Do drinkers earn less?
Heien, Dale M.
I. Introduction
Theoretical work by Becker and others on human capital led initially
to empirical research on the determinates of earnings. Interest in human
capital has now spread to other areas, especially health. This movement
is in conjunction with societal concerns regarding the role of diet and
environmental factors on human well-being and performance. Following
Becker [1] and Grossman [9], economists expect to find a significant
relationship between health and earnings. Health aspects of human
capital have been extensively explored since the early work of Grossman
[9; 10]. Good health is both beyond the control of the individual
(exogenous) as a result of genetic factors and random events, and
controllable (endogenous) through the regulation of activities such as
smoking, drinking, eating, exercise and other informed choices. This
study examines the relation between earnings and drinking.
Curiously, little rigorous empirical work has been done on the
relation between earnings and drinking. Irving Fisher's claim to
the contrary,(1) there is little evidence that prohibition led to
substantial, if any, productivity increases. Although it is established
that excessive drinking leads to poor health, the empirical evidence
regarding earnings and drinking is mixed and inconclusive. According to the U.S. Government, abusive drinkers earn less. In their biennial
reports to Congress, the National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and
Alcoholism (NIAAA) estimates the "economic cost to society" of
alcohol abuse. Approximately half of this cost arises from the estimated
loss in earnings (productivity) due to abusive drinking.(2) Their
approach consists of estimating a wage equation which includes human
capital variables as well as a dichotomous abusive drinking variable and
quantity of alcohol consumed.(3)
Berger and Leigh [3] used a sample selection model to test whether
drinkers earned more or less than nondrinkers. They divided their sample
(from the 1972-73 Quality of Employment Survey) into two categories:
drinkers and nondrinkers. Using a sample selection correction estimator,
hedonic wage regressions for each category (and by sex) were estimated.
They found that drinkers (moderate and abusive combined) earned more
than nondrinkers. Comparisons were then made between wages from each
regression with demographic and human capital variables set at the same
levels. The drinkers earned more in all cases. Model [21] found positive
and significant effects on income and wages for both moderate and heavy
alcohol use. Model used the National Household Survey on Alcohol and
Drug Abuse: 1984. Heien and Pittman [13] using the same data and
specification as the 1984 NIAAA study, but a different econometric
procedure found a positive, but not significant, effect of alcohol on
earnings. Manning et al. [20] found that alcohol consumption had no
effect on days lost from work or on visits to the doctor. Work by Kenkel
and Ribar [16] on alcohol use by young adults shows mixed effects for
men versus women. Recent work by French and Zarkin [8] and Heien [12]
develop and test models along the lines discussed below.
An alternative approach is to examine the effect of psychiatric
diagnoses on earnings, since alcoholism is defined in those terms. Using
data containing information on DSM (Diagnostic and Statistical Manual)
criterion, Benham and Benham [2] found that alcoholism was not a
statistically significant factor in either earnings or employment. The
effects were mixed in sign. The most recent NIAAA study(4) uses the
Epidemiologic Catchment Area data base and employs the DSMALC criterion
for alcoholism. By this definition, alcoholics were found to have lower
earnings.(5) Mullahy and Sindelar [23] used the DSMALC criterion and
found similar results. Excellent reviews of the work in this area can be
found in Cook [6] and Mullahy [22].
These previous studies have either used hedonic regressions and/or
sample partitioning methods to test for the effect of alcohol on
earnings. As noted above, these efforts have yielded conflicting
results. While there is considerable reference to the well known
negative effects of alcohol abuse,(6) there is little consideration
given to medical findings on the effects of moderate drinking or
abstinence. Interestingly, the medical literature also has a good deal
to say concerning the effects of moderate drinking and abstinence.
