 32.3%,
which exceeded the investment rate of 31.3% during 1987-89, when
favorable conditions were apparent. Furthermore, the Korean government
and Dornbusch-Park's positions were inconsistent with the
export-led economic policy which has been pursued since the 1960s.
In the early 1990s, the government had realized this and addressed
this with the adjustment policy. But the economic circumstance became
worse because of the increasing pressure of trade openness and
appreciation of won from the developed countries. Furthermore, the
effect of the "three lows" was reduced as time passed. This
ill-timed policy and the adverse effect of the debt repayment policy
suppressed economic growth, and current account recorded in deficits in
the early 1990s. In 1992, the current account deficit was 4.6 billion
dollars, and the GNP growth rate was 5.0 percent, the lowest (except
1980) over the developing period.
IV. Conclusion
This paper has analyzed the performance of the Korean economy
focusing on external debt, economic growth, and the pertinence of the
Balassa-Williamson position. In conclusion, according to the simulation
results and other evidences, a part of the improvement in productivity
during the boom period was likely to be temporary. There was
nevertheless a sufficiently permanent component to justify adjustment of
the surplus developed by 1987. Thus, if the Korean government had
accepted Balassa and Williamson's suggestion during the boom
period, the Korean economy would have maintained a higher level of
economic growth with an optimal level of external debt. In this context,
the revised Sixth Five Year Plan's proposal that Korea be in a
creditor position in 1991 is not a well established plan.
Through the policy controversy, we can review the characteristics of
the Korean Economy and then suggest a policy direction based upon the
lesson from it. Korean economic growth is mainly led by export
expansion. Since export expansion depends on the world's economic
situation, the Korean economy has fluctuated with the word economy.
Rapid but sharply fluctuating growth has been a prominent characteristic
of Korean development. Therefore, one can call the Korean economy a
"bicycle economy." To run a "bicycle economy"
properly, it is necessary to make rules for economic policies.
First, to maintain its speed, the country should continue its export
promotion policy through globalization of the economy. This strategy is
consistent with the policy pursued since the 1960s. To increase the
volume of export, Korean firms and the government should promote the
upgrading of Korea's industries toward continued product
specialization in favor of higher valued-added goods. These efforts are
only possible by raising the level of technology. Second, to maintain
its balance, the country needs to implement an adjustment policy
concentrated on increasing domestic demand. A policy for increasing
domestic spending should not only cause the stability of the economy but
also provide a base for domestic industries, raising their competitive
capability in the world market. The larger the domestic demand, the more
the reduction in the fluctuation of the Korean economy due to external
shocks. Also, the industries that survive in the domestic market can
compete well in the hostile world economic environment.
The necessity of the openness and the globalization of the Korean
economy are consistent with the ideas of the WTO (World Trade
Organization) which prepares to start in 1995. On the departure of the
new world trade system, Korea is demanding a set of adjustment policies
to adjust to the hostile external environment. The Korean economy should
consider the new trade system as another opportunity, which is a
different economic environment, to implement an adjustment policy to
give structural strength for the Korean economy. As experienced in the
late 1980s, if the government successfully adjusts to the new trade
system in an active manner rather than a passive one, it will improve
its productivity and economic growth. By doing so, the Korean economy
can put one more step towards the level of a developed economy.
Appendix A
The purpose of the following simple model is to disentangle the
parameter, [Tau], of Korea's output function in order to include
the effect of price changes on the output function. Assume the following
circumstances: (1) the economy produces an export good (X) which is
exchanged in the world market for a consumption good (M). (2) The price
of a tradable good and imported oil in terms of the price of M,
[P.sub.x] and [P.sub.n], respectively, are beyond the control of the
economy. (3) Three inputs, capital (K), labor (L), and imported oil (N),
are used in the production of (X): X = G(K, N, Lexp([Lambda]t)). (4) Net
output (output minus the cost of imported oil) should be maximized.
Given these assumptions, a simple model is:
Max [p.sub.x]G(K, N, L exp([Lambda]t)) - [p.sub.n]N.
To maximize the net output with respect to N, the first order
condition should be satisfied
[Delta]G/[Delta]N = [p.sub.n]/[p.sub.x].
