Understanding Saving: Evidence from the United States and Japan.
Lusardi, Annamaria
By Fumio Hayashi.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1997. Pp. x, 510. $50.00.
In this book, Hayashi collects his work of consumption and saving
over the past 15 years. In this respect, this is a unique testimony of
the work and debate on consumption and saving during the 1980s and
1990s. This book is an important resource for several reasons. First, it
focuses on useful extensions and modifications of the simple life cycle
model. For example, it takes into account imperfections in the financial
markets and the effects they can have on consumption/saving decisions.
Second, it goes beyond the finite horizon framework and considers how
generations are linked together. Third, it proposes new ways to estimate
the predictions of theoretical models and provides a very careful and
thorough empirical work. Fourth, it studies and compares the experience
of the United States and Japan. Japan is a country of special interest;
it has one of the highest saving rates, and its institutions and
structure make it an ideal case study to analyze saving models. Overall,
this book is an invaluable source for researchers working in both macro-
and microeconomics.
One common feature of many chapters in this book is the use of micro
data. Even when looking at issues relevant at the macro level, Hayashi
uses mostly household data. This has many advantages: He can not only
look into the reasons for the failure of the life cycle-permanent income
model but, most important, can directly test the theoretical predictions
of the model since they pertain to the individual level. Another common
feature is the use of rich and extensive data sets, in particular, some
of the Japanese ones that report very detailed and sometimes unique
information about consumption.
In many of the chapters of this book, Hayashi proposes an innovative
and thorough empirical work from which many other researchers have
learned and borrowed. Just as an additional indication of the care put
into the empirical work, he often updates the estimation of the papers
that were published some years ago and adds the new estimates and
revisions in an appendix. Although results hardly change, the reader
should praise the precision, care, and rigor used by the author.
The book is divided into three main sections: the first on liquidity
constraints, the second on risk sharing and altruism, and the third on
Japanese saving behavior. In the first section, Hayashi investigates the
predictions of the rational expectations-permanent income hypothesis
(PIH) and whether liquidity constraints can explain the empirical
refutation of the model. The fact that financial markets are imperfect and that most households cannot borrow in the ways assumed by the theory
is almost palpable. This adds some realism to an otherwise restrictive
framework. It is not easy, however, to test this implication in the
data. He estimates the predictions of the PIH by looking at the Euler
equations, that is, the first-order conditions of the maximization
problem. He makes use of the theoretical predictions of the model, which
state that no past information should be able to predict consumption
changes. The instrumental variables approach that he develops is a
precursor of many other works in the 1980s. It is not an exaggeration to
say that some of Hayashi's early work set the stage for much of the
future work on this topic.
Many of the problems in estimating the Euler equations that have
affected much of the research during the past 10 years were already
documented and discussed in these initial papers. Among these many
problems are: The consumption measure (i.e., consumption versus
expenditure), the durability of the consumption goods, the small sample
period, and the problem of measurement error in micro data. Hayashi gets
around many of these problems in clever ways. For example, he does not
assume that consumption is nondurable but tests for it using a unique
data set of Japanese households. His empirical findings are important
since he reports substantial evidence of durability. He also uses
consumption data from diaries. The way in which diaries are collected
soften the measurement error problems present in many micro data sets.
In addition, he overcomes the problems of the small sample size and the
weakness of the test of the Euler equations by exploiting simple
predictions of the model and testing them at the cross-sectional level.
In a work that had a big impact in the profession (chap. 3), he looks
at the households with small amounts of wealth and examines whether the
consumption of this group is lower than that of households that have a
lot of assets and are therefore less likely to be constrained. The idea
is simple and intuitive but very powerful, and it provides a rather
strong test for the presence and importance of liquidity constraints.
In his works, using both U.S. and Japanese data, Hayashi rejects the
predictions of the PIH and finds evidence in favor of liquidity
constraints. The empirical evidence on liquidity constraints is well
discussed and summarized in chapter 6, which represents an excellent
survey of the earlier work on Euler equations.
A second important topic that Hayashi examines in great detail is
whether generations are linked together and care about each other. This
topic is of paramount importance. Although many studies have been
undertaken on this issue, we still do not know much about the strength
and importance of the bequest motive. The problem is that we do not know
whether the existence of transfers across generations necessarily
indicates altruism, as many of the original models have assumed.
Transfers could originate simply from exchanges across generations or
could be the result of short, unexpected longevity.
Hayashi, together with a group of coauthors, looks at this issue from
a novel angle: If generations are altruistically linked, the
distribution of consumption should be independent of the distribution of
resources of a single generation and should depend only on the resources
of the dynasty. So, for example, the distribution of resources between
parents and children should depend only on their collective resources
and not on the distribution of the children and parents' income.
They estimate this prediction using data from the Panel Study of Income
Dynamics (PSID), which follows families and their split-offs over time.
The PSID is a very rich data set, although it suffers from the fact that
only data on food consumption is provided and some restrictive
assumptions have to be made when modeling household consumption.