The medical research, discussed in more detail below, indicates that
both abusive drinkers and abstainers are at significantly greater risk
for heart attack than moderate drinkers. Some of the problems of the
previous economic analysis can perhaps be understood in the light of
this research. Assuming that heart disease is related to income (also
discussed below), then both abstainers and abusers will have lower
incomes than moderate drinkers. The results obtained by researchers when
attempting to use sample partition methods or linear regression will
depend on the sample "mix." If there are large numbers of
abusers, or abstainers, or both, income will be negatively related to
alcohol consumption, as some studies have shown. If there are large
numbers of moderate consumers, alcohol consumption will be positively
related to income, as some studies have shown. If the sample is fairly
balanced between abusers and abstainers and moderates, then alcohol will
have no effect on income, as some studies have shown.
This paper attempts to demonstrate that the medical literature has
been largely disregarded in specifying the human capital models of the
relation between alcohol consumption and earnings. Furthermore, when
this literature is considered in the specification, the empirical
results are in line with the medical findings.
II. Alcohol and Health: A Look at the Medical Literature
Although it is well known that excessive drinkers have health
problems, what is less well known is that moderate drinkers apparently
have above average health - above the average of both abusers and
nondrinkers alike. In the past decade the evidence for this effect has
been further refined and its basis better understood.
One of the main points of this refinement relates to the type of
heart disease under consideration. Drinkers have less coronary artery
disease (CAD)(7) and fewer strokes due to blocked blood vessels. Heavy
drinkers suffer from cardiomyopathy (heart muscle disease), hypertension
(high blood pressure), hemorrhagic stroke and rhythm disturbances.
Lastly, it should be noted that CAD is by far the largest heart disease
problem in terms of cause of death. The second point which recent
studies have clarified is the role of other factors such as age, gender
and lifestyle habits, most importantly smoking.
It is useful to point out that there are two classes of those who do
not drink at all. First, there are those who have never drunk and
currently do not drink, either out of religious conviction or personal
preference. Second, there are also those who have drunk, often quite
heavily, in the past. Not infrequently, these individuals have health
problems, partly or wholly as a result of past drinking patterns, and
are now abstaining. The latter group frequently has medical problems not
present in the former. Hence this research distinguishes between
nondrinkers who have never drunk, termed Lifetime Abstainers, and
Ex-Drinkers.
The notion of the convex relation between drinking and cardiovascular
mortality risk was challenged by Shaper [27]. He maintained that
selective migration from drinking to ex-drinking by individuals at risk
resulted in this relation. He cited as additional evidence that a subset
of subjects who were free of baseline risk factors show no relation
between alcohol use and mortality. Several recent studies have
controlled for the effect of ex-drinkers as well as baseline risk
factors. Prominent among these is the Harvard study by Rimm et al. [26],
Boffetta and Garfinkel [4], DeLabry et al. [7], Klatsky, Friedman, and
Siegelaub [17], Klatsky, Armstrong, and Friedman [18], and Kono et al.
[19]. In a study of 51,000 male health professionals Rimm et al. [26]
found the relative risk of heart disease declined significantly over a
range of ethanol intake from none to 30 grams per day.
The study by Klatsky, Friedman, and Siegelaub [18] covered 129,170
male and female members of Kaiser Permanente Health plan over the 1979
to 1985 period. This study had three main findings. First, ex-drinkers
had higher CAD rates due to the confounding of alcohol related traits,
mainly smoking and gender. Second, the U-shaped curve is not due to
selective abstinence by individuals at higher risk. Third, the findings
indicate a protective effect against CAD of alcohol used in
moderation.(8) All studies were prospective in that they measured the
trait (i.e., alcohol consumption) before the occurrence of the health
event (e.g., heart attack). As well as confirming the U-shaped effect,
the DeLabry study (men only) also offered evidence that moderate
drinkers have greater life expectancy. A recent study Razy et al. [24]
uses a sample composed entirely of women. Previous studies had
concentrated mainly on men. This study also confirmed the convex
relation and greater longevity.
III. Theoretical Considerations
The following model, which is a modification of the one found in
Grossman [9], is used to provide a formal statement of the theory.