Net output function is defined by
[Y.Sub.T] [equivalent to] [P.sub.x][G(K, N, L exp([Lambda]t)) -
N[Delta]G/[Delta]N]. (1)
The first order condition becomes [Delta]K/[Delta]N -
[Beta]A[K.sup.[Alpha]][N.sup.[Beta]-1] [(L exp([Lambda]t)).sup.[Gamma]]
= [p.sub.n]/[p.sub.x], and the optimal choice of N is derived by
[N.sup.[Beta]] = [([Beta][p.sub.x]/[p.sub.n]).sup.[Beta]/(1-[Beta])][(L exp([Lambda]t)).sup.[Beta][Gamma]/(1-[Beta])][K.sup.[Alpha][Beta]/(1-[Beta ])]. (2)
Substituting (2) into (1), then
[Y.sub.t] = (1 -[Beta])[p.sub.x]([Beta][p.sub.x][([Beta][p.sub.x]/[p.sub.n]).sup.[Beta]/( 1-[Beta])] [A.sup.1/(1-[Beta])][(L
exp([Gamma]t)).sup.[Gamma]/(1-[Beta])][K.sup.[Alpha][Beta]/(1-[Beta])]
[equivalent to] [Tau]([Beta],[p.sub.x],[p.sub.n])[A.sup.1/(1-[Beta])][(L exp([Lambda]t)).sup.[Gamma]/(1-[Beta])][K.sup.[Beta]/(1-[Beta])].
From the equation, [Tau] is defined as (1 -
[Beta])[p.sub.x][([Beta][p.sub.x]/[p.sub.n]).sup.[Beta]/(1-[Beta])].
Then given the condition of [Alpha] + [Beta] + [Gamma] = 1, the output
function labor in efficiency units, [y.sub.t] [equivalent to]
[Y.sub.t]/[L.sub.t] exp([Lambda]t), is represented by [y.sub.t] =
[Tau]([p.sub.x], [p.sub.n], [Beta])[A.sup.1/(1-[Beta])] [Mathematical
Expression Omitted].
Appendix B
The following equations are used for simulations.
Debt: [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Capital accumulation function: [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Investment function: [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Consumption function: [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Output function: [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The investment function is derived by combining the marginal cost of
investment and the present value of the marginal product (see footnote 2). If r = p + [Lambda], consumption in efficiency units is constant so
that, along the optimal path, consumption per capita grows at the rate
of technological progress ([Lambda]). This assumption is used here for
the simulation of consumption. Finally the initial levels of the control
variables in the dynamic model are given by:
consumption: [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
the shadow price of capital: [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
investment: [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
(The initial level of investment is derived based upon the following
equations:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
The steady state level of capital [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
is obtained by the steady state condition in equation (5): [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], so it holds [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [pi] = [Alpha]/(1 - [Beta]), [A.sup.*] = [A.sup.1/(1-[Beta])].
Finally the path of the marginal product of capital is determined by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the celebration
meeting for professor Duk Choong Kim's birth held in Seoul in 1994,
and at the Southern Economic Associations's annual conference in
Orlando, Florida in November of 1994. The author wishes to thank
professor Bela Balassa, Carl Christ, Enrica Detragiache, and an
anonymous referee for their helpful comments. The financial support from
the chief director of the University of Ulsan is greatly acknowledged.
1. According to the author's calculation using the values of the
parameters in section III, the marginal product of capital in 1985 was
16.4 percent, while the interest rate paid by the Korean economy was 9.5
percent.
2. The first conditions for investment and consumption are derived by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [Epsilon] = -u[prime]/u[double
prime][c.sub.t] [center dot] [q.sub.t] is the shadow price of capital.
The dynamic of capital stock can be expressed in terms of [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] where [q.sub.t] [greater than or equal to] 1, it
holds it [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The solvency condition is
given as [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
3. Equation (4) is obtained as follows. [Mathematical Expression
Omitted].
4. Under the assumption of ([Rho] = r), four differrential equations
reduce to three differential equations with four unknown variables:
([Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted]).
If [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is given as a parameter such as the
initial consumption level ([c.sub.0]), the steady state of
([Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]) are then determined by the given
([c.sub.0]) and ([Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted]). (If [Rho] [not
equal to] r, consumption should be zero in the steady state because the
equation for consumption becomes [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. This
is not a reasonable result.)
5. The production function between 1974-92 where (N) is oil input is
estimated.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
([R.sup.2] = 0.68, number of observations are 17; the coefficient
standard errors are in parentheses)
6. The investigation of robustness of economic variables during the
"three lows" period of 1987-92 is not necessary. The reason is
that the simulated results over that period are derived on the
assumption that the Korean government implemented the adjustment policy
optimally.
References
1. Balassa, Bela and John Williamson. Adjusting to Success, Balance
of Payment Policy in the East Asian NICs. Washington D.C.: Institute for
International Economics, 1987.
2. Blanchard, Olivier J. and Stanley Fischer. Lectures on
Macroeconomics. Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT press, 1989.
3. Cho, Jae Ho. "External Debt and Openness Policy in
Korea," Ph.D. dissertation, The Johns Hopkins University, 1992.
4. Dornbusch, R. and Y. C. Park, "Korean Growth Policy."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1987.
5. Park, W. A. and J. H. An. "Savings, Investment and the
External Debt in Korea." Korea Development Institute Working Paper,
no. 8812, 1988.
6. Romer, Paul M. "Cross Country Determinations of Growth and
Technological Change." The World Bank Working Paper, 1989.