In all the tests performed using different estimation methods,
Hayashi and his co-authors reject the altruistic model and find that the
distribution of consumption of parents and children is highly dependent
on their incomes. However, they also find that the resources of the
single generations are not the only resources that matter, as would be
predicted by the simple life cycle model (even though the evidence
against the life cycle model is somewhat weak). In this sense, although
the study is very powerful, it does not settle whether it is the simple
life cycle or the altruistic model that governs the behavior of
households. Additionally, it could be the case that the evidence shows
what is already reported in the first part of the book, that is, that
liquidity constraints or other market imperfections are present and that
they prevent generations from smoothing their consumption.
If altruism does not explain the behavior of many American
households, could it explain the behavior of other countries? Japan is,
in this respect, an ideal country to study, given the fight family
connections and the different cultural framework that seems more
favorable to family interactions. Hayashi exploits the same intuition as
above, this time using Japanese data. In this context, he can only rely
on cross-sectional data, and he basically tests whether consumption is
dependent on the division of resources within the extended family. Even
in the Japanese framework, this hypothesis is not supported.
It should be noted that the evidence from these two studies does not
mean that generations are not altruistic at all but that they are not
altruistic enough to behave as a single decision unit. Although very
original and innovative, this test pursues a very strict theoretical
prediction, and, at the end, it is perhaps not surprising that it is
rejected by the data.
As mentioned above, the fact that the distribution of resources of
single generations matters may simply indicate that markets are not
complete and that generations cannot pool resources in the way the model
assumed them to do. In a world with uncertainty, the significance of the
resources of each individual generation may be an indication that there
is not complete risk sharing across generations. Hayashi and his
coauthors look at this issue in chapter 9, in which they perform a very
general test that also takes into account that food may not be separable from leisure and that leisure is a choice variable. Consistent with the
evidence from the previous papers, they reject the hypothesis of
complete insurance. Again this does not mean that there is no risk
sharing at all among families but only that the extent to which risk
sharing happens is imperfect.
In the third section of the book, Hayashi examines an often-asked
question: What explains the high saving rate in Japan? He examines three
important reasons: the measurement of saving, the bequest motive, and
the imperfections in the financial markets. When making international
comparisons of saving, it is important to be careful about data
comparability. Hayashi notices that there are important differences in
the national accounts between the United States and Japan. The two most
important ones are the treatment of depreciation and durable goods.
Depreciation is valued at historical costs in Japan, whereas in the
United States durable goods are counted as consumption. After he makes
many of the adjustments necessary to make figures comparable, he reports
some striking findings: The level of saving in Japan remains well above
that of the United States but is not as high as commonly thought. Most
important, the adjustments reveal that the patterns of saving are
different than commonly reported. For example, as in many other
developed countries, in Japan too the saving rate has been declining
since the 1970s.
Japanese families are very tightly connected, and empirically one
sees many elderly living with their children as well as many transfers.
This represents an ideal situation to study the importance of
intergenerational transfers. Using two large cross-sections of
households, Hayashi and coauthors investigate whether the elderly
dissave at the end of the life cycle. The analysis here is limited by
the availability of only cross-sectional data, and studying this
question would require using panel data. On the other hand, they have
very rich and large data sets of more than 50,000 households. The
presence of extended families can substantially blur the analysis in
cross-sectional data since it is usually the poorer parents that move in
with the children and therefore tend to disappear as independent
families, leaving a sample of relatively rich old households. Hayashi
and co-authors are very careful in the treatment of extended families.
They perform a separate analysis for family types and find that,
contrary to the theoretical predictions, the elderly do not dissave. In
fact, many of them continue to save and often leave behind a substantial
amount of wealth. They also find that one of the assets that many
families bequeath to the next generation is the house.
In the last chapter, Hayashi, with a group of coauthors, concentrates
on the issue of housing. They note not only that houses are very
expensive in Japan but also that the down payment required to buy a
house is quite substantial. They simulate a model that incorporates a
severe down payment constraint and evaluate whether this alone can
explain the difference in saving between the United States and Japan.
Although important, this is not enough to explain the much higher saving
rate in Japan. They then allow for a bequest motive, as some of
Hayashi's studies seem to suggest that this is relevant. Households
save to accumulate for the down payment to buy a house and at the end of
their life cycle do not sell off the house but leave it to their
children. This model can now better replicate some of the features of
the Japanese economy and the high saving rate that it experienced with
respect to the United States, particularly when it is assumed that the
economy is growing and is not yet in a steady state. Again, this is a
very interesting idea, and other authors have borrowed it to try to
explain differences across countries as well as to argue that the
development in financial markets can explain the recent decline in
saving rates.
To summarize, this is an outstanding book on consumption and saving.
It provides a very thorough and rigorous analysis of some of the most
important issues in this literature. In particular, it reports some of
the most innovative and original works of the past 15 years. Anyone,
however expert in the field, has a lot to learn by reading this book.
Annamaria Lusardi Dartmouth College