Individuals are assumed to possess a multiperiod utility function of the
form,
U = U([[Phi].sub.0][H.sub.0],..., [[Phi].sub.n][H.sub.n],
[Z.sub.0],..., [Z.sub.n]),(1)
where [H.sub.0] is the "inherited" stock of health capital,
[H.sub.i] is the stock of health capital in the ith period,
[[Phi].sub.i] is the coefficient which converts capital stock into a
flow, and [Z.sub.i] is a vector of commodities, and services in the ith
period. The health stock is governed by the standard identity
[H.sub.i] = [H.sub.i-1] + [I.sub.i] - [Delta][H.sub.i], (2)
where [I.sub.i] is gross investment in health and [Delta] is the
depreciation rate. Health investment is given by the household
production function
[I.sub.i] = [I.sub.i]([M.sub.i], T[H.sub.i] : [E.sub.i]) (3a)
where [M.sub.i] is medical care, T[H.sub.i] is time spent investing
in health care, and [E.sub.i] is human capital. The production of
[Z.sub.i] is given by,
[Z.sub.i] = [Z.sub.i]([X.sub.i], [T.sub.i]: [E.sub.i]) (4)
where [X.sub.i] is a vector of purchased inputs, including alcohol,
and [T.sub.i] is the time spent producing [Z.sub.i]. The consumer faces
a wage rate, W, and as a result has two constraints to deal with. The
first is the lifetime budget constraint
[summation of] [(1 + r).sup.-i][P.sub.i][X.sub.i] where [infinity] to
i = 1 = [summation of] [(1 + r).sup.-i] T[W.sub.i][W.sub.i] + N[W.sub.0]
where [infinity] to i = 1 (5)
where [P.sub.i] is the price of [X.sub.i], TW is hours worked and
N[W.sub.0] is net worth in the base period. The second is the simple
time constraint
T[W.sub.i] + T[L.sub.i] + T[H.sub.i] + [T.sub.i] = [Omega] (6)
where TL is time lost due to ill health, and [Omega] is total time
available. The consumer now maximizes (1) subject to the various
constraints.
Rather than face an externally given wage rate, the representative
earners are instead assumed to face a wage reaction function or a
hedonic wage relation where they can, to some extent, endogenize their
wage rate by their choice of education, occupation, and health. This
function specifies the wage rate as a function of age, education,
region, occupation, marital status, ethnic background, family size,
union membership, and various measures of health. These
health-influencing behaviors include whether or not the individual
smokes, the amount of alcohol consumed, and whether or not the
individual has a major health problem. This function permits a unique
wage determination for the individual under consideration. The
specification of this wage function is,
[W.sub.i] = [W.sub.i]([H.sub.i], [E.sub.i], [D.sub.i]) (7)
where W, H and E are as above and D represents predetermined
variables such as region, occupation and marital status. The production
of health investment relation is now modified to allow for specific
health effects, or
[I.sub.i] = [I.sub.i]([M.sub.i], T[H.sub.i], [A.sub.i], [S.sub.i],
[O.sub.i] : [E.sub.i]) (3b)
where A is the amount of alcohol consumed, S is the amount of smoking
activity, and O is other health related problems. Combining (2) and (3b)
and substituting into (7) yields,
[W.sub.i] = [W.sub.i]([M.sub.i], T[H.sub.i], [A.sub.i], [S.sub.i],
[O.sub.i], [D.sub.i], [E.sub.i]). (8)
Equation (8) now gives the wage rate as a function of medical care,
hours spent investing in health care, alcohol consumed(9), whether or
not the individual smokes, other health problems, various predetermined choice variables such as occupation, marital status, etc. and human
capital, mainly as measured by education.
It is well established that good health is an important determinant
of earnings. One important distinction made by Grossman was that while
increases in human capital increase worker productivity and hence wages,
good health not only increases productivity, but also the amount of time
one can work. It is also clear that CAD will diminish many dimensions of
health as they relate to earnings. There will be more time lost due to
recuperation, longevity will be shorter, and disability, resulting in
both time lost and less productivity while on the job, will be greater.
Equation (8) is, of course, only one of several relations yielded by
the consumer optimization process. Maximization of (1) subject to the
appropriate time constraints will yield demand relations for the various
inputs (the [X.sub.i]'s) for each time period. For the problem at
hand one important relation will be the demand for alcoholic beverages,
or
[A.sub.i] = [A.sub.i]([W.sub.i], [M.sub.i], T[H.sub.i], [P.sub.i],
[S.sub.i], [O.sub.i], [D.sub.i], [E.sub.i]). (9)
IV. Empirical Analysis
Since equation (9) is stochastic and [A.sub.i] appears on the RHS of
the wage determination relation (8), there will be simultaneous equation
bias. One solution to the problem would be to include the price of
alcoholic beverages in (8) and (9). There would then be no simultaneous
equation estimation problem. However, the data sets, discussed below,
which contain the necessary information to test this hypothesis, are
medical data sets and do not contain information of prices paid for
inputs such as alcohol. While it might be possible to use BLS area
prices indices, they are only computed for large geographical areas and
do not adequately reflect micro price behavior. Also, they tend to have
the effect of regional dummy variables. Since the crux of the
simultaneous problem is embedded in (8) and (9) it is necessary to
estimate both relations by an appropriate simultaneous equations
estimator.
This section presents the results of estimating the earnings function
and the demand for alcohol by Non-Linear Three Stage Least Squares
(NL3SLS). The hypothesis to be tested is that the relation between
earnings and alcohol consumption will be a concave quadratic function with both classes of abstainers and heavy drinkers earning less than
moderate drinkers. This hypothesis is based on two considerations.
First, the well known convex curve for CAD discussed earlier shows that
moderate drinkers will have less heart disease and as a result will live
longer and more productive lives. Second, the other positive health
effects of moderate drinking, also discussed above, will tend through
the same mechanism to produce higher earnings than those of abstainers
or abusive drinkers. These considerations in conjunction with the
knowledge that heavy drinking has severe negative health impacts will
also produce an earnings curve which is quadratic in alcohol
consumption.
In order to test this hypothesis a data base which contains health
information, alcohol consumption, demographic data, as well as economic
information is required. Health information is needed to correct for
compounding factors such as smoking and medical problems. Information on
alcohol consumption is needed so that moderate consumption can be
differentiated from heavy consumption and both classes of abstinence.
Data must be available on education and various demographic variables.
Last, the data base must also contain information on the respondents
income and hours worked.
One survey which satisfies this criterion is the National Household
Survey on Alcohol Use (NHSA). This survey is sponsored by the NIAAA and
is conducted by the Alcohol Research Group in Berkeley, California. This
survey is conducted every five years and the surveys from 1979 and 1984
are used in this study. The 1990 survey is not yet available. This
survey contains data on various socioeconomic factors such as marital
status, age, occupation, region, education, number of children,
religious preference, health, drinking practices (frequencies and
amounts), and household income (but not hours worked).(10) The 1979
survey contains 1772 observations, 243 of which were dropped due to
missing information on income. The 1984 survey contains 3828
observations. Both surveys differentiated between lifetime abstainers
and ex-drinkers.
As noted above it can be argued that most of the variables appearing
on the right hand side of (8) are exogenous. Variables such as age, sex,
etc. are clearly so. Other choice variables such as education,
occupation, and marital status were selected in the past, so that they
were choice variables at one time but are now also given. However, the
variables representing the amount of alcohol consumed are endogenous and
are jointly determined along with income and other consumption
decisions. Hence, estimation of (8) by OLS will introduce simultaneous
equation bias due to the presence of the demand for alcohol relation.
Table I presents the results of applying NL3SLS to each of the two
data sets mentioned above. Table I gives the results for equation
(8).(11) The model is identified by the presence of a large number of
religious preference variables in the demand for alcohol relation. Many
of these variables were significant in the demand for alcohol relation.
Significant positive variables were Presbyterian, Episcopalian, 'no
religious preference,' and Orthodox Russian. Significant negative
ones were Buddhist, Jewish, and Muslim.
Table I. Regression Results: NL3SLS Quadratic Functional Form
Data Base NHSA: 1979 NHSA: 1984
Dependent Variable Annual Earnings Annual Earnings
Intercept -20311. -11288.
4.4 6.2
Ex-drinker -1493.1 -388.4
.7 .3
Number of Drinks 332.9 128.2
2.2 2.4
Number of Drinks Squared -3.1 -.61
2.3 2.6
Suburban 5300.9 2423.9
5. 4.8
Age 581.3 483.8
5.8 6.4
Age x Age -5.78 -5.54
6.5 6.8
Married 760.4 689.7
.5 10.8
Divorced -5410. -1651.
3.1 2.5
Widowed -3433. 779.
1.6 .9
Education 1175. 772.5
12.5 10.4
Children 406. NA
.4
Medical Problem -276.1 NA
.5
Sex: 1 if male 3124. 1880.8
1.3 2.5
Mean-Dependent Variable 18014.4 17345.8
Sample Size 1529 3838
Drinking Impact Test 9.8 4.6
Notes:
Numbers below regression coefficients are t-ratios.
Not shown are coefficients for occupations and ethnicity (seven
categories for NHSA).
The second column of Table I gives the results for (8) for the 1979
National Survey. Both age and education are highly significant
determinants of earnings. This is consistent with general human capital
findings. Other significant variables are marital status, suburban and
sex. In addition to the variables shown in Table I there were four
regional variables, ten occupational classes, and seven ethnicity
classes. The occupational variables tended to be significant, as did
some of the ethnicity ones. The relations presented in Table I were
estimated with the significant regional and ethnicity variables
retained.
The third column of Table I gives the results for the National
Household Survey on Alcohol for 1984 for relation (8). These results are
similar to those from the 1979 survey. The effects of alcohol
consumption are similar to the 1979 results with the exception that
excessive drinkers do not show a significant drop in income. Ex-drinkers
earn less than lifetime abstainers in both surveys. Human capital
variables, age and education, are again highly significant.
In both of the regressions the linear and quadratic terms are
significant. The impact of the drinking variables was tested with the
standard F-test for a restricted subset using the 2SLS estimates. This
test consisted in running each regression from Table I with none of the
drinking variables (linear, squared, and ex-drinker terms). This is the
restricted regression. This model was then compared to the full model.
The results of this test, given under Drinking Impact Test in Table I,
show that the drinking variables add significantly to the regression in
every case.
V. Conclusions
This paper attempts to show how knowledge of medical research can
assist in specifying the effect of health related variables in a human
capital model. Specifically, the paper uses medical findings to specify
the relationship between alcohol consumption and earnings. This
relationship is quadratic and recognizes the distinction between two
classes of abstainers: ex-drinkers and lifetime abstainers. The
empirical estimates lend support to the hypothesis that moderate
drinkers earn more than either abstainers or abusive drinkers. The paper
presents estimates of the quadratic relation using data from two
separate surveys. Both are large micro based surveys with considerable
economic and epidemiological detail.
The effect of moderate alcohol consumption on earnings is
statistically significant, but not as significant as the effect of
traditional human capital variables such as education or age. The effect
of drinking on earnings is statistically significant in both models. The
results for weekly earnings imply that total hours worked is also an
inverted U-shaped function of alcohol consumption.
Knowledge of the medical literature not only aided in the
specification of the model, it also suggests an explanation for
reconciling contradictory results obtained by other researchers. Some
previous studies have found alcohol to have negative effects on earnings
while other studies have found the opposite. These studies have not
allowed for curvilinear, or inverted U shaped, effects. Hence it is
conjectured here that the effects found, positive or negative, depended
on the "sample mix" of heavy drinkers and abstainers relative
to moderate drinkers in conjunction with the linear specification.
Previous studies have, for example, used a dichotomous variable to
differentiate between moderate consumers and abusers. They also failed
to differentiate between abstainers and moderate drinkers or distinguish
between classes of abstainers.
1. In Prohibition at Its Worst (1926), Fisher claimed that
prohibition would increase national productivity by 5%.
2. These lost earnings are not to be confused with the income losses
suffered by individuals involved in auto accidents with drunken drivers.
Those costs, for both drunken drivers and their victims, are another
category of the "economic cost to society." The government
does not distinguish between external and internal costs in their
methodology.
3. The methodology described here was used in the 1980 estimates. See
Harwood et al. [11]. This methodology is criticized in Helen and Pittman
[13].
4. See Rice et al. [25].
5. The DSMALC criterion (for alcoholism) and the NIAAA criterion (for
alcohol abuse) are very different. According to the NIAAA, 2 drinks or
greater per day is alcohol abuse.
6. In some cases, such as cirrhosis of the liver, there is a clear
physiological relationship. In other cases, there are difficulties
disentangling the effects of alcohol from chronic smoking and other
lifestyle effects.
7. The main causes of CAD are smoking, high blood pressure, diabetes,
and a fatty diet. Death usually results from heart attack due to blood
vessel blockage.
8. The study also found that the protective effect of alcohol was
more pronounced for women.
9. A more rigorous formulation would replace the quantity of alcohol
consumed with input prices, especially those for alcoholic beverages.
This problem is discussed below.
10. This survey is described in detail in Clark and Midanik [5].
11. The estimates of (9), which are not of primary interest here, are
available on request. The results did show that income is not a
significant determinate of alcohol consumption. Previous studies
substantiate this finding. Heien and Pompelli [14] found small negative
income elasticities for alcoholic beverages. Johnson and Oksanen [15]
found extremely small positive and negative income elasticities for
alcoholic beverages. Both studies employed cross section data so that
trends and habit were not confounded with income effects. The demand for
ethanol is even less income elastic as it is widely recognized that
consumers shift up to higher quality beverages as income increases. In
this sense, alcohol is much like other food products.
References
1. Becker, Gary. Human Capital. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1964.
2. Benham, Lee and Alexandra Benham. "Employment, Earnings, and
Psychiatric Diagnosis," in Economic Aspects of Health, edited by V.
Fuchs. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.
3. Berger, Mark C. and J. Paul Leigh, "The Effect of Alcohol Use
on Wages." Applied Economics, 1988, 1343-51.
4. Boffeta, Paolo and Lawrence Garfinkel, "Alcohol Drinking and
Mortality among Men Enrolled in an American Cancer Society Prospective
Study." Epidemiology, September 1990, 342-48.
5. Clark, William B. and Lorraine Midanik. "Alcohol Use and
Alcohol Problems among U.S. Adults: Results of the 1979 National
Survey," in Alcohol Consumption and Related Problems, Alcohol and
Health Monograph No. 1, DHHS Publication No. (ADM) 82-1190. Washington:
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1982.
6. Cook, Philip. "The Social Costs of Drinking," Chapter 2
in The Negative Social Consequences of Alcohol Use. Oslo, Norway:
Norwegian Ministry of Health and Social Affairs, 1990.
7. DeLabry, Lorraine O., Robert J. Glynn, Michael R. Levenson, John
A. Hermos, Joseph S. LoCastro, and Pantel S. Vokonas, "Alcohol
Consumption and Mortality in an American Male Population: Recovering the
U-Shaped Curve-Findings for a Normative Aging Study." Journal of
Studies on Alcohol, 1992, 25-32.
8. French, Michael T. and Gary A. Zarkin, "Is Moderate Alcohol
Use Related to Wages? Evidence from Four Worksites." Journal of
Health Economics, 1995, 319-44.
9. Grossman, Michael, "On the Concept of Human Capital and the
Demand for Health." Journal of Political Economy, 1972, 223-55.
10. -----. The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical
Investigation. Occasional Paper no. 119. New York: Columbia University
Press (NBER), 1972.
11. Harwood, Hendrick J., Diane M. Napolitano, Patricia L.
Kristansen, and James J. Collins. Economic Costs to Society of Alcohol
and Drug Abuse and Mental Illness. Prepared for the Alcohol Drug Abuse,
and Mental Health Administration, RTI/2734/00-01FR. Research Triangle
Park, N.C.: Research Triangle Institute, 1984.
12. Heien, Dale M., "The Relationship between Alcohol
Consumption and Earnings." Forthcoming in Journal of Studies on
Alcohol.
13. ----- and David Pittman, "The Economic Costs of Alcohol
Abuse: An Assessment of Current Methods and Estimates." Journal of
Studies on Alcohol, 1989, 567-79.
14. Heien, Dale M. and Greg Pompelli, "The Demand for Alcoholic
Beverages: Economic and Demographic Effects." Southern Economic
Journal, January 1989, 759-70.
15. Johnson, James A. and Ernest H. Oksanen, "Estimation of
Demand for Alcoholic Beverages in Canada from Pooled Time Series and
Cross Sections." Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1977,
113-18.
16. Kenkel, Donald S. and David C. Ribar. "Alcohol Consumption
and Young Adults' Socioeconomic Status." Brooking Papers on
Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1994. Washington: The Brookings
Institution, 1994.
17. Klatsky, Arthur L., Gary D. Friedman and A. B. Siegelaub,
"Alcohol and Mortality: A Ten Year Kaiser Permanente
Experience." Annals of Internal Medicine, 1981, 139-45.
18. Klatsky, Arthur L., Mary Anne Armstrong, and Gary D. Friedman,
"Risk of Cardiovascular Mortality in Alcohol Drinkers, Ex-Drinkers
and Nondrinkers." The American Journal of Cardiology, November,
1990, 1237-42.
19. Kono, Suminori, Koichi Handa, Tomoki Kawano, Tadavuki Hiroki,
Yasushi Ishihara, and Kikuo Arakawa, "Alcohol Intake and Nonfatal
Acute Myocardial Infarction in Japan." The American Journal of
Cardiology, October 1991, 1011-14.
20. Manning, Willard G., Emmett B. Keeler, Joseph P. Newhouse,
Elizabeth M. Sloss, and Jeffrey Wassermann. The Costs of Poor Health
Habits. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991.
21. Model, Karen E. "The Relationship between Drug and Alcohol
Use and Income: An Econometric Model." Unpublished manuscript,
Harvard University, 1991.
22. Mullahy, John. "Alcohol and the Labor Market." Mimeo,
May 1992.
23. ----- and Jody Sindelar, "Lifecycle Effects of Alcoholism on
Education, Earnings, and Occupation." Inquiry, Summer 1989, 272-82.
24. Razy, G., K. W. Heaton, C. H. Bolton, and A. O. Hughes,
"Alcohol Consumption and Its Relation to Cardiovascular Risk
Factors in British Women." British Medical Journal, January 11,
1992, 80-83.
25. Rice, Dorothy P., Sander Kelman, Leonard S. Miller, and Sarah
Dunmeyer. The Economic Costs of Alcohol and Drug Abuse and Mental
Illness: 1985. San Francisco: Institute for Health and Aging, University
of California: 1990.
26. Rimm, Eric B., Edward L. Giovannucci, Walter C. Willett, Graham
A. Colditz, Alberto Ascherio, Bernard Rosner and Meir J. Stampfer,
"Prospective Study of Alcohol Consumption and Risk of Coronary
Disease in Men." The Lancet, August 24, 1991, 464-68.
27. Shaper, A. Gerald, Goya Wannamethee, and Mary Walker,
"Alcohol and Mortality in British Men: Explaining the U-Shaped
Curve." The Lancet, December 3, 1988, 1267-73.